34855 WHERE IS the WEALTH of Nations? Measuring Capital for the 21st Century WHERE IS THEWealth ofNATIONS? WHERE IS THE Wealth of NATIONS? Measuring Capital for the 21st Century THE WORLD BANK Washington, D.C. © 2006 The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/The World Bank 1818 H Street, NW Washington, DC 20433 Telephone 202-473-1000 Internet: www.worldbank.org E-mail: feedback@worldbank.org All rights reserved. A publication of the World Bank. 1 2 3 4 09 08 07 06 The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed herein are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Board of Executive Directors of the World Bank or the governments they represent. The World Bank does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this work. The boundaries, colors, denominations, and other information shown on any map in this work do not imply any judgment on the part of the World Bank concerning the legal status of any territory or the endorsement or acceptance of such boundaries. Rights and Permissions The material in this work is copyrighted. Copying and/or transmitting portions or all of this work without permission may be a violation of applicable law. The World Bank encourages dissemination of its work and will normally grant permission promptly. For permission to photocopy or reprint any part of this work, please send a request with complete information to the Copyright Clearance Center, Inc., 222 Rosewood Drive, Danvers, MA 01923, USA, telephone 978-750-8400, fax 978-750-4470, www.copyright.com. All other queries on rights and licenses, including subsidiary rights, should be addressed to the Office of the Publisher, World Bank, 1818 H Street, NW, Washington, DC 20433, USA, fax 202-522-2422, e-mail pubrights@worldbank.org. Cover photo courtesy of Corbis. Library of Congress Cataloging in Publication data has been applied for. ISBN-10: 0-8213-6354-9 ISBN-13: 978-0-8213-6354-6 eISBN: 0-8213-6355-7 DOI: 10.1596/978-0-8213-6354-6 TABLE OF CONTENTS Foreword vii Acknowledgments viii Acronyms and Abbreviations ix Looking for the Wealth of Nations--A Logical Map xi Executive Summary xiii Part 1--Wealth Accounting 1 Chapter 1. Introduction: The Millennium Capital Assessment 3 Chapter 2. The Wealth Stock Estimates 19 Part 2--Changes in Wealth 33 Chapter 3. Recent Genuine Saving Estimates 35 Chapter 4. The Importance of Investing Resource Rents: A Hartwick Rule Counterfactual 49 Chapter 5. The Importance of Population Dynamics: Changes in Wealth per Capita 61 Chapter 6. Testing Genuine Saving 71 Part 3--Wealth, Production, and Development 85 Chapter 7. Explaining the Intangible Capital Residual: The Role of Human Capital and Institutions 87 Chapter 8. Wealth and Production 101 Part 4--International Experience 119 Chapter 9. Developing and Using Environmental Accounts 121 Appendixes: Sources and Methods 141 Appendix 1. Building the Wealth Estimates 143 Appendix 2. Wealth Estimates by Country, 2000 159 Appendix 3. Genuine Saving Estimates by Country, 2000 163 Appendix 4. Change in Wealth per Capita, 2000 169 References 173 Index 181 V FOREWORD This volume asks a key question: Where is the Wealth of Nations? Answering this question yields important insights into the prospects for sustainable development in countries around the world. The estimates of total wealth­including produced, natural, and human and institutional capital­suggest that human capital and the value of institutions (as measured by rule of law) constitute the largest share of wealth in virtually all countries. It is striking that natural capital constitutes a quarter of total wealth in low-income countries, greater than the share of produced capital. This suggests that better management of ecosystems and natural resources will be key to sustaining development while these countries build their infrastructure and human and institutional capital. Particularly noteworthy is the share of cropland and pastureland in the natural wealth of poor countries­at nearly 70 percent, this argues for a strong focus on efforts to sustain soil quality. This new approach to capital also provides a comprehensive measure of changes in wealth, a key indicator of sustainability. There are important examples of resource-dependent countries, such as Botswana, that have used their natural resources to underpin impressive rates of growth. In addition, the research finds that the value of natural capital per person actually tends to rise with income when we look across countries­this contradicts the received wisdom that development necessarily entails the depletion of the environment. However, the figures suggest that, per capita, most low-income countries have experienced declines in both total and natural capital. This is bad news not only from an environmental point of view, but also from a broader development perspective. Growth is essential if developing countries are to meet the Millennium Development Goals by 2015. Growth, however, will be illusory if it is based on mining soils and depleting fisheries and forests. This report provides the indicators needed to manage the total portfolio of assets upon which development depends. Armed with this information, decision makers can direct the development process toward sustainable outcomes. Ian Johnson François Bourguignon Vice President, Sustainable Senior Vice President and Development Chief Economist VII ACKNOWLEDGMENTS Where Is the Wealth of Nations? has been written by a team including Kirk Hamilton, Giovanni Ruta, Katharine Bolt, Anil Markandya, Suzette Pedroso-Galinato, Patricia Silva, M. Saeed Ordoubadi, Glenn-Marie Lange, and Liaila Tajibaeva. The estimation of wealth subcomponents is based on the background work of Susana Ferreira, Liying Zhou, Boon- Ling Yeo, and Roberto Martin-Hurtado. The report received insightful comments from the peer reviewers, Marian Delos Angeles and Giles Atkinson. Specific contributions have been provided by Milen Dyoulgerov, Lidvard Gronnevet, and Per Ryden. We are indebted to colleagues inside and outside the World Bank for providing useful feedback. Our thanks goes to Dina Abu-Ghaida, Dan Biller, Jan Bojo, Julia Bucknall, Richard Damania, John Dixon, Eric Fernandes, Alan Gelb, Alec Ian Gershberg, Tracy Hart, James Keith Hinchliffe, Julien Labonne, Kseniya Lvovsky, William Sutton, Walter Vergara, and Jian Xie. The financial support of the Government of Sweden is acknowledged with gratitude. This book is dedicated to the memory of David Pearce­professor, mentor, friend, and intellectual father of the work presented here. VIII Acronyms and Abbreviations CES constant elasticity of substitution EA environment accounts eaNDP environmentally adjusted net domestic product ENRAP Environment and Natural Resource Accounting Project EPE environmental protection expenditure EU European Union Eurostat European Commission's official statistical agency FAO Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations GDP gross domestic product geNDP greened economy net domestic product GNI gross national income GNIPC gross national income per capita IO input-output IUCN The World Conservation Union MFA material flow accounts NAMEA national accounting matrix including environmental accounts NDP net domestic product NPV net present value PIM perpetual inventory model PPP Purchasing Power Parities PVC Present Value of Change OECD Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development OLS Ordinary Least Squares SAM social accounting matrix SEEA system of integrated environmental and economic accounting SNA system of national accounts SNI sustainable national income SOEs state-owned enterprises SRRI Social Rate of Return on Investment ix ACRONYMSAND ABBREVIATIONS TMR total material requirements UNEP-WCMC United Nations Environment Programme World Conservation Monitoring Centre WDI World Development Indicators WDPA World Database of Protected Areas Note: All dollar amounts are U.S. dollars unless otherwise indicated. x LOOKINGFOR THEWEALTHOF NATIONS--A LOGICAL MAP XI EXECUTIVE SUMMARY With this volume, Where Is the Wealth of Nations? the World Bank publishes what could be termed the millennium capital assessment: monetary estimates of the range of assets--produced, natural, and intangible--upon which development depends. While important gaps remain, this comprehensive snapshot of wealth for 120 countries at the turn of the millennium aims to deepen our understanding of the linkages between development outcomes and the level and composition of wealth. Figures 1 and 2 provide important insights into the role of natural resources in low-income countries (excluding oil states where resource rents exceed 20 percent of gross domestic product [GDP]). The first key message is that natural capital is an important share of total wealth, greater than the share of produced capital.1 This suggests that managing natural resources must be a key part of development strategies. The composition of natural wealth in poor countries emphasizes the major role of agricultural land, but subsoil assets and timber and nontimber forest resources make up another quarter of total natural wealth. The large share of natural resources in total wealth and the composition of these resources make a strong argument for the role of environmental resources in reducing poverty, fighting hunger, and lowering child mortality. The analysis in this volume proceeds from an overview of the Figure 1 Shares of Total Wealth in Figure 2 Shares of Natural Wealth Low-Income Countries, 2000 in Low-Income Countries, 2000 Produced capital, Pastureland, Subsoil assets, 16% 10% 17% Timber resources, 6% NTFR, 2% Natural capital, Intangible capital, 26% PA, 6% 58% Cropland, Source: Authors. 59% Note: Oil states excluded. Source: Authors. Note: Oil states excluded. NTFR: Nontimber forest resources. PA: Protected areas. EXECUTIVE SUMMARY wealth of nations to analyze the key role of the management of wealth through saving and investments. It also analyzes the importance of human capital and good governance and engages finance ministries in developing a comprehensive agenda that looks at natural resources as an integral part of their policy domain. Where Is the Wealth of Nations? is organized around three key questions. Each chapter tackles a particular aspect of the wealth-wellbeing equation and describes the story behind the numbers and the relative policy implications. Before engaging the key issues, chapter 1 and chapter 2 introduce the reader into the structure, results, and main policy implications of the volume. Chapter 1 provides an overview of the wealth estimates with a focus on the implications for policy makers. It introduces the notion of development as a process of portfolio management--a powerful framework for action. Certain assets in the portfolio are exhaustible and can only be transformed into other assets through investment of the resource rents. Other assets are renewable and can yield sustainable income streams. Economic analysis can guide decisions concerning the optimal size of these assets in the portfolio. The wealth estimates suggest that the preponderant form of wealth worldwide is intangible capital--human capital and the quality of formal and informal institutions. Moreover, the share of produced assets in total wealth is virtually constant across income groups, with a moderate increase in produced capital intensiveness in middle-income countries. The share of natural capital in total wealth tends to fall with income, while the share of intangible capital rises. The latter point makes perfect sense--rich countries are largely rich because of the skills of their populations and the quality of the institutions supporting economic activity. Chapter 2 takes the reader through the methodology used to estimate wealth, explaining the methods and assumptions used. The total wealth estimates reported in Where Is the Wealth of Nations? are built upon a combination of top-down and bottom-up approaches. Total wealth, in line with economic theory, is estimated as the present value of future consumption. Produced capital stocks are derived from historical investment data using a perpetual inventory model (PIM). Natural resource stock values are based upon country-level data on physical stocks and estimates of natural resource rents based on world prices and local costs. Intangible capital, then, is measured as the difference between total wealth and the other produced and natural stocks. The estimates XIV EXECUTIVE SUMMARY of natural wealth are limited by data--fish stocks and subsoil water are not measured in the estimates--while the environmental services that underpin human societies and economies are not measured explicitly. The introduction of the wealth estimates methodology and results in the first two chapters sets the stage for the three leading questions in the volume. The central tenet of Where Is the Wealth of Nations? is embodied in chapters 4 through 7. While wealth composition may, to some extent, determine the development options available to a particular country, the quality of development depends crucially on how wealth changes over time. Natural capital can be transformed into other forms of capital, provided resource rents are efficiently invested. Do Changes in Wealth Matter for the Generation of Well-Being? Natural resources are special economic goods because they are not produced. As a consequence, natural resources will yield economic profits--rents--if properly managed. These rents can be an important source of development finance, and countries like Botswana and Malaysia have successfully used natural resources in this way. There are no sustainable diamond mines, but there are sustainable diamond-mining countries. Behind this statement is an assumption that it is possible to transform one form of wealth--diamonds in the ground--into other forms of wealth such as buildings, machines, and human capital. Saving is obviously a core aspect of development. Without the creation of a surplus for investment there is no way for countries to escape a low-level subsistence equilibrium. Resource dependence complicates the measurement of saving effort because depletion of natural resources is not visible in standard national accounts. Adjusted net or genuine saving measures the true level of saving in a country after depreciation of produced capital; investments in human capital (as measured by education expenditures); depletion of minerals, energy, and forests; and damages from local and global air pollutants are taken into account. Chapter 3 describes the estimation of adjusted net saving. It then goes on to present and discuss the empirical calculations of genuine saving rates available for over 140 countries. XV EXECUTIVE SUMMARY Development has been referred to as a process of portfolio management. The Hartwick rule for sustainability actually mandates that in order to achieve sustainable consumption, countries should invest their rents from natural resources. Drawing on a 30-year time series of resource rent data underlying the adjusted net saving estimates, chapter 4 constructs a Hartwick rule counterfactual: how rich would countries be in the year 2000 if they had followed the Hartwick rule since 1970? The empirical estimations in this chapter test two variants of the Hartwick rule--the standard rule, which amounts to keeping genuine saving precisely equal to zero at each point in time, and a version that assumes a constant level of positive genuine saving at each point in time. In many cases, the results are striking. The calculations show how even a moderate saving effort, equivalent to the average saving effort of the poorest countries in the world, could have substantially increased the wealth of resource-dependent economies. In 2000, Nigeria, a major oil exporter, could have had a stock of produced capital five times higher. Moreover, if these investments had taken place, oil would play a much smaller role in the Nigerian economy today, with likely beneficial impacts on policies affecting other sectors of the economy. Republica Bolivariana de Venezuela could have four times as much produced capital. In per capita terms, the economies of the Republica Bolivariana de Venezuela, Trinidad and Tobago, and Gabon, all rich in petroleum, could today have a stock of produced capital of roughly US$30,000 per person, comparable to the Republic of Korea. Adjusted net saving is introduced in chapter 3 as a more inclusive measure of net saving effort. Yet, if population is not static, then it is clearly per capita welfare that policy should aim to sustain. While adjusted net saving is answering an important question--did total wealth rise or fall over the accounting period?--it does not speak directly to the question of the sustainability of economies when there is a growing population. This task is undertaken in chapter 5. If genuine saving is negative, then it is clear in both total and per capita terms that wealth is declining. For a range of countries, however, it is possible that genuine saving in total could be positive while wealth per capita is declining. Countries with high population growth rates are effectively on a treadmill and need to create new wealth just to maintain existing levels of wealth per capita. In general, the results suggest very large saving gaps in Sub-Saharan Africa when population growth is taken into account. Excluding the oil states, saving gaps (the increase in saving required to XVI EXECUTIVE SUMMARY maintain current levels of wealth per capita) in many countries are on the order of 10 percent to 50 percent of the gross national income (GNI). Against this must be set the realization that reigning in government consumption by even a few percentage points of GNI is extremely painful and often politically perilous. Macroeconomic policies alone seem unlikely to close the gap. Economic theory suggests that current net saving should equal the change in future well-being, specifically the present value of future changes in consumption. Chapter 6 tests this hypothesis. The saving tests using historical data reported in this volume suggest that a particular variant of genuine saving, one that excludes education expenditures, damage from carbon dioxide emissions, and the immiserating effects of population growth, is a good predictor of future changes in well-being. Genuine saving is, therefore, a potentially important indicator to guide development policy. The analysis includes a further key result: when the sample of countries is limited to high-income countries, there is no apparent empirical relationship between current net saving and future well-being. This raises an important distinction between developed and developing countries. It says quite clearly that asset accumulation, the apparent driver of future welfare when all countries are tested, is not a significant factor in rich countries. This result makes eminent sense. In the richest countries it is clear that technological change, institutional innovation, learning by doing, and social capital, to name a few factors, are fundamental drivers of the economy. While saving is at the basis of sustainable development, the composition of wealth determines the menu of options a given government has available. The second key question looks at specific types of wealth and their role. What Are the Key Assets in the Generation of Well-Being? As pointed out, most of a country's wealth is captured by what we term intangible capital. Given its importance, chapter 7 deals with the decomposition of intangible capital into subcomponents. By construction, the intangible capital variable captures all those assets that XVII EXECUTIVE SUMMARY are unaccounted for in the estimates of produced and natural capital. Intangible assets include the skills and know-how embodied in the labor force. The category also includes social capital, that is, the trust among people in a society and their ability to work together for a common purpose. The residual also accounts for all those governance elements that boost the productivity of labor. For example, if an economy has a very efficient judicial system, clear property rights, and an effective government, the effects will result in a higher total wealth and thus a higher intangible capital residual. The regression analysis in this chapter shows that human capital and rule of law account for the majority of the variation in the residual. Investments in education, the functioning of the justice system, and policies aimed at attracting remittances are the most important means of increasing the intangible components of total wealth. In chapter 2 it is observed that as countries become richer, the relative importance of produced and intangible assets rises in ratio to natural assets. Thus, the development process primarily entails growth in the modern sectors of manufacturing and services, which depend heavily on more intangible forms of wealth. Yet, the value of natural resources per person does not decline as income rises, particularly for agricultural land. Chapter 8 tests the hypothesis that land and other natural resources are, in fact, key in sustaining income generation. Underlying any wealth accounts is an implicit production function, which is a blueprint of the combinations of different assets with which we can achieve a given level of output. These blueprints are usually written as a mathematical function, which describes the precise relationship between the availability of different amounts of inputs, such as physical and human capital services, and the maximum output they could produce. The substitutability between inputs is then measured as an elasticity of substitution. The results provide some interesting findings. There is no sign that the elasticity of substitution between the natural resource (land) and other inputs is particularly low. Wherever land emerges as a significant input, it has an elasticity of substitution approximately equal to or greater than one. This outcome, on one hand, confirms that countries' opportunities are not necessarily dictated by their endowments of natural resources. On the other hand, it validates the importance of a Hartwick rule of saving the rents from the exploitation of natural resources if we are to achieve a sustained level of income generation. XVIII EXECUTIVE SUMMARY How Can Comprehensive Wealth and Its Changes Be Measured in National Accounts? A central tenet of the volume is the need for a pragmatic vision of sustainable development as a process of administering a portfolio of assets. Having committed themselves to achieving sustainable development, governments face a number of challenges beyond the traditional concerns of their natural resources and environmental agencies. Policy makers setting environmental standards need to be aware of the likely consequences for the economy, while economic policy makers must consider the sustainability of current and projected patterns of production and consumption. Such integration and adoption of the notion of sustainable development by governments have been the motivation for developing environmental accounting. Chapter 9 provides a context to explore the usefulness of the system of environmental and economic accounts (SEEA) as an operational framework for monitoring sustainability and its policy use. The chapter summarizes the four general components of the environmental accounts. Furthermore, it reviews a few policy applications of environmental accounting in industrialized and developing countries, and also indicates potential applications, which may not be fully exploited at this time. Putting It All Together It is in developing countries where accounting based on comprehensive wealth and its changes is most likely to be a useful indicator to guide policy. The evidence in this volume suggests that investments in produced capital, human capital, and governance, combined with saving efforts aimed at offsetting the depletion of natural resources, can lead to future welfare increases in developing countries. The step from saving to investment is crucially important. If investments are not profitable, the effect on wealth is equivalent to consumption, but without the boost to well-being presumed to accompany consumption. XIX EXECUTIVE SUMMARY Achieving the transition from natural-resource dependence to a sustained and balanced growth requires a set of institutions that are capable of managing the natural resource, collecting resource rents, and directing these rents into profitable investments. Resource policy, fiscal policy, and political economy all have a role to play in this transformation. Endnote 1. The largest share, intangible capital, consists of an amalgam of human capital, governance, and other factors that are difficult to value explicitly. XX PART 1 WEALTH ACCOUNTING Chapter 1. Introduction: The Millennium Capital Assessment Chapter 2. The Wealth Stock Estimates Chapter 1 INTRODUCTION: THE MILLENNIUM CAPITAL ASSESSMENT Can poverty reduction be sustained? The end of the 20th century saw a renewed commitment to ending poverty embodied in the Millennium Development Goals. However, deep concerns remained that current rates of depletion and degradation of natural resources may undermine any progress achieved. Achieving sustainable outcomes will require sustaining the total wealth--produced, human, natural--on which development depends. Building on several years of effort, including Expanding the Measure of Wealth (World Bank 1997), this volume assesses the wealth of the planet in the year 2000. In speaking of wealth we are returning to the ideas of the classical economists, who viewed land, labor, and produced capital as the primary factors of production. The chapters that follow detail the levels and changes in these different productive factors across the developing and the developed worlds. This volume represents the most recent achievement in a long-term program to estimate wealth and its components for a large set of countries. It improves the work in Expanding the Measure of Wealth by extending country coverage and by basing the estimation of produced capital and natural capital on a broader set of data. Details on the estimation procedure are provided in appendix 1, while box 1.1 gives a basic exposition of the theory underlying this book. The composition of wealth varies considerably by region and particularly by level of income. While this disparity may be obvious in comparing a mental image of, say, Malawi and Sweden, subsequent chapters measure this variation rigorously by providing figures for nearly 120 countries on the per capita values of agricultural land, minerals, forests, produced WHERE ISTHE WEALTH OF NATIONS? assets, and an aggregate1 termed intangible capital. Intangible capital includes raw labor, human capital, social capital, and other factors such as the quality of institutions. Tables 1.1 and 1.22 present the big picture on the composition and levels of wealth per capita by income group and for the world as a whole.3 Table 1.1 Total Wealth, 2000 -- $ per capita and percentage shares -- Natural Produced Intangible Income Natural Produced Intangible Total capital capital capital group capital capital capital wealth share share share Low-income countries 1,925 1,174 4,434 7,532 26% 16% 59% Middle- income countries 3,496 5,347 18,773 27,616 13% 19% 68% High-income OECD countries 9,531 76,193 353,339 439,063 2% 17% 80% World 4,011 16,850 74,998 95,860 4% 18% 78% Source: Authors. Notes: All dollars at nominal exchange rates. Oil states are excluded. OECD: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development Table 1.2 Natural Capital, 2000 -- $ per capita -- Total Subsoil Timber Protected natural Income group assets resources NTFR Areas Cropland Pastureland capital Low-income countries 325 109 48 111 1,143 189 1,925 Middle-income countries 1,089 169 120 129 1,583 407 3,496 High-income countries (OECD) 3,825 747 183 1,215 2,008 1,552 9,531 World 1,302 252 104 322 1,496 536 4,011 Source: Authors. Notes: NTFR: Nontimber forest resources. Oil states are excluded. 4 CHAPTER 1. INTRODUCTION: THE MILLENNIUM CAPITAL ASSESSMENT If development is approached as a process of portfolio management, then the figures make clear that both the size and composition of the portfolio vary hugely across levels of income. Managing each component of the portfolio well and transforming one form of asset into another most efficiently are key facets of development policy. Changes in real wealth determine future prospects for well-being. Accordingly, an important element of the analysis that follows is the measurement of adjusted net or genuine saving. Estimated saving rates for over 140 countries show that rates of wealth accumulation are much higher in proportion to gross national income (GNI) in rich countries than in poor countries. This is particularly the case when population growth is factored into the analysis. Evidence suggests that higher natural resource dependence coincides with lower genuine saving rates. Chapters 3 and 5 detail these results. While the analysis of wealth sheds light on sustainability, it is also directly relevant to the question of growth. Growth is essential if the poorest countries are to enjoy increases in well-being. However, growth will be illusory if it consists primarily of consuming the assets, such as soil nutrients, that underpin the economy. The linkage between measured changes in real wealth and future well- being only holds if our measures of wealth are suitably comprehensive. This is the prime motivation for expanding the measure of wealth to include a range of natural and intangible capital. This richer picture of the asset base also opens the door to a range of policy interventions that can increase and sustain growth. Where Is the Wealth of Nations? T he total wealth estimates reported here are built upon a combination of top-down and bottom-up approaches. These are presented briefly in the next chapter and detailed in appendix 1. Total wealth, in line with economic theory, is estimated as the present value of future consumption. Produced capital stocks are derived from historical investment data using a perpetual inventory model (PIM).4 Natural resource stock values are based upon country-level data on physical stocks, and estimates of natural 5 WHERE ISTHEWEALTH OF NATIONS? resource rents are based on world prices and local costs. Intangible capital then is measured as the difference between total wealth and the other produced and natural stocks. While table 1.1 reports an average global wealth per capita of roughly $96,000, this average clearly masks huge variety. The results by income group are more informative. Total wealth per capita clearly varies significantly between developed and developing countries.5 Beyond these large ratios are three other facts displayed in table 1.1: · The share of produced assets in total wealth is virtually constant across income groups. · The share of natural capital in total wealth tends to fall with income, while the share of intangible capital rises. · The value of natural capital per capita is substantially higher in rich countries than in poor, while the share of wealth is much lower. The wealth estimates suggest that the preponderant form of wealth is intangible capital, an expected result and an insight that goes back at least to Adam Smith.6 A huge variation in intangible capital per capita occurs across income levels. Taking the ratio of intangible capital to produced capital offers a different insight: this ratio varies from 3.8 in low- income countries to 3.5 in middle-income and 4.6 in high-income--a rather small variation. This suggests that over the course of economic development intangible capital and produced capital are accumulated roughly in the same proportion, with a tendency toward produced capital intensiveness at middle-income levels and intangible capital intensiveness at high-income levels. Does the 2 percent share of natural capital in total wealth for high-income countries mean that natural resources are somehow unimportant in these countries? Table 1.2 suggests not. Per capita values of each of the natural resource categories--subsoil assets, timber and nontimber resources, protected areas, and agricultural land--are higher in rich countries than in poor. What the low natural-capital share suggests is that the development process primarily entails growth in the modern sectors of manufacturing and services, while the primary sectors are relatively static. The estimates of natural wealth presented in this book are also limited by 6 CHAPTER 1. INTRODUCTION: THE MILLENNIUM CAPITAL ASSESSMENT data--for example, fish stocks are not measured in the estimates, while the environmental services that underpin human societies and economies are not measured explicitly. Natural Resources and Development N atural resources are special economic goods because they are not produced. As a consequence, natural resources will yield economic profits--rents--if properly managed. These rents can be an important source of development finance, and countries like Botswana and Malaysia have successfully leveraged natural resources in this way. There are no sustainable diamond mines, but there are sustainable diamond-mining countries. Implicit in this statement is the assumption that it is possible to transform one form of wealth--diamonds in the ground--into other forms of wealth, such as buildings, machines, and human capital. Achieving this transformation requires a set of institutions capable of managing the natural resource, collecting resource rents, and directing these rents into profitable investments. Resource policy, fiscal policy, political factors, institutions, and governance structure all have a role to play in this transformation. Exhaustible resources, once discovered, can only be depleted. Consuming rents from exhaustible resources is, therefore, literally consuming capital, which motivates the Hartwick policy rule for sustaining development-- invest resource rents in other forms of capital. Living resources are unique because they are a potentially sustainable source of resource rents--truly a gift of nature. Sustainable management of these resources will be the optimal policy, but the question of the optimal stock size is complex. For example, clearing forest land for agriculture will be optimal up to the point where the land rent on the marginal cleared hectare is just equal to the total economic value of the standing forest.7 Land resources are potentially sustainable if managed well. Land is particularly important in the poorest countries because it is a direct source of livelihood and sustenance for many poor households. As table 1.2 shows, cropland and pastureland make up 70 percent of natural wealth in low-income countries and 18 percent of total wealth. 7 WHERE ISTHE WEALTH OFNATIONS? Natural resources play two basic roles in development: · The first, mostly applicable to the poorest countries and poorest communities, is the role of local natural resources as the basis of subsistence. · The second is as a source of development finance. Commercial natural resources can be important sources of profit and foreign exchange. Rents on exhaustible, renewable, and potentially sustainable resources can be used to finance investments in other forms of wealth. In the case of exhaustible resources these rents must be invested if total wealth is not to decline. While the preceding discussion has focused on natural goods, chapter 3 will also show the importance of measuring environmental bads in the form of marginal damages from local and global air pollutants. Pollution, which does not appear directly in the wealth stock estimates, is included implicitly in the form of lowered labor productivity linked to ill health. This depresses income generation, limiting consumption, and accordingly, total wealth. From a development perspective a key message from table 1.1 is that natural resources make up a very significant share of the total wealth in low-income countries--26 percent--and that this is substantially larger than the share of produced capital. Sound management of these natural resources can support and sustain the welfare of poor countries, and poor people in poor countries, as they move up the development ladder. Policies and Institutions A major focus in this analysis is on placing economic values on stocks of natural resources and changes in the values of these stocks. This information is used to illuminate the role that natural resources play in development, particularly in poor countries. The analysis suggests that changes in natural resource management are needed to increase economic benefits, and the need for these changes will lead to reforms of policies and institutions. 8 CHAPTER 1. INTRODUCTION: THE MILLENNIUM CAPITAL ASSESSMENT From an economic perspective, inefficiencies in resource exploitation can potentially take the form of under- or overexploitation. In practice, incentives for resource management generally encourage excess exploit- ation, which will depress genuine saving relative to its level under efficient exploitation. Reforming resource management practices can play a signifi- cant role in boosting saving levels in highly resource-dependent economies. Extensive literature exists on policies and institutions for natural resource management, dealing with the very different problems of open- or common-access, exploiting exhaustible resources such as minerals and energy, and managing living resources such as forests and fish. This literature thoroughly explores the roles that different types of policy instruments, property rights, and institutional structures can play in ensuring efficient resource management. This study will not attempt to summarize or add significantly to this literature. However, an important set of institutions--ministries of finance and treasury--often overlooks the analysis of natural resource issues. The fiscal policy implications of natural resource management in developing countries will be explored below. Saving and Investment S aving is a core aspect of development. Without the creation of a surplus for investment, there is no way for countries to escape a state of low-level subsistence. Adjusted net or genuine saving measures the true level of saving in a country after accounting for depreciation of produced capital; investments in human capital (as measured by education expenditures); depletion of minerals, energy, and forests; and damages from local and global air pollutants. Economic theory suggests that current net saving should equal the change in future welfare, specifically the present value of future changes in consumption (Hamilton and Hartwick 2005). Resource dependence complicates the measurement of saving effort because a depletion of natural resources often occurs but is not visible in standard national accounts. As will be seen in chapter 3, the dissaving associated with resource depletion is a particular problem in low-income countries. 9 WHERE ISTHE WEALTH OFNATIONS? The saving tests using historical data reported in chapter 6 suggest that a particular variant of genuine saving--one that excludes education expenditures, damage from carbon dioxide emissions, and the immiserating effects of population growth--is a good predictor of future changes in welfare. Genuine saving is therefore an important indicator to guide development policy. Saving in Developed and Developing Countries The analysis in chapter 6 includes a further key result: When the sample of countries is limited to high-income countries, there is no apparent empirical relationship between current net saving and future welfare. This raises an important distinction between developed and developing countries. It says quite clearly that asset accumulation, the apparent driver of future welfare when all countries are tested, is not a significant factor in rich countries. This result makes eminent sense--in the richest countries it is clear that technological change, institutional innovation, learning by doing, and efficient institutions, to name a few factors, are fundamental drivers of growth. It is in developing countries, therefore, where genuine saving is most likely to be a useful indicator to guide policy. As chapters 3 and 5 will show, the poorest countries have the lowest genuine saving rates. The tests of genuine saving suggest that investments in produced capital, combined with saving efforts aimed at offsetting the depletion of natural resources, can lead to future welfare increases in developing countries. Finally, the step from saving to investment is crucially important. If investments are not profitable, the effect on wealth is equivalent to consumption, but without the boost to well-being presumed to accompany consumption. Fiscal Policy and Comprehensive Wealth E xpanding the measure of wealth to include natural resources raises an important set of fiscal issues concerning revenues, expenditures, fiscal space, boom-and-bust cycles, and the quasi-fiscal impact of state-owned enterprises (SOEs). Dealing with these issues will not likely turn finance 10 CHAPTER 1. INTRODUCTION: THE MILLENNIUM CAPITAL ASSESSMENT ministers into environmentalists, but a sharper focus on the fiscal aspects of natural resources can have a substantial impact on macrobalances and economic performance in many countries. Revenue issues with respect to commercial natural resources are well understood. The government, as the owner of the resource, should be taxing natural resource rents to the point where the private sector is just willing to risk capital in natural resource exploitation. This applies equally to minerals, forests, and fisheries. For forests and fisheries there is the additional concern with sustainability: if sectoral policies encourage overexploitation of the resource, then fiscal revenues from the sector may not be sustained. Finally, there is the issue of rent capture from foreign tourists. If a country's natural resources attract foreign tourists, then taxes on entry and hotels are important instruments for resource rent capture. For government expenditures major questions revolve around the use of resource revenues. In principle, the government should seek to reinvest royalties on exhaustible resources in other assets--thereby maintaining the total wealth of the nation. The caveat to this basic rule is that public investments must be profitable. The issue of profitability may raise questions of absorptive capacity--the capacity of governments to make productive investments--which is typically constrained by the availability of factors such as skilled labor and infrastructure. Countries with significant debts have the option of investing resource rents in debt reduction. Whether this is a good investment depends on the social returns to the best alternative project. In addition, certain types of development expenditures, for example, on national parks, may not appear to be particularly profitable from the treasury's viewpoint; a broader view, though, may suggest that investments in parks will increase tourist sector growth and increase fiscal revenues from tourists. The phenomenon of fiscal boom-and-bust is common for many resource exporters where government revenues are highly dependent on resource royalties. Easy money in the form of resource revenues tempts governments to increase consumption expenditures when commodity prices are buoyant. These expenditures are often difficult to rein in when the inevitable commodity bust arrives, leading to major fiscal imbalances. Generally, investing resource rents requires a system to help governments stabilize resource revenues, as well as instruments, such as medium-term expenditure frameworks, to control expenditures. 11 WHERE ISTHE WEALTH OF NATIONS? Comprehensive wealth accounts offer new insights into the question of fiscal space, that is, the ability of the government to increase expenditure without jeopardizing its ability to service its debt. Generally, the measure of a government's change in fiscal stance is the change in its net worth. This suggests that tax revenues from exhaustible resources do not fully increase fiscal space because a portion of these taxes represents the consumption of natural capital. While the news that fiscal space is not as large as conventionally measured will not be welcomed by most treasuries, prudent governments will heed the bad news. SOEs are common in the resource sectors and present quasi-fiscal risks of their own. The low efficiency of these enterprises may lead to the growth of liabilities. If the enterprises are off-budget, then these contingent fiscal liabilities are typically not factored into the government's fiscal stance. If the enterprises are on-budget, then they often do not have retained earnings out of which to finance capital expenditures; the result is that the investment needs of the SOE become part of the government development budget. In this case there is a risk of undercapitalization of SOEs. Botswana provides an example of sound management of many of these fiscal issues with respect to its diamond wealth. The treasury calculates a sustainable budget index to determine whether consumption expenditures are being financed out of resource rents and adjusts expenditures accordingly. It also holds diamond revenues offshore in order to deal with issues of absorptive capacity, revenue stabilization, and Dutch disease effects from currency appreciation. Investing in the Intangible Capital Residual F rom a policy perspective a potential problem may arise with calculating such a large intangible capital residual. Since the residual necessarily includes a wide array of less-tangible assets--for example, raw labor, human capital, social capital, or quality of institutions--it raises the question of whether virtually any component of public spending could be considered to be a type of investment. To explore this question using cross-sectional data, chapter 7 estimates the major factors contributing to the intangible capital residual, and tables 1.3 and 1.4 present some key results. 12 CHAPTER 1. INTRODUCTION: THE MILLENNIUM CAPITAL ASSESSMENT Table 1.3 Factors Explaining the Intangible Capital Residual Factor Elasticity School years per capita 0.53 R-squared 0.89 Rule of law index 0.83 Remittances per capita 0.12 Source: Authors. Note: Coefficients are significant at the 5 percent level. Table 1.4 Marginal Returns to Different Factors School years Remittances Income group per capita Rule of law index per capita Low-income countries 838 111 29 Middle-income countries 1,954 404 39 High-income countries (OECD) 16,430 2,973 306 Source: Authors. Note: Figures represent the increase in the intangible capital residual associated with a 1-unit increase in the given factor. Any model of the intangible residual must include only factors that are not already captured in the value of produced capital and natural resources, since these have been subtracted from total wealth in order to calculate the residual. Table 1.3 shows that three such factors--average years of schooling per capita, rule of law, and remittances received per capita--explain 89 percent of the total variation in the residual across countries. Policy makers, therefore, can be reasonably confident that investments in education and the justice system, as well as policies aimed at attracting remittances, are the most important means of increasing the intangible- capital component of total wealth. The elasticities reported in table 1.3 show that, on average, for all countries a 1 percent increase in rule of law pays large dividends, boosting intangible capital by 0.83 percent; 1 percent increases in the stock of schooling or remittances per capita will increase intangible capital by 0.53 percent and 0.12 percent, respectively. Table 1.4 reports the marginal returns, measured at the mean, to unit increases in the three factors for each level of income. Increasing the 13 WHERE ISTHEWEALTH OF NATIONS? average stock of schooling by one year per person increases total wealth per capita by nearly $840 in low-income countries; nearly $2,000 in middle-income countries; and over $16,000 in high-income countries. The wide range reflects the gearing effect of having larger stocks of produced capital at higher-income levels, as well as the use of nominal exchange rates. A one-point increase in the rule of law index (on a 100-point scale) boosts total wealth by over $100 in low-income countries, over $400 in middle-income countries, and nearly $3,000 in high-income countries. Setting aside the smallest factor, remittances, it is worth considering how finance ministries can invest in the factors explaining the intangible capital aggregate. Education expenditure can obviously play a role, but these expenditures have to be effective in actually creating human capital. Investing in rule of law is clearly complex. Issues of judicial salaries, for example, can be important. However, the larger problem is building trusted, competent legal institutions, thereby creating confidence in the minds of citizens and entrepreneurs that their rights will be protected. The returns to doing so, reported in chapter 7, are potentially very large. Conclusions T he notion of development as portfolio management is powerful. Certain assets in the portfolio are exhaustible and can only be transformed into other productive assets, such as infrastructure or human capital, through investment of the resource rents. Other assets are renewable and can yield sustainable income streams. Economic analysis can guide decisions concerning the optimal size of these assets in the portfolio. Some assets, such as produced capital, depreciate over time. National savings can be used to invest in natural assets, produced capital, or human capital. The choice of investment will depend on the asset with the highest marginal return on investment, a standard tenet of public finance. Each year from 10 to 20 developing countries have negative genuine saving rates. What should the policy response be? Monetary and fiscal policies affect saving behavior, and public sector dissaving can be a key target of policy. If investment in human capital is measured as saving, then efforts to increase effective education expenditures can boost overall 14 CHAPTER 1. INTRODUCTION: THE MILLENNIUM CAPITAL ASSESSMENT saving. For natural resources the general prescription is not to simply reduce exploitation, but rather to reduce incentives for overexploitation, which will typically entail reforms in the resource sectors. The evidence presented in subsequent chapters shows that low or negative saving is primarily an issue in low-income countries and some resource-dependent middle-income countries. For resource-dependent middle-income countries, negative saving is almost always a reflection of excessive government consumption expenditure. Conversely, for the poorest countries a prescription to boost saving by reducing consumption is clearly unpalatable. A better policy response is to boost the productivity of all assets, including resource assets, in these countries through policy and institutional reforms, leading to a cycle of rising consumption and saving. BOX 1.1 The Theory of Wealth, Welfare, and Sustainable Development Wealth, welfare, and sustainability are closely interlinked. Pezzey (1989) suggested a straightforward definition of sustainability: a development path is sustainable if utility does not decline at any point along the path. Dasgupta (2001) offers a more general definition: a development path is sustainable if social welfare does not decline at any point along the path. Social welfare is in turn defined to be the present value of utility along the development path--it is a measure of intertemporal wellbeing. While a useful concept, utility is not directly observable.This raises a measurement challenge: can we define an index of measurable quantities that can be shown to be related to social welfare? The suggestion that total wealth can provide such a measure is presented in Samuelson (1961): "...the only valid approximation to a measure of welfare comes from computing wealth-like magnitudes not income magnitudes." According to Samuelson, the work of Irving Fisher (1906) pointed the way: current wealth should equal the present value of future consumption. Hamilton and Hartwick (2005) show that the sum of the values of a heterogeneous set of assets (total wealth) is equal to the present value of future consumption. These notions of wealth and welfare underpin the basic calculation of total wealth in this book. It follows that if total wealth is related to social welfare, then changes in wealth should have implications for sustainability--this is the basic intuition of Pearce 15 WHERE ISTHEWEALTH OF NATIONS? and Atkinson (1993). For optimal economies, economies where a planner can enforce the maximization of social welfare, a number of results have made the link explicit (it is implicit in Weitzman [1976], but not derived).Aronsson and others (1997, equation 6.18) show that net saving in utility units is equal to the present value of changes in utility, using a time-varying pure rate of time preference. Hamilton and Clemens (1999) show that net or `genuine' saving adjusted for resource depletion, stock pollutant damages, and human capital accumulation is equal to the change in social welfare measured in dollars; they also establish that negative genuine saving implies that future utility must be less than current utility over some interval of time. This motivates the focus on savings in chapter 3 below. These results depend on the assumption that governments maximize social welfare. Dasgupta and Mäler (2000) show that net investment is equal to the change in social welfare in a nonoptimizing framework where a resource allocation mechanism is used to specify the mapping from initial capital stocks to future stocks and flows in the economy. This result depends on accounting prices for assets being defined as the marginal changes in social welfare resulting from an increment in each asset (that is, accounting prices are the partial derivatives of the social welfare function). Arrow and others (2003a) explore the accounting issues under a variety of resource allocation mechanisms. In this book resource stocks and resource depletion are valued using world prices and local costs of extraction and harvest. The use of border prices is consistent with how projects would be evaluated using social cost-benefit analysis, but it is not explicitly linked either to assumptions about optimality or to any specific resource allocation mechanism as in Dasgupta and Mäler (2000). Hartwick (1977) provided the canonical rule for sustainability in resource- dependent economies­if genuine saving is set equal to zero at each point in time (that is, traditional net saving just equals resource depletion), then consumption can be maintained indefinitely, even in the face of finite resources and fixed technology. Hamilton and others (forthcoming) show that this can be generalized to a rule with constant positive genuine saving; such a rule will yield unbounded consumption. Chapter 4 calculates countries' produced capital stocks under the alternative Hartwick rules during 1970­2000; these calculations are then compared with actual year 2000 capital stocks. If population grows over time, as in virtually all developing countries, then changes in total wealth should take into account the change in population. Dasgupta (2001) shows that wealth per capita is the correct measure of social 16 CHAPTER 1. INTRODUCTION: THE MILLENNIUM CAPITAL ASSESSMENT welfare if certain conditions are met: (i) population grows at a constant rate; (ii) per capita consumption is independent of population size; and (iii) production exhibits constant returns to scale. This book calculates wealth per capita as the measure of social well-being under these assumptions, as do Arrow and others (2004). The measure of the change in wealth per capita derived in chapter 5 below includes a specific adjustment for the immiserating effects of population growth. Arrow and others (2003b) identify the correct welfare index in more general situations. Finally, the result linking net saving to changes in social welfare in Aronsson and others (1997) can be extended to show that current saving equals the present value of changes in consumption in an optimizing economy. Dasgupta (2001) shows that the same is true in nonoptimal economies where accounting prices are defined as above. Hamilton and Hartwick (2005) show that this relationship holds in an optimal economy, but their proof clearly only requires that the economy be competitive. This relationship between current saving and the present value of future changes in consumption is exploited in an empirical test of genuine saving in chapter 6. Endnotes 1. Intangible capital includes raw labor, human capital, social capital, and other important factors such as the quality of institutions. 2. All references to dollars ($) are in U.S. dollars. 3. Oil states (where oil rents exceed 20 percent of GNI) are excluded and are discussed separately in later chapters. The very large resource endowments of these countries make them outliers in the analysis of wealth. 4. Pritchett (2000) argues that cumulating investments in this way is likely to overstate the value of capital stocks in developing countries, because the method does not account for the profitability of these investments. 5. The use of nominal exchange rates explains part of the high variation. Purchasing Power Parities (PPP) are typically used to compare welfare between developed and developing countries. Welfare measurement is not the prime concern in this volume, where the focus is on variation in the composition of wealth across income levels, changes in wealth, and the role of natural assets in development. 17 WHERE ISTHE WEALTH OF NATIONS? 6. In An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, Adam Smith (1776) wrote: "The annual labour of every nation is the fund which originally supplies it with all the necessaries and conveniences of life which it annually consumes." Smith recognized "the skill, dexterity, and judgment with which [. . .] labour is generally applied" as a precondition for generating supply "whatever be the soil, climate, or extent of territory of any particular nation." 7. Total economic value in this instance would include the rents on sustainable timber and nontimber off-take, value of carbon sequestration, and local (and potentially global) willingness to pay for the external services that forests provide. 18 Chapter 2 THE WEALTH STOCK ESTIMATES What constitutes wealth? Traditionally attention has been focused on produced capital such as buildings, machinery, equipment, and infrastructure. The wealth estimates introduced below extend these measures by accounting for exhaustible resources, renewable resources, and agricultural land. The estimates also include intangible capital, which encompasses raw labor, human capital (the stock of human skills and know-how), social capital, and the quality of institutions. Economic theory tells us that there is a strong link between changes in wealth and the sustainability of development--if a country (or a household, for that matter) is running down its assets, it is not on a sustainable path. For the link to hold, however, the notion of wealth must be truly comprehensive. This is a major motivation for expanding the measure of wealth. We are also interested in several basic questions concerning the wealth of nations: · What is the most important component of wealth across countries? · How do the shares of different types of wealth vary with income? Does the value of natural wealth increase or decrease as countries develop? These and other questions are examined below. This chapter presents wealth stock estimates for 120 developing and developed countries for the year 2000. The details of the wealth estimation procedure and country-level data can be found in Appendixes 1 and 2. WHERE ISTHE WEALTH OF NATIONS? The Richest and the Poorest A ggregate wealth estimates are presented in tables 2.1 and 2.2, which highlight the 10 wealthiest and poorest countries. The results are hardly surprising. Switzerland heads a list in which the top performers are all Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) countries. European countries--two in Scandinavia--dominate the list along with the United States and Japan. The composition of wealth is very consistent across these countries, with the exception of Norway and Japan. Norway's natural capital, which includes oil and gas resources from the North Sea, accounts for 12 percent of total wealth. Japan stands out for its large share of produced capital--30 percent of the total. The list of the 10 poorest countries is presented in table 2.2. If Europe heads the top-10 list, Sub-Saharan Africa dominates the bottom-10 list. Countries in table 2.2 are characterized by high levels of natural capital-- at least 25 percent of the total. Ethiopia has the lowest level of total wealth, combined with a very low share of produced capital. A similar pattern can be observed in Burundi, Niger, Chad, and Madagascar. Nepal is the only country in the table that is not in Sub-Saharan Africa. Table 2.1 Total Wealth: Top-10 Countries, 2000 Country (descending order of Wealth per Natural Produced Intangible per capita wealth) capita ($) capital (%) capital (%) capital (%) Switzerland 648,241 1 15 84 Denmark 575,138 2 14 84 Sweden 513,424 2 11 87 United States 512,612 3 16 82 Germany 496,447 1 14 85 Japan 493,241 0 30 69 Austria 493,080 1 15 84 Norway 473,708 12 25 63 France 468,024 1 12 86 Belgium-Luxembourg 451,714 1 13 86 Source: Authors. 20 CHAPTER 2. THE WEALTH STOCK ESTIMATES Table 2.2 Total Wealth: Bottom-10 Countries, 2000 Country (descending order of Wealth per Natural Produced Intangible per capita wealth) capita ($) capital (%) capital (%) capital (%) Madagascar 5,020 33 8 59 Chad 4,458 42 6 52 Mozambique 4,232 25 11 64 Guinea-Bissau 3,974 47 14 39 Nepal 3,802 32 16 52 Niger 3,695 53 8 39 Congo, Rep. of 3,516 265 180 ­346 Burundi 2,859 42 7 50 Nigeria 2,748 147 24 ­71 Ethiopia 1,965 41 9 50 Source: Authors. Intangible capital appears with a negative sign in some instances, which is an empirical possibility given that it is calculated as a residual--the difference between total wealth and the sum of natural and produced resources. Box 2.1 explores what it means to have a negative intangible capital residual. The Architecture of the Wealth Estimates M easuring capital stocks is a complex task. Capital can be valued using two basic methods: · It can be valued as the sum of the additions, minus the subtractions, made over time to an initial stock--summing up the value of gross investments and subtracting depreciation of produced capital, for example. · Alternatively, capital can be valued as the net present value (NPV) of the income it is able to produce over time. This is what an investor would be willing to pay for a capital good. As a practical matter we employ the first method, also called the perpetual inventory method (PIM), to estimate the value of produced capital stocks, 21 WHERE ISTHE WEALTH OF NATIONS? Figure 2.1 Estimating the Components of Wealth Total Intangible wealth capital measured by: NPV Prot. areas Natural measured by: capital Opportunity cost Forest resources measured by: NPV Sub-soil assets measured by: NPV Agriculture land measured by: NPV Urban land Produced Produced measured capital capital indirectly Structures Structures, measured by: equipment PIM and machinery Equipment measured by: PIM Step 1 Step 2 Step 3 Step 4 Step 5 Equipment Urban land Natural Total Intangible and structures capital wealth capital while the second method is used to value stocks of natural resources. Figure 2.1 represents the steps in estimating wealth components. Produced capital is the sum of machinery, equipment, and structures (including infrastructure). Urban land is not considered to be a natural resource, and so is lumped in with produced capital in the wealth estimates. The value of urban land is calculated as a percentage of the value of machinery, equipment, and structures. 22 CHAPTER 2. THE WEALTH STOCK ESTIMATES Natural capital is the sum of nonrenewable resources (including oil, natural gas, coal, and mineral resources), cropland, pastureland, forested areas (including areas used for timber extraction and nontimber forest products), and protected areas. The values for nontimber forest resources and protected areas are estimated only crudely. In the case of nontimber forest products, world average values of benefits per hectare, distinguishing developed and developing countries, are applied to a share of the country's forested area (values are derived from Lampietti and Dixon 1995). Protected areas are valued using country-specific per-hectare values for cropland or pastureland (whichever is lower). This severely undervalues the Serengeti Plain, for example, but possibly overvalues some of the Arctic parks. As noted above, most natural resources are valued by taking the present value of resource rents--the economic profit on exploitation--over an assumed lifetime. While forests can, in principle, yield benefits forever if sustainably managed, we account for overexploitation by calculating the effective lifetime of the resource given current harvest rates. The next step is the measurement of total wealth. Measuring total wealth as the sum of its components makes intuitive sense, but this is limited by data and methodological constraints. We have few good tools for valuing human capital, for example, and even fewer for valuing social or institutional capital. In other cases, such as fisheries, we simply lack data. The alternative is to rely on economic theory, which defines total wealth as the net present value of future consumption. We therefore measure total wealth by assuming a future consumption stream and calculating the net present value in year 2000. However, some countries have unsustainable levels of consumption, which is signaled by negative net or genuine saving levels (see chapter 3). In these cases consumption is decreased by the amount of negative saving in order to arrive at a sustainable level of consumption. Intangible capital is calculated as a residual, the difference between total wealth and the sum of produced and natural capital. Since it includes all assets that are neither natural nor produced, the residual necessarily includes human capital--the sum of knowledge, skills, and know-how possessed by the population. It also includes the institutional infrastructure of the country as well as the social capital--the level of trust among people in a society and their ability to work together toward common goals. Finally, the residual includes net foreign financial assets through the returns generated by these assets. For example, if a country is a debtor, then interest payments on the foreign debt depress consumption, reducing total wealth and therefore the intangible residual. 23 WHERE ISTHEWEALTH OF NATIONS? A special caveat applies to natural capital. While the wealth estimates include a large number of assets, the exercise is far from perfect. Assets for which data are lacking include subsoil water, diamonds, and fisheries. To the extent that countries profit from these resources, their value is implicitly included in the total wealth aggregate and, hence, ends up in the intangible capital residual. The services provided by ecosystems, such as the hydrological functions of forests and the pollination services of insects and birds, are indirectly captured in the natural wealth estimates through the values of cropland and pastureland, but no explicit value for ecosystem services is estimated, owing to data limitations. Figure 2.2 summarizes what is captured and what is not in the wealth estimates. Figure 2.2 The Inclusion of Environment and Natural Resources in the Wealth Estimates Measured Measured Not directly indirectly measured Subsoil Protected Water Fisheries assets areas resources Crop- and Forest Ecosystem Diamonds pastureland products services Natural Estimation capital Intangible capital residual Produced capital 24 CHAPTER 2. THE WEALTH STOCK ESTIMATES The lack of data on fisheries may be particularly important in a number of countries. Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations (FAO) figures show that the roughly 90 million tons of captured fish have a landed value of $78 billion annually. The export value of the total world trade of fish and fisheries products (including aquaculture) was $58.2 billion in 2002. Half of this value comes from developing countries, many of which also generate substantial additional income from licensing foreign access to their fisheries. Similarly, missing data on diamonds has a serious impact on the wealth accounts of countries such as Botswana. Lange and others (2003) report diamond wealth of $7,400 per capita in Botswana in 1997. This would increase Botswana's value of natural capital to roughly $10,600 per person (25 percent of the total), and reduce intangible capital to about $21,000 (52 percent of the total). Since many wealth components are estimated as a net present value of a flow of benefits, the calculations require assumptions regarding the time horizon and the discount rate. Throughout the calculations, we assumed a time horizon of 25 years, which coincides roughly with a human generation. So, for example, total wealth is calculated as the net present value of sustainable consumption from the year 2000 to 2025. With respect to discounting, since the focus is on sustainable development, the discount rate used is the one a government would choose in allocating resources across generations. This is an argument in favor of using a social discount rate instead of a private discount rate. Estimates of the Social Rate of Return on Investment (SRRI--another name for the social discount rate) for industrialized countries report values between 2 and 4 percent (Pearce and Ulph 1999). We assume an SRRI at the upper limit, 4 percent. This would likely be too low for fast-growing economies such as China, while being high for slow-growing economies in Sub-Saharan Africa. We choose a single discount rate for all countries in order to facilitate comparisons. What the Data Reveal H aving explained the methods and caveats in the estimation of wealth, the remainder of the chapter is devoted to an overview of the wealth estimates. Subsequent chapters deal with specific aspects and go deeper into the 25 WHERE ISTHE WEALTH OF NATIONS? Table 2.3 Wealth per Capita by Region and Income Group, 2000 $ per capita % share of total wealth Total Natural Produced Intangible Natural Produced Intangible Region wealth capital capital capital capital capital capital Latin America and 67,955 8,059 10,830 49,066 12 16 72 the Caribbean Sub-Saharan Africa 10,730 2,535 1,449 6,746 24 13 63 South Asia 6,906 1,749 1,115 4,043 25 16 59 East Asia and the 11,958 2,511 3,189 6,258 21 27 52 Pacific Middle East and 22,186 7,989 4,448 9,749 36 20 44 North Africa Europe and 40,209 11,031 12,299 16,880 27 31 42 Central Asia Income group Low-income 7,216 2,075 1,150 3,991 29 16 55 countries Lower-middle- 23,612 4,398 4,962 14,253 19 21 60 income countries Upper-middle- 72,897 10,921 16,481 45,495 15 23 62 income countries High-income 439,063 9,531 76,193 353,339 2 17 80 OECD countries World 90,210 4,681 16,160 69,369 5 18 77 Source: Authors. Note: The data in this table include oil-exporting countries. analysis. The discussion here is focused on the estimates aggregated by region and income group, while appendix 2 provides the country-level estimates. Table 2.3 summarizes total wealth by region and income group. Worldwide, natural capital accounts for 5 percent of total wealth, produced capital for 18 percent, and intangible capital 77 percent. The average world citizen has a total wealth of $90,000, an amount similar to the per capita wealth of Brazil ($87,000), Libya ($89,000), or Croatia ($91,000). Most of this wealth is in the form of intangible capital. Tangible assets include produced capital, totaling $16,000, and natural capital, $5,000. Natural capital is dominated by land resources (cropland, pastureland, and protected areas), which constitute 51 percent of total natural resources (see table 2.4, where natural wealth is broken down into its components). Subsoil assets account for 41 percent, and timber and nontimber forest resources account for the remaining 8 percent of natural capital. 26 CHAPTER 2. THE WEALTH STOCK ESTIMATES Table 2.4 The Composition of Natural Capital by Region and Income Group, 2000 Natural Subsoil Timber Region capital assets resources NTFR PA Cropland Pastureland Latin America and 8,059 3,845 359 424 411 1,942 1,077 the Caribbean 48% 4% 5% 5% 24% 13% Sub-Saharan Africa 2,535 979 225 129 64 925 213 39% 9% 5% 3% 36% 8% South Asia 1,749 189 53 13 109 1,183 202 11% 3% 1% 6% 68% 12% East Asia and the 2,511 710 140 43 79 1,415 125 Pacific 28% 6% 2% 3% 56% 5% Middle East and 7,989 6,002 14 14 58 1,510 390 North Africa 75% 0% 0% 1% 19% 5% Europe and Central 11,031 6,532 225 688 779 1,622 1,185 Asia 59% 2% 6% 7% 15% 11% Income group Low-Income 2,075 487 119 49 104 1,134 182 countries 23% 6% 2% 5% 55% 9% Lower-middle-income 4,398 1,933 159 182 189 1,526 409 countries 44% 4% 4% 4% 35% 9% Upper-middle-income 10,921 7,031 265 206 463 1,872 1,084 countries 64% 2% 2% 4% 17% 10% High-income OECD 9,531 3,825 747 183 1,215 2,008 1,552 countries 40% 8% 2% 13% 21% 16% World 4,681 1,933 247 134 343 1,477 547 41% 5% 3% 7% 32% 12% Source: Authors. Note: The data in this table include oil-exporting countries. NTFR: Nontimber forest resources. PA: Protected areas. Figures are in dollars per capita and in percents. Of course, using world averages obscures important differences. The level of total wealth per capita and the distribution of different types of wealth vary hugely across regions and income groups. Table 2.4 shows that endowments of natural capital vary substantially across regions of the world. Subsoil assets abound in the Middle East and North Africa, Europe and Central Asia, and Latin America and the Caribbean. Agricultural land (cropland plus pastureland) has a relatively high importance in East Asia and the Pacific, South Asia, and Sub- Saharan Africa. From this broad analysis of the wealth estimates a few stylized facts emerge. 27 WHERE ISTHEWEALTH OF NATIONS? Intangible Capital Is the Largest Share of Total Wealth T he most striking aspect of the wealth estimates is the high values for intangible capital. Nearly 85 percent of the countries in our sample have an intangible capital share of total wealth greater than 50 percent. This outcome validates the classical economists' intuition that human capital and other intangibles play a major role in economic development. Intangible capital varies widely across income groups and across regions. In the developing world, the Latin America and the Caribbean region has the highest level of intangible capital, $49,000 per capita. The lowest levels are in South Asia, $4,000 per capita, and Sub-Saharan Africa, less than $7,000 per capita. Chapter 7 uses a production function framework to divide the intangible capital residual into the components that explain its variation across countries. Human capital (measured through years of schooling) and governance (measured through a rule of law index) together explain nearly 90 percent of the variation in intangible capital. Intangible capital comprises 80 percent of the total wealth in high-income countries. It is close to zero, and often negative, in major oil exporters such as Nigeria, Algeria, and Venezuela. What is special about oil states? Box 2.1 analyzes this issue. Box 2.1 Why a Negative Level of Intangible Capital As seen in table 2.2 in appendix 2, a number of countries appear to have negative levels of intangible capital. This is the case for the Republic of Congo, Nigeria, Algeria, the Syrian Arab Republic, and Gabon. Although positive, very low levels of intangible capital are estimated for República Bolivariana de Venezuela, Moldova, Guyana, and the Russian Federation (see table on the next page). A negative level of intangible capital is possible by construction because it is calculated as a residual--the difference between total wealth (the present value of future consumption) and the sum of produced and natural capital. The real question is how to interpret a negative or extremely low value of intangible capital. 28 CHAPTER 2. THE WEALTH STOCK ESTIMATES Intangible Capital and the Composition of Wealth in Highly Resource-Dependent Countries Percentage share of total wealth Intangible capital Natural Produced Intangible Country per capita ($) capital capital capital Russian Federation 6,029 44 40 16 Guyana 2,176 65 21 14 Moldova 1,173 37 49 13 Venezuela, R. B. de 4,360 60 30 10 Gabon ­3,215 66 41 ­7 Syrian Arab Rep. ­1,598 84 32 ­15 Algeria ­3,418 71 47 ­18 Nigeria ­1,959 147 24 ­71 Congo, Rep. of ­12,158 265 180 ­346 Source: Authors. Recall that total wealth is the present value of sustainable consumption. What the low and negative values of intangible capital are really saying is that the level of GNI is too low in these countries. If it were higher, then higher levels of consumption per capita could be sustained and both total wealth and intangible wealth would be higher. GNI is too low in these countries in the sense that they are achieving extremely low rates of return on their produced, human, and institutional capital. This is a classic symptom of the resource curse as documented by Auty (2001) and Gylfason (2001). Lower Shares but Higher Levels of Natural Capital in Richer Countries H igh-income countries have a relatively low ratio of natural resources to total assets compared with poorer countries. Is income in poorer countries constrained by a high level of natural-resource dependence? Without further analysis it is not possible to draw a general conclusion regarding the causal link between asset composition and income. The fact 29 WHERE ISTHEWEALTH OFNATIONS? that lower-income countries are more dependent on natural resources than their richer peers seems to be an intrinsic feature of the development process. While rich countries clearly were more heavily forested and had more abundant wildlife and fish resources in the past, it is striking that the value of natural capital per person is higher today in high-income countries than in low- and middle-income countries. In high-income countries it is likely that preferences linked to higher incomes are playing a key role in fostering more careful management of natural capital, while higher levels of other forms of capital may interact positively with the value of natural capital--specialized knowledge and greater mechanization, for example, boosts the yields on cropland in rich countries compared with the yields in poor countries. Poorer Countries Rely on Land Resources G iven the importance of natural capital in the wealth of poor countries, the individual subcomponents merit consideration. Excluding large oil-exporting countries, land resources are very important in low-income countries, with a 75 percent share of natural wealth (69 percent consisting of cropland and pastureland), followed by subsoil assets at 17 percent. By comparison, in middle-income countries land resources account for 61 percent of natural capital, while subsoil assets account for 31 percent. Figure 2.3 summarizes these findings. The importance of land resources (cropland, pastureland, and protected areas) decreases with the level of income. This suggests a potential poverty-land-dependence trap in low-income countries. Countries in which land resources account for more than one third of total wealth, such as Niger, Burundi, and Moldova, all belong to the low-income country group. By contrast, low-income countries, as a group, are not particularly dependent on subsoil assets. Countries rich in mineral and energy resources may be found in each of the income groups. 30 CHAPTER 2. THE WEALTH STOCK ESTIMATES Figure 2.3 The Composition of Natural Capital (High Oil Exporters Excluded) 100 90 80 50% 70 61% 75% 60 50 10% Percentage 40 8% 30 20 8% 40% 31% 10 17% 0 Low-income countries Middle-income countries High-income countries Subsoil Timber Land Source: Authors. Key Conclusions on Wealth T he ranking of countries by total wealth per capita in appendix 2 does not differ hugely from the ranking by gross domestic product (GDP) per capita. It would be surprising if it did, since GDP is the return on total wealth. There are important exceptions to this, particularly the highly resource-dependent economies featured in box 2.1. But the primary interest in measuring wealth is not to rank countries. It is to better understand the composition of wealth and how this composition varies across levels of income. The main conclusions from the wealth analysis include: · Low-income countries are highly dependent on natural resources. The share of natural capital is greater than the share of produced capital in these countries. · Cropland and pastureland is the largest share, nearly 70 percent, of natural wealth in poor countries (excluding oil exporters). 31 WHERE ISTHEWEALTH OF NATIONS? · Overall, intangible capital is the preponderant share of wealth in virtually all countries, with the share increasing with income. The particularly inefficient use of produced and intangible assets in the most resource-dependent economies leads to the anomalous result of apparently negative shares of intangible capital in these economies. · The level of natural wealth per capita actually rises with income. This contradicts the common assumption, that development necessarily entails the depletion of the environment and natural resources. The declining share of natural wealth as income increases is not an argument that natural resources are somehow unimportant--food, fiber, timber, minerals, and energy are all plainly needed to sustain lives and economies, but it does indicate a decline in relative importance. The key point is that low-income countries are highly dependent on natural resources now. How these resources are managed will affect both current welfare and the prospects for development in poor countries. 32 PART 2 CHANGES IN WEALTH Chapter 3. Recent Genuine Saving Estimates Chapter 4. The Importance of Investing Resource Rents: A Hartwick Rule Counterfactual Chapter 5. The Importance of Population Dynamics: Changes in Wealth per Capita Chapter 6. Testing Genuine Saving Chapter 3 RECENT GENUINE SAVING ESTIMATES However sustainable development is defined,1 achieving it is, at heart, the process of maintaining wealth for future generations. Wealth is conceived broadly to include not only the traditional measures of capital, such as produced and human capital, but also natural assets. Natural capital comprises assets such as land, forests, and subsoil resources. All three types of capital--produced, human, and natural--are key inputs to sustaining economic growth. The standard national accounts measure the change in a country's wealth by focusing solely on produced assets. A country's provision for the future is measured by its gross national saving, which represents the total amount of produced output that is not consumed. Gross national saving, however, can say little about sustainable development, since assets depreciate over time. Net national saving equals gross national saving minus depreciation of fixed capital and is one step closer to measuring sustainability. The next step in measuring sustainability is to adjust net saving for the accumulation of other assets--human capital, the environment, and natural resources--that underpin development. This chapter introduces the concept of genuine saving (formally known as adjusted net saving) first derived in Pearce and Atkinson (1993) and Hamilton (1994). It then presents and discusses the empirical calculations of genuine saving rates available for over 140 countries (tabulated in appendix 3). Genuine saving provides a much broader indicator of sustainability by valuing changes in natural resources, environmental quality, and human capital, in addition to the traditional measure of changes in produced assets provided by net saving. WHERE ISTHEWEALTH OF NATIONS? Negative genuine saving rates imply that total wealth is in decline; policies leading to persistently negative genuine saving are unsustainable. In addition to serving as an indicator of sustainability, genuine saving has the advantage of presenting resource and environmental issues within a framework that finance and development planning ministries can understand. It makes the growth-environment trade-off explicit, since those countries pursuing economic growth today, at the expense of natural resources, will be notable by their depressed rates of genuine saving. Of the 140 countries where genuine saving is estimated for 2003, just over 30 have negative saving rates. Calculating Genuine Saving F igure 3.1 provides a flow chart describing each of the main steps in the genuine saving calculation. Starting at the top of figure 3.1, the calculation of genuine saving begins with gross national saving. Gross national saving is calculated as the difference between the gross national income (GNI) and public and private consumption plus net current transfers. From this the consumption of fixed capital is subtracted, giving the traditional measure of net national saving. Consumption of fixed capital represents the replacement value of capital used up in the process of production. In the traditional measure of net national saving only that portion of total expenditure on education that goes toward fixed capital (such as school buildings) is included as a part of saving; the rest is treated as consumption. From the perspective of broadening the measure of wealth this is clearly unsatisfactory. Therefore, as a crude approximation, current operating expenditures on education, including wages and salaries and excluding capital investments in buildings and equipment, are added to net national saving.2 Natural resource depletion is then subtracted. The value of resource depletion is calculated as the total rents on resource extraction and harvest, where rents are estimated as the difference between the value of production at world prices and total costs of production, including depreciation of fixed capital and return on capital. The energy resources include oil, natural gas, and coal, while metals and minerals include bauxite, copper, gold, iron ore, lead, nickel, phosphate, silver, tin, and zinc. 36 CHAPTER 3. RECENT GENUINE SAVING ESTIMATES Figure 3.1 Flow Chart of Genuine Saving Calculation Gross national saving From gross national saving the consumption of fixed capital is subtracted to give the traditional indicator of saving: net national savings. Net national saving Current operating expenditures on education are added to net national saving to adjust for investments in human capital. The value of natural resource depletion is subtracted. Energy, metals, minerals, and net forest depletion are included. The value of damages from pollutants is subtracted. The pollutants carbon dioxide and particulate matter are included. Genuine saving As a living resource, forest resources are fundamentally different from energy, metals, and minerals. The correction to the net saving rate is thus not simply rent on timber extraction, but rather rent on that portion of timber extraction that exceeds natural growth. If growth exceeds harvest, this figure is set to zero. The genuine saving calculation also includes the value of damages from air pollution. Pollution damages can enter the national accounts in several ways. While, in theory, pollution damage to produced assets is included in depreciation figures, in practice, most statistical systems are not detailed enough to capture this. For example, acid rain damages to building materials are rarely fully accounted. The effects of pollution 37 WHERE ISTHEWEALTH OFNATIONS? on output--damage to crops, for example--are already included in the standard national accounts, although not explicitly. Next is the adjustment for damages from carbon dioxide, using a figure for marginal global damages of $20 (1995 prices) per metric ton of carbon emitted (Fankhauser 1994).3 This represents the present value of marginal damages to crops, infrastructure, and human health over the time that emitted carbon dioxide resides in the atmosphere--over 100 years. Finally, the value of health damages arising from particulate matter pollution is deducted. Particulate air pollution is capable of penetrating deep into the respiratory tract and causing damage, including premature mortality. The population-weighted average level of PM10 (particulate matter less than 10 microns in diameter) is estimated for all cities in each country with a population in excess of 100,000. Particulate emission damage is calculated as the willingness to pay to reduce the risk of mortality attributable to PM10 (Pandey and others 2005). The net result of all these adjustments is genuine saving. Interpreting Genuine Saving Estimates W elfare can be sustained indefinitely if gross saving just equals the sum of depreciation of produced assets, depletion of natural resources, and pollution damages. This is the well-known Hartwick rule. A persistently negative genuine saving rate implies that a country is on an unsustainable path and welfare must fall in the future. However, we should be cautious in interpreting a positive genuine saving rate. There are some important assets omitted from the analysis for methodological and empirical reasons, which may mean that saving rates are only apparently positive. First, fisheries can be a significant resource for a local or national economy. However, it can be very difficult to measure fish stocks and to attribute ownership to one country, not least because of their mobility. Soil erosion is another important issue, especially in agrarian economies. Attaching a value to soil erosion requires detailed local data that are not widely available, and it can be extremely difficult to disentangle the economic costs of soil erosion from the physical losses (see box 3.1). Diamonds are another important resource for some countries, most significantly in Angola, Botswana, the Democratic Republic of Congo, Namibia, the Russian Federation, and 38 CHAPTER 3. RECENT GENUINE SAVING ESTIMATES South Africa. Diamonds are excluded from the analysis because of data availability issues and the lack of free-market prices. Box 3.1 Soil Degradation and Changes in Wealth Ideally, adjusted net or genuine saving should include the depletion and degradation of land resources, which contribute 18 percent of total wealth in low-income countries. However, data comparability and availability do not allow for systematic inclusion of this item in the saving analysis. For many low-income countries that depend on the natural resource base for their development, the loss of soil quality can be a major problem. The UN Convention to Combat Desertification is a policy response to this trend, and the recently published Millennium Ecosystem Assessment (2005) points to land degradation in drylands, in particular in Africa and Central Asia, as one of the major challenges now facing the international community. Many of the poorest countries in the world face serious land degradation problems. Statistical information on the cost of land degradation is not widely available, largely because the effects of erosion are complex to measure with accuracy. It is not sufficient to measure on-farm effects since the external consequences of erosion can be significant. Negative off-farm effects of erosion include siltation of dams, salinization, and loss of biodiversity. But there are also positive effects of erosion-- for example, delta landscapes, such as the Nile Delta and Bangladesh, depend on the yearly deposit of soil and nutrients transported by rivers for their fertility. It is probably safe to assume that soil erosion that goes considerably beyond natural levels has negative economic effects. Through case studies undertaken for seven developing countries in Africa, Asia, and Latin America it has been estimated that the problems of sustainable land management deduct 3 percent to 7 percent from agricultural GDP (Berry and others 2003).A study from Australia (Gretton and Salma 1996) estimates soil fertility loss equivalent to 6 percent of agricultural production. Soil losses can be significant. The Genuine Saing Calculation: A Country Example F igure 3.2 shows the steps in calculating genuine saving for Bolivia, one of the poorest countries in Latin America, with GDP per capita below $1,000. Bolivia is endowed with a wealth of natural resources, including minerals, oil, and huge deposits of natural gas discovered at the end of the 1990s. 39 WHERE ISTHE WEALTH OF NATIONS? Figure 3.2 Adjustments in the Genuine Saving Calculation for Bolivia (2003) 15 Depreciation 10 of fixed capital Depletion of GNI natural 5 Education % expenses resources 0 Pollution damages 5 Gross saving Net saving Net saving plus Genuine saving Genuine saving educational excluding expenses pollution damages Source: World Bank 2005. The first column in figure 3.2 shows the traditional measure of gross national saving in Bolivia, 12 percent of gross national income (GNI) in 2003. Deducting the depreciation of produced capital reveals a much lower net saving rate, less than 3 percent. Investments in education are estimated to be around 5 percent of GNI, bringing the saving rate up to nearly 8 percent as shown by the third column in figure 3.2. Following this, adjustments are made for depletion of natural resources. Resource rents from Bolivia's extraction of oil and gas are deducted, as well as the rents from gold, silver, lead, zinc, and tin. Depletion of energy, metals, and minerals amount to over 9 percent of the GNI. While deforestation is deemed to be a problem in Bolivia, available data suggest that net forest depletion is zero. As a result of these deductions for resource depletion, Bolivia's genuine saving rate is negative. Finally, the deduction for pollution damages leads to a bottom-line estimate of Bolivia's genuine saving rate of minus 3.8 percent of GNI. Bolivia is currently on an unsustainable development path. Regional Disparities T he calculation of aggregate genuine saving rates by region reveals some striking differences between regions of the world as shown 40 CHAPTER 3. RECENT GENUINE SAVING ESTIMATES Figure 3.3 Genuine Saving Rates by Region 30 20 10 0 GNI % 10 20 30 40 1970 1980 1990 2000 Year East Asia and Pacific Middle East and North Africa Sub-Saharan Africa 30 20 10 0 GNI % 10 20 30 40 1970 1980 1990 2000 Year Latin America and the Caribbean South Asia Europe and Central Asia Source: World Bank 2005. in figure 3.3. The Middle East and North Africa stands out for its consistently negative saving rate, reflecting high dependence on petroleum extraction. However, not all countries in the region have negative genuine saving rates. Jordan, Morocco, and Tunisia had consistently positive genuine saving rates over the period, exceeding 15 percent of GNI. 41 WHERE ISTHEWEALTH OF NATIONS? Regional genuine saving rates are highly sensitive to changes in world oil prices. The Iranian revolution from 1978 to 1979 followed by the Iran- Iraq war in 1980 resulted in crude oil prices more than doubling from $14 in 1978 to $35 per barrel in 1981. This is clearly shown in figure 3.3--genuine saving rates dipped in the region, largely owing to the consumption of sharply increased oil rents. In stark contrast to the Middle East and North Africa stands the East Asia and Pacific region, with recent aggregate genuine saving figures nearing 30 percent, driven largely by China. This diverse region has enjoyed steady economic growth and progress toward poverty reduction. From 1999 to 2004, the number of East Asians living on less than $2 a day fell from 50 to 34 percent, or by about 250 million people. The boom in economic performance from the second half of the 1980s until the Asian financial crisis in 1997 is reflected in the genuine saving numbers, largely driven by increases in gross national saving. In Sub-Saharan Africa, the poorest region in the world, the number of people living in extreme poverty has almost doubled, from 164 million in 1981 to 314 million today. Genuine saving rates in the region have been hovering around zero. The aggregation masks wide disparities between countries in the region. Positive genuine saving rates in countries such as Kenya, Tanzania, and South Africa are offset by strongly negative genuine saving rates in resource-dependent countries such as Nigeria and Angola, which have genuine saving rates of minus 30 percent. South Asia displays consistently strong genuine saving rates. The regional aggregate genuine saving rate has been fluctuating between 10 and 15 percent since 1985, with India dominating the aggregate figure. Nepal is the region's new strong saver with genuine saving rates reaching nearly 30 percent in 2003. Nepal's gross national saving rate has been steadily increasing from the 1990s to the present day. Latin American genuine saving rates have remained fairly constant throughout the 1990s. The large economies in the region, Mexico and Brazil, have positive genuine saving rates in excess of 5 percent. However, for the region's largest oil producer, República Bolivariana de Venezuela, saving rates tell a different story. Like many other oil producers, República Bolivariana de Venezuela's genuine saving rate has been persistently negative since the late 1970s. Regional genuine saving data for Eastern Europe and Central Asia are only available from 1995. Saving rates have fallen from over 42 CHAPTER 3. RECENT GENUINE SAVING ESTIMATES 7.7 percent in 1995 to 1.7 percent in 2003. Of the 23 countries for which data were available in the region, 17 have positive genuine saving rates in 2003, averaging around 10 percent of GNI. However, the oil states of Azerbaijan, Kazakhstan, Uzbekistan, Turkmenistan, and the Russian Federation all have persistently negative genuine saving rates, thus pulling the regional aggregate downwards. Consuming Resource Rents S tocks of exhaustible resources such as oil represent a potential source of development finance. The question for countries with resource endowments is whether to consume these resource rents, providing current welfare but at a cost to future generations, or to invest the rents in other assets. Figure 3.4 scatters genuine saving rates against mineral and energy rents for resource-rich countries (defined as countries with exhaustible resource shares in excess of 1 percent of GNI). Figure 3.4 shows that as resource rents increase as a percentage of GNI, genuine saving rates tend to decline. This implies that a significant proportion of natural resource rents are being consumed rather than Figure 3.4 Genuine Saving and Exhaustible Resource Share (share 2003) 40 30 20 GNI 10 % 0 saving 10 20 Genuine 30 40 50 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 Mineral and energy rents % GNI Source: World Bank 2005. 43 WHERE ISTHE WEALTH OF NATIONS? invested in other productive assets. Chapter 4 explores this issue further and finds that the consumption rather than investment of resource rents is common in resource-rich countries. Income and Saving G enuine saving estimates for the 1970s reveal a worrying trend: rich countries had considerably higher saving rates than poorer countries, implying a potentially wider divergence in income and wealth between high-income and low-income countries. In 1970, high-income countries were saving 15 percent more of their GNI than low-income countries. Genuine saving rates for low-income countries were positive in aggregate, but only equal to 4 percent of GNI. However, as shown in figure 3.5, genuine saving rates have converged over time. In fact, in 2003 high- income countries were saving less as a percentage of GNI than both low- and middle-income countries. High-income countries saving rates as a percentage of GNI have declined over time, while saving rates for low- and middle-income countries have increased. Figure 3.5 Genuine Saving Rates by Income Group 25 20 15 10 GNI % 5 0 5 10 1970 1980 1990 2000 Year Low-income countries Middle-income countries High-income countries Source: World Bank 2005. 44 CHAPTER 3. RECENT GENUINE SAVING ESTIMATES Saving and Growth F igure 3.6 scatters genuine saving rates (as percentage of GDP) against GDP growth in 2003. Countries in the top-right quadrant have positive GDP growth rates and positive genuine saving rates. These economies are growing and, according to the genuine saving measure, not at the expense of future generations. This points to a positive future for countries like Botswana, China, and Ghana, all of whom have strong economic growth and positive genuine saving rates. Countries in the top-left-hand quadrant of figure 3.6 are experiencing contracting economies with declining GDP. However, these countries have positive genuine saving rates, implying they are still investing for the future. Traditional indicators of economic growth would suggest that those countries in the bottom-right-hand corner of figure 3.6 are doing well-- economic growth is positive. However, when genuine saving is taken into consideration, this optimistic story changes. Countries such as Nigeria, Angola, Uzbekistan, and Azerbaijan all have growing economies, but negative genuine saving rates may be imperiling future generations. Figure 3.6 Genuine Saving Rates against Economic Growth (2003) 40 China 30 Botswana 20 Ghana Central African 10 GDP Republic Ethiopia % g 0 savin 10 uine 20 Gen Venezuela, R. B. de Angola 30 Nigeria 40 Uzbekistan Azerbaijan 50 10 5 0 5 10 15 GDP growth % year Source: World Bank 2005. 45 WHERE ISTHEWEALTH OF NATIONS? Countries in the bottom-left-hand quadrant face the biggest challenge. These economies are currently shrinking, while at the same time future welfare prospects are being reduced as a result of negative genuine saving rates. República Bolivariana de Venezuela is a case in point--persistent negative levels of economic growth4 and genuine saving paint a troubling picture for future welfare. Conclusions Genuine saving provides an indicator of sustainability. There are many countries for which negative genuine saving rates are a reality (see appendix 3). In addition, those countries with low positive levels of genuine saving may also be pursuing a policy mix that will result in declining welfare over time, since measures of the depreciation of key assets may be masked by lack of data and methodological limitations. Genuine saving rates differ widely throughout the world as shown by the regional aggregates in figure 3.3. The evidence suggests that while resource-rich countries have the potential to achieve sustainable development if resource rents are appropriately invested, many are not doing so, as shown in figure 3.4. Genuine saving is useful to policy makers not only as an indicator of sustainability, but as a means of presenting resource and environmental issues within a framework familiar to finance and development planning ministries. It underlines the need to boost domestic saving, and hence, the need for sound macroeconomic policies, and it highlights the fiscal aspects of environment and resource management, since collecting resource royalties and charging pollution taxes are basic ways to both raise development finance and ensure efficient use of the environment. 46 CHAPTER 3. RECENT GENUINE SAVING ESTIMATES Endnotes 1. See Pearce (1993) for a discussion on the definition of sustainable development. 2. For a further discussion of accounting for human capital in the genuine saving calculation see World Bank (1996). 3. Tol (2005) reviewed over 100 estimates of the marginal damage cost of carbon dioxide emissions. He found a large range of uncertainty: the median cost was found to be $14 per ton of carbon and the mean to be $93/tC. On balance the use of the Fankhauser (1994) estimate of $20/tC appears to be reasonable. 4. República Bolivariana de Venezuela GDP has declined by 11 percent between 1993 and 2003. 47 Chapter 4 THE IMPORTANCE OF NVESTING I RESOURCE RENTS: A HARTWICK RULE COUNTERFACTUAL A substantial empirical literature documents the resource curse or paradox of plenty.1 Resource-rich countries should enjoy an advantage in the development process, and yet these countries experienced lower GDP growth rates post-1970 than less well-endowed countries. A number of plausible explanations for this phenomenon have been suggested: · Inflated currencies may impede the development of the nonoil export sector (this is known as "Dutch disease"). · Easy money in the form of resource rents may reduce incentives to implement needed economic reforms. · Volatile resource prices may complicate macroeconomic management, exacerbating political conflicts over the sharing and management of resource revenues. In the most extreme examples, levels of welfare in resource-rich countries are lower today than they were in 1970--development has not been sustained. The Hartwick rule (Hartwick 1977; Solow 1986) offers a rule-of-thumb for sustainability in exhaustible-resource economies--a constant level of consumption can be sustained if the value of investment equals the value of rents on extracted resources at each point in time. For countries dependent on such wasting assets, this rule offers a prescription for sustainable development, a prescription that Botswana, in particular, has followed with its diamond wealth (Lange and Wright 2004). Drawing on a 30-year time series of resource rent data underlying chapter 3, this chapter constructs a Hartwick rule counterfactual: how rich would countries be in the year 2000 if they had followed the Hartwick rule since 1970? The empirical estimations below test two variants of the Hartwick WHERE ISTHEWEALTH OFNATIONS? rule--the standard rule, which amounts to keeping genuine saving precisely equal to zero at each point in time, and a version that assumes a constant level of positive genuine saving2 at each point in time. The results, in many cases, are striking. Hypothetical Estimates of Capital Stocks T he basic methodology for testing how rich countries would be if they had followed the Hartwick rule is to compare the estimates of produced capital stocks for the year 2000 derived in chapter 2 with the size these stocks could be if countries had followed the Hartwick rule or its variants since 1970. The approach is to accumulate resource rents starting from the base-year produced capital stock in 1970. For simplicity, it is assumed that all resource rents are invested in produced capital, although theory suggests more generally that resource rents could be invested in a range of assets, including human capital and paying down of foreign debts. If any of the countries highlighted below had been investing their resource rents in human capital3 or foreign assets (quite unlikely given the observed levels of per capita income and indebtedness), then the methodology would produce a biased picture of their investment performance. Furthermore, since the analysis is limited to investments in produced capital, we will refer to genuine investment rather than genuine saving in what follows. In order to examine a variety of counterfactuals, four estimates of produced capital stock are derived using data covering 1970­2000: · A baseline capital stock derived from investment series and a Perpetual Inventory Model (PIM)--this is the same stock reported in Chapter 2 · A capital stock derived from strict application of the standard Hartwick rule · A capital stock derived from the constant genuine investment rule · A capital stock derived from the maximum of observed net investment and the investment required under the constant genuine investment rule. All investment and resource rent series are measured in constant 1995 dollars at nominal exchange rates. 50 CHAPTER 4. THE IMPORTANCE OFINVESTING RESOURCE RENTS For genuine investment IG, net investment N, depreciation of produced capital D, and resource depletion R, the following basic accounting identities hold at any point in time: I G I - D - R N I - D = I G + R For constant genuine investment I , we therefore estimate the G counterfactual series of produced capital for each country as the sum of net investments: 2000 K 2000 = K1970 + * (IG+ Rt ) t =1971 2000 K 2000 = K1970 + * * max(Nt , I G + Rt ) t =1971 Here K1970 is the baseline stock derived from the PIM. Two versions of K* are calculated in what follows--one with rule), and a second with I , equal to a constant =5 percent of 1987 GDP. (the standard Hartwick G K * The choice of a particular level of genuine investment for the analysis is arbitrary. We use 5 percent of 1987 GDP for the following reasons: there is some logic to choosing the midpoint of our time series of data from 1970 to 2000; 1987 is a slightly better choice, falling after the recession of the early 1980s, after the collapse of oil prices in 1986, and before the recession of the early 1990s; and a 5 percent genuine investment rate is roughly the average achieved by low-income countries over time. Resource depletion is estimated as the sum of total rents on the extraction of the following commodities: crude oil, natural gas, coal, bauxite, copper, gold, iron, lead, nickel, phosphate, silver, and zinc. These data underlie the genuine saving estimates presented in chapter 3. While the underlying theory suggests that scarcity rents are what should be invested under the Hartwick rule (that is, price minus marginal extraction cost), the World Bank data do not include information on marginal extraction costs. This gives an upward bias to the hypothetical capital stock estimates under the genuine investment rules. When comparing estimates of the stock of produced capital for different countries, it is worth noting that the PIM underestimates the capital stock for countries with very old infrastructures, as in most European 51 WHERE ISTHEWEALTH OFNATIONS? countries. The value of roads, bridges, and buildings constructed many decades and even centuries ago is not captured by the PIM. Pritchett (2000) makes a different point, that low returns on investments imply that the PIM overestimates the value of capital in developing countries. Our methodology assumes that both the PIM and cumulated net investments are, in fact, adding up productive investments. To the extent that this is not the case, estimated capital stock levels should be lower in developing countries. But the primary interest here is to compare the level of actual capital in a given country with the counterfactual level of capital in the same country, had it followed a sustainability rule. This makes the point concerning relative investment efficiency across countries less salient. Empirical Results H ow rich would countries be in the year 2000 had they followed the Hartwick rule since 1970? Based on the preceding methodology, table A4.1 (see annex) presents the year 2000 produced capital stock and the changes in this stock, which would result from the alternative investment rules. The countries shown in this table are those having both exhaustible resources and a sufficiently long-time series of data on gross investment and resource rents. For reference, the table also shows the average share of resource rents in GDP from 1970 to 2000. Negative entries in this table imply that countries actually invested more than the policy rule would suggest. For the standard Hartwick rule, figure 4.1 scatters resource dependence, expressed as the average share of exhaustible resource rents in GDP, against the percentage difference between actual capital accumulation and counterfactual capital accumulation. Using 5 percent of GDP as the threshold for high resource dependence, figure 4.1 divides countries into the four groups shown. The top-right quadrant of the graph displays countries with high resource dependence and a counterfactual capital stock that is higher than the actual (baseline) capital stock. The bottom-left quadrant displays countries with low natural-resource dependence and baseline capital stock that is higher than would be obtained under the Hartwick rule. These 52 CHAPTER 4. THE IMPORTANCE OF INVESTING RESOURCE RENTS Figure 4.1 Resource Abundance and Capital Accumulation (standard Hartwick rule) 400 Low High 350 resource resource Nigeria dependence dependence Zambia 300 Venezuela, R. B. de standard 250 if 200 Trinidad and Tobago capital followed 150 Guyana rule Bolivia Mauritania 100 Ecuador Gabon produced South Africa Congo, Rep. of Low in 50 Jamaica Algeria capital Hartwick Ghana Peru Zimbabwe Mexico accum. 0 Chile Indonesia High increase Egypt, Arab Rep. of 50 India capital % Brazil China Malaysia accum. 100 Thailand Korea, Rep. of 150 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 % share of resource rents in GDP (average 1970­2000) Source: Authors. two quadrants include most of the countries in our sample, indicating a high negative correlation between resource abundance and the difference between baseline and counterfactual capital accumulation--a simple regression shows that a 1 percent increase in resource dependence is associated with a 9 percent increased difference between counterfactual and actual capital. Clearly the countries in the top-right quadrant have not been following the Hartwick rule. Economies with very low levels of capital accumulation, despite high rents, include Nigeria (oil), República Bolivariana de Venezuela (oil), Trinidad and Tobago (oil and gas), and Zambia (copper). With the exception of Trinidad and Tobago, all of these countries experienced declines in real per capita income from 1970 to 2000. In the opposite quadrant, economies with low exhaustible resource rent shares but high levels of capital accumulation include the Republic of Korea, Thailand, Brazil, and India. Some high-income countries are also in this group. Figure 4.1 shows that no country with resource rents higher than 15 percent of GDP has followed the Hartwick rule. In many cases the differences are huge. Nigeria, a major oil exporter, could have had a year 2000 stock of produced capital five times higher than the actual stock. Moreover, if these investments had taken place, oil would play a much smaller role in the Nigerian economy today, with likely beneficial 53 WHERE ISTHE WEALTH OF NATIONS? impacts on policies affecting other sectors of the economy. República Bolivariana de Venezuela could have four times as much produced capital. In per capita terms, the economies of Gabon, República Bolivariana de Venezuela, and Trinidad and Tobago, all rich in petroleum, could today have a stock of produced capital of roughly US$30,000 per person, comparable to the Republic of Korea (see figure 4.2). Consumption, rather than investment, of resource rents is common in resource-rich countries, but there are exceptions to the trend. In the bottom-right quadrant of figure 4.1 are high resource-dependent countries that have invested more than the level of exhaustible resource rents. China, Egypt, Indonesia, and Malaysia stand out in this group, while Chile and Mexico have effectively followed the Hartwick rule-- growth in produced capital is completely offset by resource depletion. Among the countries with relatively low natural resource dependence and higher counterfactual capital, we find Ghana (gold and bauxite) Figure 4.2 Actual and Counterfactual Produced Capital (per capita), 2000 40,000 35,682 35,000 34,199 32,931 31,008 30,000 29,754 28,896 27,072 25,000 US$20,000 16,028 15,000 11,638 10,549 10,000 02 9,684 8,213 22 7,276 7,247 6,7 7,7 6,432 5,000 4,615 1,935 2,166 2,697 2,365 2,825 422 1,114 0 . de . of ana of Nigeria R.B , Rep Tobago Guy Gabon Algeria and Mauritania , Rep.duced capital) Venezuela, Congo Koreaal pro Trinidad (Actu Actual produced capital Produced capital with Hartwick rule Produced capital with 5% constant saving Source: Authors. Note: 1995 dollars, nominal exchange rate. 54 CHAPTER 4. THE IMPORTANCE OF INVESTING RESOURCE RENTS and Zimbabwe (gold). This is indicative of very low levels of capital accumulation in these economies. Figure 4.3 highlights countries which have invested more than their resource rents (as shown by the negative entries on the left side of the figure) but have failed to maintain constant genuine investment levels of at least 5 percent of 1987 GDP (as shown by the entries on the right). Developing countries in this group include Argentina, Cameroon, Cote d'Ivoire, and Madagascar. A number of high-income countries also appear in the figure. Sweden could have a stock of capital 36 percent higher if it had maintained constant genuine investment levels at the specified target. The corresponding difference for the United Kingdom is 27 percent, for Norway 25 percent, and for Denmark 22 percent.4 The generally low level of genuine investment levels in the Nordic countries is particularly surprising. Are these countries trading off intergenerational equity against intragenerational equity? Further research would be required to clarify this, a question that is beyond the scope of this chapter. Figure 4.3 Capital Accumulation under the Hartwick and Constant Net Investment Rules Hungary Finland United States Fiji Nicaragua Denmark United Kingdom Sweden Madagascar Malawi Togo Indonesia Côte d'Ivoire Colombia Norway Egypt, Arab Rep. of Cameroon Argentina Chile Mexico 60 40 20 0 20 40 60 80 % change in produced capital % change in produced capital under under the standard Hartwick rule the constant net investment rule 55 WHERE ISTHEWEALTH OFNATIONS? The next-to-last column in table A4.1 shows the change in produced assets for countries if they had genuine investments of at least 5 percent of 1987 GDP. The positive figures indicate that, with the exception of Singapore, all countries experienced at least one year from 1970 to 2000 where genuine investments were less than the prescribed constant level. Conclusions A pplying the standard Hartwick rule as development policy would be extreme. It implies a commitment to zero net saving for all time. Conversely, the constant genuine saving rule embodies a commitment to building wealth at each point in time. In a risky world this may be a more palatable development policy. The Hartwick rule counterfactual calculations show how even a moderate saving effort, equivalent to the average saving effort of the poorest countries in the world, could have substantially increased the wealth of resource-dependent economies. Of course, for the most resource- dependent countries such as Nigeria there is nothing moderate about the implied rate of investment. A Nigerian genuine investment rate of 36.1 percent of GDP in 1987 is what the calculations suggest under the constant genuine investment rule. The saving rules presented here are appealing in their simplicity. Maintaining a constant level of genuine saving will yield a development path where consumption grows monotonically, even as exhaustible resource stocks are run down. The real world is more complex. Poor countries place a premium on maintaining consumption levels, with negative effects on saving--the alternative may be starvation. At the same time financial crises, social instability, and natural disasters all have deleterious effects on saving. Holding to a simple policy rule in such circumstances would be no small feat. Saving effort is of course not the whole story in sustaining development. Saving must be channeled into productive investments that can underpin future welfare, rather than high-profile but ultimately nonremunerative projects. As Sarraf and Jiwanji (2001) document, Botswana's successful 56 CHAPTER 4. THE IMPORTANCE OF INVESTING RESOURCE RENTS bid to avoid the resource curse was built upon a whole range of sound macroeconomic and sectoral policies, underpinned by a positive political economy. Endnotes 1. See Auty (2001), ch. 1 for a good overview. One of the earliest studies was Sachs and Warner (1995). 2. See Hamilton and Hartwick (2005). This chapter builds upon Hamilton and others (forthcoming). 3. In support of the point that high natural resource rents are not necessarily invested in human capital, Gylfason (2001) shows that public expenditure on education relative to national income and gross secondary-school enrollment is inversely related to the share of natural capital in national wealth across countries. Natural capital appears to crowd out human capital. 4. A sensitivity test shows that these results hold by and large for most countries in the group. A change of the investment rule to 4 per cent of 1987 GDP affects qualitatively only those countries for which the change in produced capital was relatively small: Hungary, Finland, and Indonesia. 57 WHERE ISTHE WEALTH OF NATIONS? Annex Table A4.1 Change in Produced Assets under Varying Rules for Genuine Investment (IG) Produced capital in IG = 5% of IG >= 5% of Rent per GDP 2000, $bn IG = 0 1987 GDP 1987 GDP average % (1995 dollars) % difference % difference % difference (1970­2000) Nigeria 53.5 358.9 413.6 413.6 32.6 Venezuela, R. B. de 175.9 272.1 326.1 326.1 27.7 Congo, Rep. of 13.9 57.0 78.0 116.9 25.2 Mauritania 3.0 112.3 153.7 154.0 25.0 Gabon 19.7 80.3 105.5 130.4 24.1 Trinidad and 13.7 182.1 238.3 239.1 23.6 Tobago Algeria 195.4 50.6 80.9 83.9 23.3 Bolivia 13.7 116.1 169.8 177.5 12.8 Indonesia 540.6 ­26.5 3.8 32.1 12.5 Ecuador 37.7 95.3 158.0 158.3 11.6 Zambia 7.5 312.3 383.4 388.0 11.5 Guyana 2.1 149.3 185.6 191.2 11.4 China 2,899.4 ­62.1 ­45.0 5.1 10.8 Egypt, Arab Rep. of 159.7 ­12.9 28.1 36.2 9.5 Chile 151.4 ­3.0 31.6 54.0 9.5 Malaysia 305.2 ­52.7 ­31.4 6.6 8.3 Mexico 975.5 ­1.5 35.3 42.2 8.2 Peru 132.3 37.2 98.1 103.9 7.5 Cameroon 24.1 ­9.3 54.8 67.6 6.5 South Africa 349.5 50.7 109.3 115.8 6.5 Jamaica 13.4 39.9 87.8 99.6 5.7 Colombia 198.0 ­19.7 30.4 39.3 5.3 Norway 456.6 ­14.3 24.6 33.0 4.3 India 965.4 ­52.9 ­18.3 8.6 3.4 Zimbabwe 14.9 9.1 64.8 89.1 3.3 United States 16,926.7 ­39.8 12.9 26.1 2.7 Argentina 569.6 ­6.9 49.4 53.9 2.6 Togo 3.6 ­26.8 22.7 55.1 2.6 58 CHAPTER 4. THE IMPORTANCE OF INVESTING RESOURCE RENTS Produced capital in IG = 5% of IG >= 5% of Rent per GDP 2000, $bn IG = 0 1987 GDP 1987 GDP average % (1995 dollars) % difference % difference % difference (1970­2000) Pakistan 125.6 ­50.7 ­1.7 11.1 2.2 Hungary 149.1 ­43.5 8.7 22.3 2.2 Morocco 93.8 ­59.1 ­16.3 7.8 2.0 Brazil 1,750.5 ­59.0 ­6.6 9.1 1.9 United Kingdom 2,400.1 ­32.7 27.3 32.8 1.6 Dominican 33.8 ­73.0 ­27.9 1.2 1.6 Republic Philippines 195.0 ­58.4 ­14.5 10.6 1.5 Honduras 12.3 ­66.9 ­29.7 8.9 1.5 Ghana 16.1 30.6 73.2 76.7 1.0 Fiji 3.6 ­36.5 26.9 59.3 0.9 Benin 4.6 ­72.7 ­21.7 10.6 0.8 Senegal 10.0 ­44.0 14.2 27.5 0.7 Thailand 520.6 ­86.3 ­63.6 3.0 0.7 Haiti 2.8 ­62.7 109.2 109.5 0.6 Korea, Rep. of 1,607.6 ­93.5 ­68.6 0.9 0.6 Israel 215.8 ­72.8 ­31.3 4.2 0.5 Côte d'Ivoire 16.1 ­21.2 71.1 108.7 0.5 Bangladesh 89.7 ­59.0 ­12.9 15.5 0.5 Rwanda 3.9 ­83.2 ­6.9 24.6 0.4 Sweden 508.0 ­31.1 35.6 36.1 0.4 Nicaragua 6.9 ­34.9 8.1 44.8 0.3 Spain 1,623.6 ­58.9 ­15.1 6.1 0.3 Denmark 437.2 ­33.0 21.9 28.7 0.2 France 3,724.7 ­55.0 ­1.9 6.9 0.1 Italy 2,711.2 ­44.8 7.5 10.2 0.1 Finland 347.6 ­40.9 11.6 23.3 0.1 Belgium 681.9 ­48.0 2.3 10.4 0.1 Niger 3.0 9.7 95.2 136.1 0.1 Burundi 1.6 ­87.3 10.1 30.2 0.1 Portugal 308.8 ­71.0 ­30.8 5.7 0.0 Costa Rica 24.1 ­80.0 ­30.6 3.6 0.0 Continued 59 WHERE ISTHE WEALTH OFNATIONS? Table A4.1 (Continued) Produced capital in IG = 5% of IG >= 5% of Rent per GDP 2000, $bn IG = 0 1987 GDP 1987 GDP average % (1995 dollars) % difference % difference % difference (1970­2000) El Salvador 17.1 ­59.7 ­2.5 24.6 0.0 Hong Kong, 445.9 ­88.6 ­56.4 0.9 0.0 China Kenya 20.1 ­51.9 2.0 20.8 0.0 Madagascar 4.9 ­26.9 62.4 65.5 0.0 Sri Lanka 41.2 ­88.1 ­55.4 1.0 0.0 Malawi 4.6 ­26.8 9.4 68.2 0.0 Uruguay 29.9 ­55.5 22.1 37.2 0.0 Luxembourg 43.3 ­63.2 ­22.0 15.7 0.0 Paraguay 23.7 ­88.6 ­46.6 3.0 0.0 Lesotho 5.7 ­95.7 ­79.9 0.1 0.0 Singapore 314.8 ­92.7 ­73.2 0.0 0.0 Source: Authors. Note: Negative entries indicate that hypothetical produced assets would be lower than observed assets under the specified rule. 60 Chapter 5 THE IMPORTANCE OF POPULATION DYNAMICS: CHANGES IN WEALTH PER CAPITA Adjusted net, or genuine, saving was introduced in chapter 3. As a more- inclusive measure of net saving effort, one that includes depletion and degradation of the environment, depreciation of produced assets, and investments in human capital, genuine saving provides a useful indicator of sustainable development. The underlying theory (Hamilton and Clemens 1999) shows that negative rates of genuine saving imply future declines in utility along the optimal growth path for the economy. In the real world these theoretical results imply the common-sense notion that sustained negative rates of genuine saving must lead, eventually, to declining welfare. See box 1.1 for an overview of the theoretical work linking net saving to changes in welfare. If population is not static, then it is clearly per capita welfare that policy should aim to sustain. Genuine saving measures the real change in value of total assets rather than the change in assets per capita. Genuine saving answers an important question: Did total wealth rise or fall over the accounting period? However, it does not speak directly to the question of the sustainability of economies when there is a growing population. If genuine saving is negative, then it is clear in both total and per capita terms that wealth is declining. For a range of countries, however, it is possible that genuine saving in total could be positive while wealth per capita is declining. A simple formula, which assumes that the population grows exogenously, makes the accounting clear. If total wealth is denoted W, population P, WHERE ISTHEWEALTH OF NATIONS? and population growth rate g, then the change in wealth per capita can be shown to equal: W W W W W P = - g = (5.1) P P P W - g If we interpret DW as genuine saving, then the first equality says that the change in wealth per capita equals genuine saving per capita minus a Malthusian term, the population growth rate times total wealth per capita. A growing population implies that existing wealth must be shared with each new cohort entering the population. More intuitively, the second equality in equation 5.1 says that total wealth per capita will rise or fall depending on whether the growth rate of total wealth (DW/W ) is higher or lower than the population growth rate. This chapter applies the formula for changes in wealth per capita provided in equation 5.1 to the wealth database for the year 2000. The interplay of saving effort and population growth turns out to be quite significant. Accounting for Changes in Wealth per Capita: A Ghanaian Example M easuring saving and wealth in per capita terms requires some changes to the accounting framework presented in chapters 2 and 3. The first point is that we wish to measure only total tangible wealth, excluding intangible capital, when calculating the change in wealth per capita. Roughly speaking, the intuition behind this is that much intangible capital is embodied in the population. An adjustment should be made to the calculation of adjusted net saving. The underlying accounting framework suggests that a growing population, through a Malthusian effect, as described above, should actually boost saving per person when the stock of carbon dioxide historically emitted by a given country is taken into account. This potentially offsets the effect of current emissions per person. Since no data on stocks of carbon dioxide emitted by country are available, we simplify the accounting by dropping value of emissions per person. 62 CHAPTER 5. THE IMPORTANCE OF POPULATION DYNAMICS: CHANGES INWEALTHPERCAPITA Table 5.1 Ghana: Calculating the Change in Wealth -- $ per capita -- Tangible wealth Adjusted net saving Subsoil assets 65 Gross national saving 40 Timber resources 290 Education expenditure 7 NTFR 76 Consumption fixed capital 19 Protected areas 7 Energy depletion 0 Cropland 855 Mineral depletion 4 Pastureland 43 Net forest depletion 8 Produced capital 686 Total tangible 2022 Adjusted net saving 16 wealth Population growth 1.7% D Wealth per capita ­18 Source: Authors. Note: Data for 2000. NTFR: nontimber forest resources. Table 5.1 displays the detailed accounting of the change in wealth per capita in Ghana, a country with a 1.7 percent population growth rate per year. The left-hand column shows the assets that compose tangible wealth, summed to yield total tangible wealth per capita. The right-hand column breaks out the accounting of adjusted net saving. Gross national saving is added to education expenditures to yield total saving effort; consumption of fixed capital and natural resource depletion are then subtracted from this total to yield the net saving per Ghanaian, $16. The population growth rate is then multiplied by tangible wealth (the Malthusian term) and the result subtracted from adjusted net saving to yield the bottom- line change in wealth, ­$18 per Ghanaian. The rate of change of total real wealth ($16/$2,022 = 0.8 percent) is less than the population growth rate. Changes in Wealth per Capita in Selected African Countries T able 5.2 summarizes the results of this accounting for the African countries in the wealth database. The gross national income (GNI) per capita and population growth rates are provided for reference in the table. Adjusted net saving excludes carbon dioxide emissions, as described above. 63 WHERE ISTHEWEALTH OF NATIONS? Table 5.2 Africa: Change in Wealth per Capita 2000 -- $ per capita -- Population Adjusted Change in Saving GNI growth rate net saving wealth per gap per capita (%) per capita capita (% GNI) Benin 360 2.6 14 ­42 11.5 Botswana 2,925 1.7 1,021 814 Burkina Faso 230 2.5 15 ­36 15.8 Burundi 97 1.9 ­10 ­37 37.7 Cameroon 548 2.2 ­8 ­152 27.7 Cape Verde 1,195 2.7 43 ­81 6.8 Chad 174 3.1 ­8 ­74 42.6 Comoros 367 2.5 ­17 ­73 19.9 Congo, Rep. of 660 3.2 ­227 ­727 110.2 Côte d'Ivoire 625 2.3 ­5 ­100 16.0 Ethiopia 101 2.4 ­4 ­27 27.1 Gabon 3,370 2.3 ­1,183 ­2,241 66.5 Gambia, The 305 3.4 ­5 ­45 14.6 Ghana 255 1.7 16 ­18 7.2 Kenya 343 2.3 40 ­11 3.2 Madagascar 245 3.1 9 ­56 22.7 Malawi 162 2.1 ­2 ­29 18.2 Mali 221 2.4 20 ­47 21.2 Mauritania 382 2.9 ­30 ­147 38.4 Mauritius 3,697 1.1 645 514 Mozambique 195 2.2 15 ­20 10.0 Namibia 1,820 3.2 392 140 Niger 166 3.3 ­10 ­83 50.3 Nigeria 297 2.4 ­97 ­210 70.6 Rwanda 233 2.9 14 ­60 26.0 Senegal 449 2.6 31 ­27 6.1 Seychelles 7,089 0.9 1,162 904 South Africa 2,837 2.5 246 ­2 0.1 Swaziland 1,375 2.5 129 8 Togo 285 4.0 ­20 ­88 30.8 Zambia 312 2.0 ­13 ­63 20.4 Zimbabwe 550 2.0 53 ­4 0.7 Source: Authors. Note: All dollars at market exchange rates. 64 CHAPTER 5. THE IMPORTANCE OFPOPULATION DYNAMICS: CHANGES IN WEALTH PERCAPITA The table introduces a new performance indicator, the saving gap as a share of GNI. This is a measure of how much extra saving effort would be required in order for a country to break even with zero change in wealth per capita. It is calculated by identifying negative changes in wealth per capita, a measure of how far countries are from the break-even point, then dividing this by GNI per capita. South Africa is effectively at the point where wealth creation just offsets population growth. This table shows that the generally high rates of population growth in African countries translate into very few countries with growing wealth per capita--Botswana,1 Mauritius, Namibia, Seychelles, and Swaziland. These positive examples show that a Malthusian outcome is not inevitable. Sound resource policies combined with sound macroeconomic policies can lead to wealth creation. A long list of African countries exhibits positive net saving per capita, but negative changes in total wealth per capita. These include Benin, Burkina Faso, Cape Verde, Ghana, Kenya, Madagascar, Mali, Mozambique, Rwanda, Senegal, and Zimbabwe. Population growth is outstripping wealth creation in these countries. The oil states--the Republic of Congo, Gabon, and Nigeria--stand out in table 5.2 for enormous saving gaps (more than 100 percent of GNI in the case of the Republic of Congo). These countries are both running down total assets (as measured by negative adjusted net saving) and experiencing the immiserating effects of high population growth rates. Changes in Wealth per Capita Across Countries F igures 5.1 and 5.2 summarize changes in wealth per capita across all 118 countries in the database. The first figure scatters change in wealth per capita as a share of GNI against GNI per capita. The aim is to see how saving performance is linked to levels of income. The second figure looks at the correlation of net saving per capita with population growth rates. As figure 5.1 shows, the broad picture is that the rich are getting richer while the poor are getting poorer. There is an upward trend to the scatter, 65 WHERE ISTHE WEALTH OFNATIONS? Figure 5.1 Change in Wealth per GNI vs. GNI per Capita, 2000 0.4 0.2 0 GNI per 0.2 0.4 wealth in 0.6 Change 0.8 1 1.2 10 100 1,000 10,000 100,000 US$ GNI per capita Source: Authors. Data on GNI per capita are from World Bank 2005. and the majority of countries with GNI of less than $1,000 per person have declines in wealth per capita. Low levels of saving in poor countries are well-known phenomena, but factoring in population growth accentuates this trend markedly. The downward trend in figure 5.2 shows that high population growth rates are associated with lower net accumulation of wealth per person. Empirically, the majority of countries with population growth rates above 1.5 percent a year are on a path of declining wealth per capita. The figure shows a cluster of countries with population growth rates between 2 percent and 3 percent and positive accumulation of wealth per capita. Countries such as Namibia, the Philippines, and Jordan show that, as noted above, Malthusian outcomes are not inevitable. The table in appendix 4 reports results on changes in wealth per capita and saving gaps across all countries in the database, using the same structure as table 5.2. The oil producers joining the list of countries with high saving gaps (greater than 10 percent of GNI) include Syria, Iran, Ecuador, Algeria, República Bolivariana de Venezuela, and Trinidad and Tobago. Both in total and on a per capita basis these countries are running down their assets. Studies of historical data have shown that 66 CHAPTER 5. THE IMPORTANCEOFPOPULATION DYNAMICS: CHANGES INWEALTHPERCAPITA Figure 5.2 Change in Wealth per GNI vs. Population Growth Rate, 2000 0.4 0.2 0 GNI per 0.2 0.4 wealth in 0.6 Change 0.8 1 1.2 3.0 2.0 1.0 0 1.0 2.0 3.0 4.0 5.0 6.0 % population growth rate Source: Authors. Data on population growth are from World Bank 2005. countries combining high dependence on resource extraction and negative net saving rates have lagged the growth performance of other countries (Atkinson and Hamilton 2003). Finally, many of the countries of Eastern Europe and Central Asia are experiencing population declines, which raises saving per capita according to the formula underlying the saving calculation. These countries include Bulgaria, Estonia, Georgia, Hungary, Latvia, Moldova, Romania, and the Russian Federation. While, in principle, shrinking populations increase assets per capita, there is no guarantee that this will increase welfare per capita if these assets are not used efficiently. Conclusions B efore drawing the main conclusions from this analysis, it is important to note some alternative models of adjusted net saving. First, one of the largest potential factors offsetting dissaving is technological change. If technological change can be considered to be exogenous, then the effect of growth in total factor productivity has to be built into the saving 67 WHERE ISTHEWEALTH OF NATIONS? analysis. While for high-income countries the adjustment to saving could be very large,2 total factor productivity growth in low-income countries has been extremely low or negative. Second, if population growth were endogenous, then this could potentially have an impact on countries' prospects for future welfare. For example, if fertility were negatively related to wealth per person, then countries that are calculated to have negative changes in wealth per capita could potentially face higher birthrates and a downward spiral of immiseration. This would tend to emphasize the importance of the figures presented here. The Ghanaian example shows that it is indeed possible to have positive genuine saving in total, but declining wealth per person. Countries with high population growth rates are effectively on a treadmill, and need to create new wealth just to maintain existing levels of wealth per capita. Table 5.2 suggests very large saving gaps in Sub-Saharan Africa when population growth is taken into account. Excluding the oil states, saving gaps in many countries are on the order of 10­50 percent of GNI. Against this must be set the realization that reigning in government consumption by even a few percentage points of GNI is extremely painful and often politically perilous. Macroeconomic policies alone seem unlikely to close the gap. The table in appendix 4 shows that large saving gaps are not strictly a Sub-Saharan African phenomenon. Selected countries in the Middle East and North Africa, Latin America and the Caribbean, East Asia, and South Asia also have significant saving gaps. Although wealth data are lacking, given their sharply negative genuine saving rates (reported in chapter 3) and moderate population growth rates, it is highly likely that the oil states in Central Asia (Azerbaijan, Kazakhstan, and Uzbekistan) also face large saving gaps. Against this rather bleak picture there are the examples of countries that, even in the face of high population growth rates, have managed to achieve positive rates of wealth accumulation per capita. Policy clearly matters, both in the resource and macroeconomic domains. The next chapter examines, using historical data, whether the model of saving presented here is overstringent in its assumptions about the effects of population growth. 68 CHAPTER 5. THE IMPORTANCE OF POPULATION DYNAMICS: CHANGES INWEALTH PERCAPITA Endnotes 1. Botswana has relatively low population growth and a sizable increase in wealth per capita, but the lack of data on diamonds in the wealth database means that this is a highly distorted picture. 2. Weitzman and Löfgren (1997) calculate a boost to United States GDP on the order of 40 percent from exogenous technological changes. Total factor productivity measures the contribution to economic growth that cannot be strictly attributed to accumulation of produced capital or labor. 69 Chapter 6 TESTING GENUINE SAVING Intuition suggests that saving today should have an effect on future economic performance, and indeed, the large body of work on across- country analysis of economic growth supports this (Sala-i-Martin 1997; Hamilton 2005; Ferreira and others 2003; Ferreira and Vincent 2005). The literature on genuine saving makes a prediction that is eminently testable: current saving should equal the change over the accounting period in the present value of future well-being along the optimal growth path of the economy. The proposition that net saving is equal to changes in well-being has been proved in the literature. See box 1.1 for more details. The empirical test of this prediction exploits the 30-plus-year time series on genuine saving described in chapter 3 and published every year in the World Development Indicators (WDI) (World Bank 2005). With these historical data it is possible to ask whether measured genuine saving in 1980 actually equaled the present value of changes in consumption as measured in the consumption time series. While the data may not fit the theory perfectly for any individual country, the analysis is carried out across countries to see whether statistically there is a good fit of the data to the theory. One problem with designing an empirical test concerns the restrictiveness of the underlying model of the economy. Many of the models in the literature on saving and sustainability assume optimality, in the sense of the economy actually maximizing the present value of social well-being at each point in time, as well as fixed interest rates and constant returns to scale. Each of these assumptions is likely to be violated in real-world economies, which limits the feasibility of testing the models with historical data. WHERE ISTHE WEALTH OF NATIONS? These difficulties notwithstanding, testing alternative measures of saving is important if policy makers are to be convinced to use a measure such as genuine saving as a performance measure for the economy. Specifying the Empirical Test R ecent theoretical work provides a model of the linkage between saving and future well-being that shares few of the theoretical restrictions of earlier work (Hamilton and Hartwick 2005; Hamilton and Withagen 2004). Two basic assumptions are required: · Economies are competitive, in the sense that producers are free to maximize profits, while households are free to maximize well-being. · Externalities are internalized. For example, pollution taxes are employed to ensure that prices reflect the damages that producers inflict on households when a pollutant is emitted. The first assumption is valid for many economies. The second assumption is valid for relatively few economies, but the empirical literature on pollution damages suggests that the size of the impact is likely to be small in most economies. Under these assumptions it is possible to define the following basic relationship between the measure of change in total real wealth per capita G and changes in consumption C per capita: T G0 = (1 1 Ct - (6.1) Nt-1 Ct-1 t =1 + r)t Nt Here N is total population, r is the discount rate, and T is an assumed time period for the analysis. This expression just says that current change in total wealth per capita should equal the present value of changes in consumption per capita. Assuming this relationship holds, then it is possible to test it econometrically as: PVCi = + Gi + i (6.2) 72 CHAPTER 6. TESTING GENUINE SAVING where Gi is one of several alternative measures of saving for country i, while PVCi is the present value of changes in future consumption as suggested by the expression above. If the data fit the theory, then we would expect a = 0 and b = 1. The World Bank's time series of saving data permit tests of alternative measures of saving. Four different measures are tested, as follows: · Gross saving is just gross national income (GNI) minus total consumption in the private and public sectors--it is the amount of output that is not consumed in any given year. Gross saving is the figure typically reported and used by ministries of finance. · Net saving deducts the depreciation of produced capital from gross saving. · Adjusted net or genuine saving deducts the depletion of natural resources and pollution damages from net saving. · Malthusian saving1 measures the change in total real wealth per capita as defined in chapter 5--it is equal to genuine saving per capita, minus the population growth rate times the value of tangible wealth per capita. Data and Methodology of Estimation T he time series data for the analysis--GNI, gross saving, consumption of fixed capital,2 and depletion of natural resources (energy, minerals, and net forest depletion)--are taken directly from the WDI (World Bank 2005). Total tangible wealth, employed in the Malthusian saving calculation, is derived using a perpetual inventory model (PIM) for produced capital stock estimates (the same model used in arriving at the total wealth estimates for 2000 presented in chapter 2 and elsewhere); present values of mineral and energy rents; and present values of forestry, fishing, and agricultural rents, all measured in constant 1995 dollars (Ferreira and others 2003). Public expenditures on education are excluded from the genuine and Malthusian saving measures. These were shown to perform exceedingly 73 WHERE ISTHE WEALTH OFNATIONS? badly in earlier econometric tests of saving by Ferreira and Vincent (2005). There are a number of plausible reasons for the poor performance: · These are gross, rather than net, investment estimates. · Private education expenditures are excluded. · Expenditures may be a very poor proxy for human capital formation, particularly in developing countries (Pritchett 1996). Damages from carbon dioxide emissions are also excluded from the saving measures. This is partly because the bulk of the damages occur in the longer term, but also because, in the absence of a binding agreement to pay compensation, damages to other countries (the major effect of emitting carbon dioxide) should have no effect on future consumption in the emitting country. One of the key choices to be made in estimating the expression for saving econometrically is the choice of period over which to calculate changes in consumption. The underlying theory suggests that there is, in principle, an infinite time horizon. As a practical matter, however, the data on genuine saving are limited to the period 1970­2000, with data for the early 1970s being particularly sparse. A reasonable choice of time horizon would be the mean lifetime of produced capital stocks, roughly 20 years (machinery and equipment lifetimes are typically shorter, 10 years or so, but buildings and infrastructure have lifetimes of several decades). Choosing 20 years would be saying, in effect, that the effects of saving will be felt over the lifetime of the produced capital in which they are presumed to be invested. This is the assumption used below, and testing the estimation for a 10-year time horizon produced less robust estimates overall (in terms of explained variation, probability of rejecting a linear relationship between dependent and independent variables, and significance of the coefficients on saving). The other decision required for estimation concerns the discount rate. The underlying theory (Ferreira and others 2003) suggests that the rate should be the marginal product of capital, less depreciation rates for produced capital, less population growth rates, which argues for a low value. We use a uniform rate of 5 percent, and tests of alternatives suggest that the estimates are fairly insensitive to small changes in the discount rate. Allowing for the sparse early-1970s saving data,3 therefore, the regression equation was estimated using Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) for 74 CHAPTER 6. TESTING GENUINE SAVING consecutive 20-year periods from 1976 to 1980. These results, as well as more informal methods, are reported below. Empirical Results T o provide a feel for the data, we first scatter the present value of changes in consumption against the four different saving measures for 1980 in figures 6.1­6.4. The broad picture which emerges is that there is no monotonic improvement in the fit with theory as more stringent measures of saving are applied. The coefficient on saving actually drops from gross saving to net saving, and the explained variation drops considerably. For genuine saving the coefficient on saving is higher and very near one. Finally, for Malthusian saving the coefficient on saving drops to the lowest level of the four measures, while explained variation reaches its highest value. Figure 6.5 presents the same scatter for high-income countries only. As seen in Ferreira and Vincent (2005) and Ferreira and others (2003), the model fit is particularly poor for these countries. Further tests show the coefficient on saving to be insignificant, while the explained variation is very low. Figure 6.1 Present Value of Change in Consumption vs. Gross Saving, 1980 1 0.8 0.6 GDP % C 0.4 delta 0.2 y 0.8319x 0.0751 of R2 0.1469 0 value 0.2 Present 0.4 0.6 0.8 0.2 0.1 0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 Gross saving % GDP Source: Authors. 75 WHERE ISTHE WEALTH OF NATIONS? Figure 6.2 Present Value of Change in Consumption vs. Net Saving, 1980 1 0.8 0.6 GDP 0.4 % C 0.2 y 0.7066x 0.0116 delta R2 0.0921 of 0 0.2 value 0.4 Present 0.6 0.8 0.2 0.1 0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 Net saving % GDP Source: Authors. Figure 6.3 Present Value of Change in Consumption vs. Genuine Saving, 1980 1 0.8 0.6 GDP % C 0.4 y 0.9882x 0.0568 delta 0.2 R2 0.2391 of 0 value 0.2 Present 0.4 0.6 0.8 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 Genuine saving % GDP Source: Authors. 76 CHAPTER 6. TESTING GENUINE SAVING Figure 6.4 Present Value of Change in Consumption vs. Malthusian Saving, 1980 0.6 0.4 GDP % C 0.2 delta of 0 value 0.2 y 0.5221x 0.1249 Present R2 0.3194 0.4 0.6 1 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 0.2 0.4 Malthusian saving % GDP Source: Authors. Figure 6.5 Present Value of Change in Consumption vs. Genuine Saving, High-Income Countries, 1980 0.4 0.35 GDP 0.3 % C 0.25 delta of 0.2 value 0.15 0.1 Present 0.05 0 0.05 0 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2 Genuine saving % GDP Source: Authors. 77 WHERE IS THE WEALTH OF NATIONS? Table 6.1 Regression Results for PVC = alpha + beta ¥ Saving 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 beta alpha beta alpha beta alpha beta alpha beta alpha Gross saving Coeff. 1.0152 ­0.0737 0.7596 ­0.0338 1.0484 ­0.1212 1.2325 ­0.1743 0.8319 ­0.0751 tstat 3.0335 ­0.9511 2.4358 ­0.4628 3.7257 ­1.8992 4.7372 ­2.8601 3.6416 ­1.4656 R2 0.1479 0.0803 0.1598 0.2351 0.1469 Df 53 68 73 73 77 Pr > F 0.0037 0.0175 0.0004 0.0000 0.0005 beta = 1 0.0445 ­0.7595 0.1697 0.8814 ­0.7264 Net saving Coeff. 0.6634 0.0606 0.2161 0.1047 0.6485 0.0209 0.9835 ­0.0293 0.7066 0.0116 tstat 1.7723 1.0787 0.6471 2.0414 1.9740 0.4433 3.2791 ­0.6574 2.7943 0.3102 R2 0.0560 0.0061 0.0507 0.1284 0.0921 Df 53 68 73 73 77 Pr > F 0.0821 0.5198 0.0522 0.0016 0.0066 beta = 1 ­0.8823 ­2.3125 ­1.0555 ­0.0542 ­1.1451 Genuine saving Coeff. 1.2803 0.0483 0.8532 0.0677 1.2553 0.0131 0.7815 0.0580 0.9882 0.0568 tstat 4.5524 1.4442 3.4246 2.1915 4.9943 0.4654 4.2716 2.3469 4.9187 2.3175 R2 0.2811 0.1471 0.2547 0.2000 0.2391 Df 53 68 73 73 77 Pr > F 0.0000 0.0010 0.0000 0.0001 0.0000 beta = 1 0.9780 ­0.5808 1.0019 ­1.1781 ­0.0578 Malthusian saving Coeff. 0.7757 0.1337 0.5741 0.1200 0.4663 0.1061 0.3599 0.1117 0.5221 0.1249 tstat 3.8801 5.1418 3.2489 5.0664 4.0371 5.0553 3.7425 5.2683 5.1265 6.1294 R2 0.2785 0.1772 0.2352 0.2030 0.3194 Df 39 49 53 55 56 Pr > F 0.0004 0.0021 0.0002 0.0004 0.0000 beta = 1 ­1.0937 ­2.3613 ­4.5343 ­6.5358 ­4.6100 Source: Authors. Table 6.1 presents the results of the individual OLS estimates of the model for each of the five years and four measures of saving. This table reports the coefficient values with t-statistics, R-squared, degrees of freedom, the probability of rejecting a linear relationship (from the F statistic), and a simple two-sided t-test of whether the coefficient on 78 CHAPTER 6. TESTING GENUINE SAVING saving is equal to 1 (values greater than 2.00 imply the coefficient is significantly different from 1 at the 5 percent confidence level). While there is some heterogeneity in the results, the following broad conclusions hold: · The results for 1977 are the weakest of the five years, with low R-squared, higher probabilities of rejecting a linear relationship than other years, and two saving coefficient estimates that are significantly different from one (although the coefficient for net saving is not itself significant). This suggests some systematic shock being picked up by the data for this year. · Results for net saving are generally the weakest of the four saving measures tested, with insignificant coefficients on saving at the 5 percent level in 1976 and 1977, and generally low R-squared and higher probability of rejecting a linear relationship than other measures. · Malthusian saving exhibits the worst fit with theory, with the coefficients on saving being the lowest of the four saving measures, and significantly different from one in four out of the five years tested. · The results for gross and genuine saving have similarities, with the coefficients on saving being significant and not significantly different from one in all years. Genuine saving explains much more of the total variation in four out of five years, and exhibits lower probability of rejecting a linear relationship in the same four years, suggesting a more robust fit with theory. Quantitative analysis suggests a moderate advantage to using genuine saving as a predictor of future welfare, in the sense of a one percentage- point change in saving translating into a 1 percent change in the present value of changes in future consumption. Figures 6.1 and 6.3 suggest a more qualitative test. In Figure 6.1 it can readily be seen that gross saving provides many false positives in the form of positive base-year saving translating into negative welfare outcomes--these are the scatter points lying in the lower-right quadrant. Similarly, the upper-left quadrant points in figure 6.3 represent false negatives--countries where negative base-year genuine saving was associated with increases in welfare. 79 WHERE ISTHEWEALTH OF NATIONS? Table 6.2 False Signals regarding Future Changes in Consumption (ratios) 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 Wt. avg. Gross saving False positive 0.241 0.246 0.320 0.360 0.267 0.294 False negative 1.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.167 Net saving False positive 0.226 0.250 0.275 0.338 0.209 0.266 False negative 0.500 0.500 0.167 0.250 0.167 0.231 Genuine saving False positive 0.188 0.200 0.226 0.293 0.154 0.218 False negative 0.429 0.400 0.231 0.412 0.407 0.378 Malthusian saving False positive 0.043 0.080 0.037 0.077 0.043 0.056 False negative 0.611 0.615 0.464 0.452 0.600 0.543 Source: Authors. Table 6.2 assembles the proportions of false positives and false negatives4 for all saving measures, for all years, along with an average for each saving measure weighted by the number of countries with positive or negative saving observed. A few observations: · Malthusian saving has the lowest proportion of false positives, but in fact, the vast majority of the countries with positive Malthusian saving are developed countries. The result is therefore unsurprising. This saving measure also has the highest proportion of false negatives, which is consistent with the results of the quantitative analysis. · Gross and net saving have relatively low proportions of false negatives, but this represents very few countries (only one in the case of gross saving) across all years. There are simply very few countries with negative gross or net saving. · Genuine saving has lower proportions of false positives than either gross or net saving, but this is balanced by a much higher proportion of false negatives. 80 CHAPTER 6. TESTING GENUINE SAVING Conclusions G rowth theory provides the basis for a stringent test of whether saving does, in fact, translate into future welfare. This chapter confronts the theory with real-world data--with positive results for measures of gross and genuine saving. Even without appealing to theoretical models, it may be asked when a dollar is saved how it could not show up in future production and consumption. Many answers to this question are possible: · Saving may be measured very badly. · Funds appropriated for public investments may not, in fact, be invested, owing to problems of governance. · Investments, particularly by the public sector, may not be productive. It is important to note the many caveats pertaining to this analysis. First, measurement error may be significant, particularly for consumption of fixed capital (where government estimates may be incorrect), depletion of natural resources (where World Bank resource rent estimates depend on rather sparse cost of extraction data, and where the methodology probably inflates the value of depletion for countries with large resource deposits), and total wealth estimates (especially produced capital in developing countries, where public investments may be particularly inefficient [Pritchett 2000]). Missing variable bias may also be an issue. Although human capital is excluded from the analysis for the reasons outlined above, in principle, net investment in human capital should be an important contributor to future welfare. However, the negative effects of including education spending in the analysis of saving and future welfare in Ferreira and Vincent (2005) and Ferreira and others (2003) may simply be another manifestation of the small or negative growth impact of public education spending in developing countries analyzed by Pritchett (1996). In addition, for some countries, the exclusion of natural resources such as diamonds and fish may be a significant omission. Exogenous shocks may present problems for testing the theory of saving and social welfare. The period under analysis in this chapter includes, in the early and least heavily discounted stages, the second oil shock in 1979 81 WHERE ISTHE WEALTH OFNATIONS? and a steep worldwide recession in 1981. However, Ferreira and others (2003) do not find any significant effects of exchange rate shocks in their analysis of the theory. It should be noted that the theory being tested is particularly stringent, since it implies that measuring positive or negative saving at a point in time leads to future welfare being higher or lower than current welfare over some interval of time. In the real world, a positive exogenous shock (such as an improvement in the terms of trade) in the year immediately following the time when saving turned negative could easily swamp the effect of negative saving, and conversely for positive saving and negative shocks. Turning to the results of the analysis, we find that the various saving measures are poor at signaling future changes in welfare in developed countries, similar to what Ferreira and Vincent (2005) and Ferreira and others (2003) find. This probably reflects factors other than capital accumulation being key for the growth performance of these economies: in particular, technological innovation, learning by doing, creation of institutional capital, and so on. For all countries combined, we find that both net and Malthusian saving fit the theory poorly. The significantly low coefficients on Malthusian saving suggest that this measure overstates the effects of population growth on wealth accumulation per capita. Gross and genuine saving perform well, with estimated coefficients not being significantly different from the predicted values and with lower probabilities of rejecting a linear relationship between dependent and independent variables than for other measures. Genuine saving performs better than gross saving in terms of goodness of fit. In terms of the more qualitative question of false positives and negatives, genuine saving provides, on average, a lower false-positive ratio than gross saving (22 percent of countries with positive genuine saving at a point in time actually experienced welfare declines, compared with 29 percent of countries with positive gross saving). Conversely, on average, negative genuine saving falsely signaled future welfare decreases in 38 percent of cases. The bottom line is that genuine saving, excluding adjustments for population growth and education expenditure, is a good predictor of changes in future welfare as measured by consumption per capita. This result does not hold for high-income countries as a group, where factors 82 CHAPTER 6. TESTING GENUINE SAVING other than simple asset accumulation are clearly driving future welfare. For developing countries the processes of accumulating produced assets and depleting natural resources clearly do influence their prospects for welfare. Endnotes 1. While Malthusian saving is not a standard textbook saving measure, the name is useful and evocative for the purposes of this chapter. 2. Ferreira and others (2003) use estimated figures for consumption of fixed capital derived from the perpetual inventory model used to estimate total stocks of produced capital. Inspection of these figures reveals a fairly large number of anomalous estimates. 3. From 1970 to 1975 there are fewer than 40 countries with the necessary data, and these are primarily developed countries. 4. This is clearly a rather ad hoc test, but one that policy makers may care about. 83 PART 3 WEALTH, PRODUCTION, AND DEVELOPMENT Chapter 7. Explaining the Intangible Capital Residual: The Role of Human Capital and Institutions Chapter 8. Wealth and Production Chapter 7 EXPLAINING THE NTANGIBLE I CAPITAL RESIDUAL: THE ROLE OF HUMAN CAPITAL AND NSTITUTIONS I The Meaning of Intangible Capital C hapter 2 showed that in most countries intangible capital is the largest share of total wealth. What does intangible capital measure in the wealth estimates? By construction, it captures all those assets that are not accounted for elsewhere. It includes human capital, the skills and know-how embodied in the labor force. It encompasses social capital, that is, the degree of trust among people in a society and their ability to work together for common purposes. It also includes those governance elements that boost the productivity of the economy. For example, if an economy has a very efficient judicial system, clear property rights, and an effective government, the result will be a higher total wealth and thus an increase in the intangible capital residual. As a residual, intangible capital necessarily includes other assets which, for lack of data coverage, could not be accounted in the wealth estimates. As mentioned in chapter 2, one form of wealth is net foreign financial assets. When a country receives interest on the foreign bonds it owns, this boosts consumption and hence total wealth and the intangible capital residual. A similar argument applies to countries with net foreign obligations--to the extent that interest is being paid to foreigners, the residual will be lower. So while there are no comprehensive cross-country data on net foreign financial assets, this variable is measured implicitly in the intangible wealth residual for each country. Finally, the intangible capital residual also includes any errors and omissions in the estimation of produced and natural capital. The main omissions include fisheries and subsoil water. WHERE ISTHEWEALTH OF NATIONS? Figure 7.1 The Meaning of the Intangible Capital Residual Estimation of wealth Intangible capital residual Human capital Formal/informal Foreign financial Errors and institutions assets omissions Raw labor Governance Net financial Natural capital assets for which the country receives an Skilled labor Social capital income or Produced pays interest capital Source: Authors. Keeping in mind the caveats above, the goal in this chapter is to disaggregate the intangible capital residual into its major components. The omission of foreign financial assets and some natural resources is not systematic, in that countries may differ widely in their endowments of such assets. For this reason we will concentrate on the more systematic contributors to the residual, such as human capital and institutional quality. The decomposition analysis in the following sections makes it possible to measure the residual as a set of specific assets; these assets in turn may be subject to specific policy measures. Among the components of intangible capital, perhaps the one that has been most widely analyzed in the economics literature is human capital. For example, table 7.1 shows how growth in output per capita in the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) countries compares to growth in inputs and in total factor productivity. Growth in labor quality explains an important part of the 88 CHAPTER 7. EXPLAINING THE INTANGIBLE CAPITAL RESIDUAL Table 7.1 Growth in Output and Input per Capita in OECD Countries (percentage) 1960­95 USA Canada UK France Germany Italy Japan Growth in output per capita 2.11 2.24 1.89 2.68 2.66 3.19 4.81 Growth in capital stock per 1.35 2.35 2.69 3.82 3.76 4.01 3.49 capita Growth in hours worked per 0.42 0.14 ­0.50 ­0.99 ­0.67 ­0.17 0.35 capita Growth in labor quality 0.60 0.55 0.44 0.85 0.43 0.31 0.99 Growth in productivity 0.76 0.57 0.80 1.31 1.33 1.54 2.68 Source: Jorgensen and Yip 2001. high rates of growth in output, but productivity growth is still a major component. Box 7.1 provides a brief and nonexhaustive overview of what is meant by human capital and its measurement. Box 7.1 The Measurement of Human Capital While there is currently no monetary measure of human capital, this area of research promises to be very rewarding. Behrman and Taubman (1982, 474) define human capital as "the stock of economically productive human capabilities." Human capital can be increased through education expenditure, on-the-job training, and investments in health and nutrition. The difficulties in measuring human capital are linked to the fact that human capital is accumulated in a variety of ways. Not all of these contributions to human capital formation are easily measured. Even in the cases in which it is possible to have a measure, years of schooling for example, the effect on values of human capital may vary from country to country. Physical Measures of Human Capital The most basic measure of human capital is the average years of education for the population or the labor force. Schultz (1961) and Becker (1964) introduced the explicit treatment of education as an investment in human capital. Schultz (1988) provides a comprehensive analysis of the relationship between investments in human capital and income. Growth accounting exercises show that high levels of education explain high levels of output. The figure below displays this point by plotting average years of education against gross national income (GNI) per capita. 89 WHERE ISTHE WEALTH OFNATIONS? 40,000 30,000 capita 20,000 per GNI 10,000 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 School years per capita Source: Data on GNI per capita are from World Bank 2005. Data on school years are from Barro and Lee 2000. Even taking into account years of schooling in growth accounting equations, a large unexplained difference in income across countries persists (Caselli 2003). For this reason, average school year measures are often complemented by attainment ratios, that is, the percentage of the relevant population that completes a given level of education (for example, primary, secondary, higher level). A comprehensive data set covering both school years and attainment is available from Barro and Lee (2000) and it has been used in the quantitative analysis here. The use of schooling as a proxy for human capital implicitly assumes that one year of schooling in country A produces the same amount of human capital as one year of schooling in country B. If a more accurate measure of human capital is desired, the quality of education should be taken into account. This can be achieved by considering variables such as the quality of the teachers, the availability of teaching materials, the student-teacher ratio, test scores, and so on. All these measures are difficult to collect, and country-level data are not widely available. Toward Monetary Measures of Human Capital Human capital is the result of investments in improving the skills and knowledge of the labor force. A major step forward in the monetary valuation of human capital is therefore the estimation of the returns to such investments. Psacharopoulos and Patrinos (2004) provide comprehensive measures of the profitability of investment in education across countries. Among their findings is the fact that primary education produces the highest returns in low-income countries. The table below summarizes the results by income group. The entries 90 CHAPTER 7. EXPLAINING THE INTANGIBLE CAPITAL RESIDUAL in the table provide the return to one extra dollar spent on education. Returns decline with the level of schooling--that is, one dollar spent on primary school provides higher returns than one dollar spent on higher education--and with per capita income. The authors show that investments in education constitute a very profitable policy option. Returns to Investment in Education by Level Social returns to education investments, % Country group Primary Secondary Higher Low-income countries 21.3 15.7 11.2 Middle-income countries 18.8 12.9 11.3 High-income countries 13.4 10.3 9.5 World 18.9 13.1 10.8 Source: Psacharopoulos and Patrinos 2004. The usefulness of the rate of returns on education is very much under scrutiny. Using data for Sweden, Bjorklund and Kjellstrom (2002) find, for example, that results may be driven by the structure imposed by the estimation models. Further investigation is needed to refine such calculations. Even if reliable data on rates of return were available, the estimation of human capital would require a baseline, that is, a starting level to which we can add successive investments in human capital to obtain the total value of human capital in any given moment in time. Wages for unskilled labor provide a conceptually sensible baseline, but comparable cross-country data are not available. In the following section we will look at the broader intangible capital residual and attempt to disaggregate the effects of education and other variables, including governance. This will provide a first indication of the relative importance of the assets that constitute the residual. A Regression Analysis of the Intangible Capital Residual T he intangible capital residual forces us to think of all contributors to wealth other than produced and natural capital. What are left are those assets that are more intangible and less prone to be measured. 91 WHERE ISTHEWEALTH OF NATIONS? Regression analysis can help us pinpoint the major determinants of the intangible capital residual. Human capital must clearly be an important part of any model specification. A readily available proxy for human capital is schooling. Schooling level per person constitutes an imperfect measure of human capital, since it does not take into account the quality of education of those trained, nor other types of human capital investment such as on-the-job training. Measurement errors of this kind need not bias the coefficient, but would affect the significance. Average years of schooling per capita are used here for lack of better data. A special form of human capital is represented by workers who have emigrated and send money to their families in the form of remittances. Even if they are not physically present in the country, workers abroad contribute to the country's income and hence they are a part of total national wealth. For this reason we also include remittances in our model. Institutional quality is another important dimension that needs to be captured. Kaufmann, Kraay, and Mastruzzi (2005) provide data on six dimensions of governance: · Voice and accountability · Political stability and absence of violence · Government effectiveness · Regulatory quality · Rule of law · Control of corruption The model below uses the rule of law indicator. This measures the extent to which agents have confidence in and abide by the rules of society. It encompasses the respect of citizens and the state for the institutions which govern their interactions. While there is no strong reason to prefer one governance dimension over another, an argument in favor of choosing the rule of law indicator is that it captures particularly well some of the features of a country's social capital. Paldam and Svendsen (forthcoming) associate social capital with trust, and report a generalized trust indicator for 20 countries. The correlation between generalized trust and rule of law is high, as shown in table 7.2.1 The interpretation of the coefficients, in the analysis below, should then be subject to the caveat that there are 92 CHAPTER 7. EXPLAINING THE INTANGIBLE CAPITAL RESIDUAL several underlying elements explaining the association between rule of law and the intangible capital residual. Table 7.2 Correlation Matrix of Social Capital and Governance Dimensions Trust Voice Stab Goveff Regqua Rulelaw Corr Trust 1.000 Voice 0.397 1.000 Stab 0.309 0.675 1.000 Goveff 0.482 0.506 0.868 1.000 Regqua 0.240 0.450 0.807 0.878 1.000 Rulelaw 0.514 0.560 0.908 0.945 0.868 1.000 Corr 0.517 0.595 0.892 0.965 0.865 0.975 1.000 Sources: The trust indicator is taken from Paldam and Svendsen (forthcoming). The six governance dimensions are taken from Kaufmann, Kraay, and Mastruzzi (2005). Notes: Voice: voice and accountability; Stab: political stability and absence of violence; Goveff: government effectiveness; Regqua: regulatory quality; Rulelaw: rule of law; Corr: control of corruption. Our model represents the residual as a function of domestic human capital, as captured by the per capita years of schooling of the working population; human capital abroad, as captured by the amount of remittances by workers outside the country; and governance/social capital, expressed here as a rule of law index. We considered a simple Cobb- Douglas function: R = ASS F F LL (7.1) where R is the intangible residual, A is a constant, S is years of schooling per worker, F is remittances from abroad and L is the rule of law index (measured on a scale of 1 to 100). The coefficients ai express the elasticity of the residual with respect to the explanatory variables on the right-hand side of the equation above. So, for example, aS measures the percentage increase in R if schooling is increased by 1 percent. There is also a set of income group dummy variables that take into account differences in the residual linked to income levels. Elasticities As table 7.3 shows, the specified model fits the data well. The independent variables explain 89 percent of the variations in the residual. 93 WHERE ISTHEWEALTH OF NATIONS? Table 7.3 Elasticities of Intangible Capital with Respect to Schooling, Remittances from Abroad, and Rule of Law Variable Coefficient Standard error School years 0.53 0.2162 Remittances from abroad 0.12 0.0472 Rule of law 0.83 0.3676 Low-income dummy ­2.54 0.4175 Lower-middle-income dummy ­1.90 0.2911 Upper-middle-income dummy ­1.55 0.2693 Constant 7.24 1.6005 Source: Authors. Note: Dependent variable: log of intangible capital. Observations included: 79. R-squared: 0.89. Excluded dummy: high-income countries. All coefficients are significant at the 5 percent level. All the coefficients estimated are significantly2 different from zero at the 5 percent level and positive. The estimation suggests that a 1 percent increase in school years will increase the intangible capital residual by 0.53 percent. A 1 percent increase in the rule of law index is associated with a 0.83 percent increase in the residual. A coefficient lower than one in the model above means that there are decreasing marginal returns to the corresponding factor--for example, one more year of schooling yields higher returns in those countries with lower levels of schooling. In addition, all the income dummy coefficients are negative. This means that countries in each income group have a lower level of intangible capital residual compared with high-income countries. We also tested the hypothesis that the sum of the coefficients for schooling, remittances, and rule of law is equal to one. Statistically, this hypothesis cannot be rejected. In other words, if we imagine the three dependent variables as inputs in the production of intangible capital, then this production function exhibits constant returns to scale. Marginal Returns Using the elasticities obtained in the regression, it is possible to obtain marginal returns, that is, the unit change in the residual resulting from a unit change in the explanatory variable. In the case of Cobb-Douglas 94 CHAPTER 7. EXPLAINING THEINTANGIBLE CAPITAL RESIDUAL functions, marginal returns, or partial derivatives are easily obtained as: R R X = X (7.2) X Notice that while the elasticity aX is constant, the marginal returns depend on the level of R and X. We evaluated marginal returns using the mean estimates for R and X in each income group. The information is summarized in table 7.4. Table 7.4 Variation in Intangible Capital Resulting from a Unit Variation in the Explanatory Variables, by Income Group ($ per capita) Marginal Marginal returns to returns to rule Marginal returns to schooling of law foreign remittances Low-income countries 838 111 29 Lower-middle-income countries 1,721 362 27 Upper-middle-income countries 2,398 481 110 High-income OECD countries 16,430 2,973 306 Source: Authors. At the mean level of schooling, a one-year increase in schooling in low- income countries corresponds to a US$838 increase in the residual. In comparison, low-income countries spend nearly US$51 per student per year in primary school (World Bank 2005). This information provides useful insight for policy makers, especially when it comes to comparing costs and benefits of a given policy. With respect to the rule of law variable, the implications for policy making are less obvious since the partial derivative depends on the scale on which the rule of law index is measured (1 to 100 in this instance), not to mention the difficulty in deciding what it means--in terms of changing real institutions--to increase rule of law by one point on the scale. The returns to schooling also depend on other country-specific characteristics. Looking down the columns of table 7.4, the marginal returns to schooling appear to be higher at higher levels of income. This result is attributable to the unobserved characteristics of countries that are captured by the dummy variables in the model. From equation 7.1 it is clear that country-specific characteristics will affect the level of the constant term A. What we are observing in table 7.4 is, in effect, four different functions for intangible capital, one per income group. 95 WHERE ISTHEWEALTH OF NATIONS? Disentangling the Intangible Capital Residual T he Cobb-Douglas specification permits us to go one step further by deriving the following decomposition of the intangible capital residual: R = R R R (7.3) SS +F F + L L + Z The residual can therefore be decomposed into a schooling component, a foreign remittances component, and a governance component. A fourth component, termed Z, captures the difference between intangible capital and the individual contributions of the explanatory variables. In our specification, if the sum of the elasticities aS, aF, aL equals one--which cannot be rejected econometrically--then Z is equal to zero. Assuming Z equals zero, we can then estimate the contributions of schooling, remittances, and rule of law to the intangible capital residual (figure 7.2). Rule of law is the largest component. On average, it explains 57 percent of the total residual. Schooling is also important with 36 percent of the total value. Foreign remittances account for 7 percent. A Tale of Three Countries Three country examples can increase our intuitive understanding of the decomposition of intangible wealth: El Salvador, Peru, and Figure 7.2 Decomposition of the Intangible Capital Residual, World 2000 Foreign remittances, 7% Schooling, 36% Rule of law, 57% Source: Authors. 96 CHAPTER 7. EXPLAINING THE INTANGIBLE CAPITAL RESIDUAL Table 7.5 Shares of Residual and Levels of Schooling, Foreign Remittances, and Rule of Law Shares of the residual Levels Total Intangible Foreign wealth capital Rule Foreign Schooling Rule remittances ($ per residual Schooling of law remittances (years per of law ($ per Country Region capita) (%) (%) (%) (%) capita) (index) capita) Turkey ECA 47,858 75 31 63 6 5 51 68 Peru LAC 39,045 77 47 51 3 8 39 28 El LAC 36,476 86 28 47 24 5 41 284 Salvador Lower- 23,612 60 36 57 7 6 44 84 middle- income countries Source: Authors. Turkey. While enjoying similar levels of total wealth per capita and a very high intangible capital residual, the differences in relative endowments of intangible capital among the three countries are very high. Table 7.5 applies formula 7.3 to decompose the intangible capital residual. Turkey, located in the Europe and Central Asia region, is the richest of the three countries considered, with a GNI per capita of $2,980. As seen in appendix 2 its total wealth is 18 percent produced capital and 7 percent natural resources (especially agricultural land). Rule of law is the main contributor to a very large intangible capital residual. The rule of law index is above the regional average. Peru, in Latin America, has a GNI per capita of $1,991. Relatively rich in subsoil resources, Peru has natural capital that accounts for 9 percent of total wealth and a level of produced capital that accounts for 14 percent of wealth (see appendix 2). While rule of law is at a much lower level compared with Turkey, the average school years are higher. As a consequence, schooling explains a large share of the intangible capital residual (47 percent). El Salvador, located in Central America, yields yet another decomposition of the residual. It has a GNI per capita of $2,075 and a residual that accounts for 86 percent of total wealth. Here remittances play a major role (24 per cent of the residual), reflecting the large share of Salvadoran human capital residing abroad. 97 WHERE ISTHEWEALTH OF NATIONS? The data in table 7.5 suggest that there is no one-size-fits-all policy rule. The varying composition of intangible capital across the three countries suggests very different policy options. In Turkey, education is a major priority. Increasing per capita education in Turkey by one year would raise the residual by nearly 10 percent. In Peru, improving the judicial system to a level similar to Argentina's, for example, would increase the residual by 25 percent. The management of remittances is a key issue in El Salvador. Adams and Page (2003) show that international remittances have a strong statistical impact on reducing poverty, an impact that could be stronger if policies encouraged investment rather than consumption of remittances. In the long term, increasing the dynamism of the Salvadoran economy would provide an incentive for human capital and financial resources to come back to the country. Conclusions C ross-country monetary measures of human capital are not available in the literature. The major impediments to valuing human capital include the availability of data on wages and the comparability of data on education. When available, data are difficult to combine across countries because of differences in definitions, measurement methods, and assumptions. The intangible capital residual obtained from the wealth estimates offers an opportunity for advancing work in this domain. In addition, while there is a rich literature using governance and institutional indicators as explanatory variables in cross-country growth regressions, there has been little work on trying to place an economic value for issues such as institutional quality. The decomposition of the intangible wealth residual takes some first steps in this direction. The list of assets that potentially constitute the residual includes human capital, social capital, and the quality of institutions. The regression analysis shows that school years per capita and rule of law account for the largest share of the residual: at the aggregate level, rule of law explains nearly 60 percent of the variation in the residual, while human capital explains another 35 percent. 98 CHAPTER 7. EXPLAINING THE INTANGIBLE CAPITAL RESIDUAL These results present a plausible menu for development policy. In addition, it is hoped that these results will stimulate new research. Endnotes 1. If the Russian Federation and Indonesia are excluded from the sample, the correlation coefficient between rule of law and trust becomes 0.73, while the correlation coefficient between control of corruption and trust goes up to 0.70. 2. Statistically speaking, saying that a coefficient is significantly different from zero at the 5 percent level means that there is a 95 percent chance that the coefficient is different from zero. 99 Chapter 8 WEALTH AND PRODUCTION One of the recurring themes in the sustainability literature has been the legitimacy of using an economic framework to account for natural resources. Those critical of such an approach contend that wealth accounting assumes that produced assets, such as human and physical capital, can substitute for natural-resource assets on a dollar-for-dollar basis. This, they argue, does not capture the limited degree to which such substitution is possible. A loss of some natural capital, such as an entire ecosystem, surely cannot be made up with an increase in physical capital if the very basis of social existence and well-being are destroyed in the areas affected by that system. This makes them skeptical of the kind of wealth accounts we are constructing here. While we cannot hope to disentangle the full set of issues embedded in this line of reasoning, we can at least start by focusing on the degree of substitutability between the different assets. Underlying any wealth accounts is an implicit production function, which is a blueprint of the combinations of different assets with which we can achieve a given level of output. These blueprints are usually written as a mathematical function, which describes the precise relationship between the availability of different amounts of inputs, such as physical and human capital services, and the maximum output they could produce. The substitutability between inputs is then measured as an elasticity of substitution. In general terms, this captures the ease with which a decline in one input can be compensated by an increase in another, while holding output constant. More precisely, it measures how much the ratio of two inputs (for example, physical capital and land) changes when their relative price changes (for example, the price of land goes up relative to the price of capital).1 The greater the elasticity, the easier it is to make up for the loss WHERE ISTHEWEALTH OFNATIONS? of one resource by using another. Generally, an elasticity of less than one indicates limited substitution possibilities. A commonly used production function, which implies elasticities of one between the inputs, is the Cobb-Douglas form, written as: Yt = AtK L (8.1) Income or output (Y ) is expressed as a function of the levels of capital input (K ), labor input (L), an exogenous technological factor (A) and the parameters a and b, which give the returns to capital and labor respectively. If the national production options could be captured by such a function, with natural capital services included, it would have considerable implications for sustainability. First, it would imply a degree of substitutability between natural and produced capital that would give some comfort to those who argue we can lose some natural capital without seriously compromising our well-being. Related to that it would validate the Hartwick rule, which states that when exploiting natural resources, consumption can be sustained at its highest possible level if net saving just equals the rent from exploiting those resources (Hartwick 1977; Hamilton 1995). The Hartwick rule is a useful sustainability policy since it is open to monitoring. We can check whether or not it has been adhered to. Economists have devoted a considerable amount of effort to estimating these elasticities for inputs such as capital, labor, and energy but not natural resources. Although, starting in the 1970s, there were theoretical studies that modeled neoclassical economic growth with nonproduced capital, such as natural resources, as factors in production (Stiglitz 1974a, b; Mitra 1978),2 the empirical estimation of the underlying production functions was never carried out, largely because of a lack of data. This chapter is a preliminary attempt in that direction. As mentioned in the earlier chapters, a database of new wealth estimates has been developed, including both produced and nonproduced capital-- renewable and nonrenewable resources and human resources--which allows us to estimate a production function that includes the services from these different resources as inputs. This chapter examines, therefore, the economic relationship between total wealth and income generation and takes advantage of the new wealth estimates to estimate a production function based on a larger set of assets. Section 2 presents the estimation of the production function. Section 3 concludes. 102 CHAPTER 8. WEALTH AND PRODUCTION Estimation of Nested CES Production Function T he estimation carried out here uses national-level data on gross national income (GNI) or economic output and sees the extent to which variations in GNI across countries, at any point in time, can be explained in terms of the national availability of produced capital, human resources, and natural resources (energy and land resources). A Cobb-Douglas production function of the form shown above is not appropriate for this estimation because it restricts the elasticity between factors to be one. In fact, one of our objectives is to estimate the elasticity of substitution between factors or groups of factors. A form that holds the elasticity constant but allows it to take values different from one is the constant elasticity of substitution (CES) production function. In particular, this chapter uses a nested CES production function. For example, a two-level nested CES with three inputs takes the form:3 X = F[X AB(A,B),C ] (8.2) where X is the gross output; A, B, and C are inputs; and XAB represents the joint contribution of A and B to production. The first level of the estimation involves A and B; while the second level models the production of output by XAB and C. A special feature of the nested CES function is that the elasticity of substitution between the first-level inputs, A and B, can be different from the elasticity of substitution between the second-level inputs, XAB and C. In other words, by placing natural resources and other inputs in different levels of the function, we effectively allow for different levels of substitutability. So, for example, natural assets may be critical (low substitutability) while other inputs are allowed to be more substitutable among themselves. There are several studies that have estimated the nested CES production function between three or four production inputs, such as capital, labor, energy, and nonenergy materials at the firm level (Prywes 1986; Manne and Richels 1992; Chang 1994; Kemfert 1998; Kemfert and Welsch 2000). A common interest among these studies is examining the capital-energy substitution in manufacturing industries. For example, Manne and Richels (1992) estimated the substitution possibilities between the capital and labor nest and energy to be about 0.4; while Kemfert (1998) estimated the same to be about 0.5. On the other hand, Prywes (1986) found the elasticity of substitution between the capital and energy nest and labor to be less than 0.5. 103 WHERE ISTHEWEALTH OFNATIONS? In this chapter we use related variables to estimate aggregate national-level production functions. The variables used are:4 · Produced capital (K) is an aggregate of equipments, buildings, and urban land. · Human capital (H) has two alternative measures--human capital, which relates educational attainment with labor productivity (HE); or intangible capital residual (HR), which is obtained as the difference between a country's total wealth and the sum of produced and natural assets. Part of the intangible capital residual captures human capital in the form of raw labor and stock of skills. For further discussion of this variable and its rationale see chapters 2 and 7. · Production and net imports of nonrenewable energy resources (E) includes oil, natural gas, hard coal, and lignite.5 · Land resources (L) refers to the aggregated value of cropland, pastureland, and protected areas. Land is valued in terms of the present value of the income it generates rather than its market value. The GNI and all inputs mentioned above are measured in per capita values at 2000 prices and are taken at the national level for 208 countries. GNI data are obtained from the World Development Indicators (World Bank 2005). HE is derived based on the work by Barro and Lee (2000); E is a flow measure and is obtained using the same data that underpin the wealth estimates; while the remaining variables, K, HR, and L are the components of wealth as described in chapter 2. The relationships of the production inputs to income are expressed in nested CES production functions described in the chapter annex. Three different nested CES approaches are examined: · One-level function, with two inputs · Two-level function, with three inputs · Three-level function with four inputs The combinations of the variables in the different CES approaches were varied to further investigate any possible differences among substitution elasticities for pairs of inputs. The production function approach taken so far neglects an important set of factors that influence differences in national income. These 104 CHAPTER 8. WEALTHANDPRODUCTION relate to the efficiency with which productive assets are utilized and combined, and include both institutional as well as economic factors. In this study, we consider the following institutional indicators, which capture the efficiency with which production can take place, as well as economic indicators, which also capture the efficiency of economic organization: · Institutional development indicators--indices on voice and accountability (VA), political instability and violence (PIV), government effectiveness (GE), regulatory burden (RB), rule of law (RL); and control of corruption (CC). An increase in a given index measures an improvement in the relevant indicator. Hence, they are expected to have a positive impact on income and possibly growth (Kaufmann and others 2005).6 · Economic indicators--trade openness (TOPEN) is calculated as the ratio of exports and imports to GDP (World Bank 2005); and the country's domestic credit to the private sector as proportion of GDP (PCREDIT), which represents private sector investments (Beck and others 1999).7 Two methods of incorporating the impact of these institutional and economic indicators were investigated. The first method involved the derivation of residuals from the regression of a nested CES production function. The residuals are the part of income not explained by the wealth components--physical capital, human capital, land resources, and energy resources, and are regressed on the identified institutional and economic indicators. By using this method, however, a statistically significant correlation between the residuals and any indicator would imply that relevant variables have been omitted in the estimation of the nested CES production function. Thus, the estimated coefficients of the nested CES production function derived earlier will be biased and inefficient (Greene 2000). Hence another method is considered to be more appropriate. The influences of the institutional and economic indicators on income will be incorporated into the efficiency parameter of the production function, A (see annex 2). Depending on the available data for the variables of the nested CES production function, the number of countries drops in the range of 67 to 93 countries. In the complete case method, for a given nested CES approach, the reduction is caused by considering only those countries that have nonmissing observations for their corresponding dependent and explanatory variables.8 105 WHERE ISTHE WEALTH OF NATIONS? Regression Results T he nested CES production functions are estimated using a nonlinear estimation method.9 The sample size in each CES approach differs because countries with missing observations in any of the variables had to be dropped. Table A8.1.1 in annex 1 shows the estimated substitution elasticities corresponding to the case where human capital is part of the measured intangible capital residual (HR). All statistically significant substitution elasticity estimates have a positive sign, which is encouraging.10 The lowest is that between K and E at 0.37 in the three- level production function. It is also interesting to note that most of the significant elasticities of substitution are close to one. A second round of regressions was carried out using the other measure of human capital that is related to schooling and labor productivity, HE. Table A8.1.2 in annex 1 shows the statistically significant elasticities of substitution, which also have a positive sign. An elasticity of substitution approximately equal to one is likewise found for most of the nested functions. The results provide some interesting findings. First, there is no sign that the elasticity of substitution between the natural resource (land) and other inputs is particularly low. Wherever land emerges as a significant input, it has an elasticity of substitution approximately equal to or greater than one. Second, the HE variable performs better in the estimation equations than the HR variable. Third, the best-determined forms, with all parameters significant, are those using HE, involving four factors and containing the combinations: · K, HE, and L are nested together and then combine with E, or · K, HE, and E are nested together and then combine with L. It is hard to distinguish between these two versions, and so they are both used in the further analysis reported below. From the nested CES production function estimations, the elasticity estimates of the institutional and economic indicators can be derived. Table A8.1.3 and table A8.1.4 in annex 1 show the results for the four-factor production functions [(K,HE,L)/E] and [(K,E,HE)/L] of table A8.1.2, respectively. In both tables, the variables on trade openness 106 CHAPTER 8. WEALTH ANDPRODUCTION and private sector investment are found to be statistically significant. The elasticity estimates of these two variables are not very different from each other. The results imply that for every percent increase in trade openness, gross national income per capita (GNIPC) increases by approximately 0.5 percent. None of the institutional indicators, on the other hand, has a statistically significant elasticity estimate.11 Simulation T he predicted value of the dependent variable can be calculated by using the estimated coefficient estimates of the production function and the mean values of the explanatory variables. Through this method, we try to predict what will happen to the economic output per capita (GNIPC) if there is significant natural resource depletion. The natural resource considered in this exercise is land resources (L); and the four-factor nested CES production functions used are [(K,HE,L)/E] and [(K,E,HE)/L] of table A8.1.2. Table A8.1.5 in annex 1 presents the predicted average GNIPC, as well as the change in GNIPC given a reduction in the amount of land resources, other things being equal. Based on the production function [(K,HE,L)/E], economic output is reduced by 50 percent when the amount of L declines by about 92 percent, while holding other variables constant. For the production function [(K,E,HE)/L], on the other hand, it takes a reduction in the amount of L by about the same percentage, other things being equal, to halve the economic output relative to the baseline. Conclusions I n this chapter, we looked at the potential for substituting between different inputs in the generation of GNI. Among these are land resources, one of the most important natural resources. The estimation of a well-known production function form, which allows the elasticities of substitution to be different from one, was carried out. The resulting elasticities involving land resources (between L and other inputs such as physical capital, human capital, and energy resources) were 107 WHERE ISTHEWEALTH OF NATIONS? generally around one or greater, which implies a fairly high degree of substitutability. Moreover, it validates the use of a Hartwick rule of saving the rents from the exploitation of natural resources if we are to follow a maximum constant sustainable consumption path. This result, not surprisingly, has many caveats. Land resources as measured here include cropland, pastureland, and protected areas. Each has been valued in terms of present value of the flow of income that it generates. Such flows, however, underrepresent the importance of, for example, protected areas, which provide significant nonmonetary services, including ecosystem maintenance services that are not included. Further work is needed to include these values, and if this were done, and if the GNI measure were adjusted to allow for these flows of income, the resulting estimates of elasticities of substitution might well change. We intend to continue to work along these lines and to improve the estimates made here. Another shortcoming of the method applied here is the limited number of factors included in the original estimation. Generating national income depends not on the stock of assets, but on the amounts of the stocks that are used in production and the way in which they are used. For physical and human capital and land, we assume the rate of use is proportional to the stock. That assumption should be improved on, to allow for different utilization rates. Finally, the chapter also examines how the institutional and economic indicators affect the generation of GNI. Estimation results show that income generation is significantly influenced by changes in trade openness and private sector investment. The institutional indicators, however, have no statistically significant impact on income generation. 108 CHAPTER 8. WEALTH AND PRODUCTION Annex 1 Tables Table A8.1.1 Elasticities of Substitution ( ^i ), Using Human Resources (HR) Elasticity of substitution Standard Inputs ^i error R-squared Adj. R-squared Sample size A. Two factors (one-level CES production function) (1) K/HR 1.00* 3.88E-10 0.9216 0.9131 93 (2) K/E ­0.48 2.02 0.9958 0.9951 78 B. Three factors (two-level CES production function) (1) (K,HR)/L 0.9375 0.9290 93 K/HR 6.79 13.92 (K,HR)/La 1.00* 4.33E-10 (2) (K,HR)/E 0.9089 0.8916 70 K/HR ­0.78 1.31 (K,HR)/Ea 1.00* 5.37E-10 (3) (K,E)/HR 0.87667 0.8533 70 K/E 0.65 0.69 (K,E)/HRa 1.00* 3.96E-09 C. Four factors (three-level CES production function) (1) (K,HR,L)/E 0.3435 0.1911 70 K/HR ­0.90 0.70 (K,HR)/La 0.97* 0.01 (K,HR,L)/Eb 1.00* 5.46E-12 (2) (K,HR,E)/L 0.9958 0.9951 78 K/HR ­0.13 0.17 (K,HR)/Ea 0.93* 0.18 (K,HR,E)/Lb 1.00* 6.52E-09 (3) (K,E,HR)/L 0.9350 0.9200 70 K/E 0.37* 0.20 (K,E)/HRa ­0.64 0.55 (K,E,HR)/Lb 1.00* 1.27E-09 Source: Authors. Notes: Legend: K=physical capital; HR=human capital (captures raw labor and stock of skills); L=land resources; E=energy resources. Inputs in parentheses imply that they are nested. a. Two inputs in a nested function. b. Three inputs in a nested function. (*) denotes statistical significance at 5 percent level. The elasticities of substitution and their corresponding standard errors are rounded off to the nearest hundredth. 109 WHERE ISTHE WEALTH OF NATIONS? Table A8.1.2 Elasticities of Substitution ( ^i ), Using Human Capital Related to Schooling (HE) Elasticity of substitution Standard Inputs ^i error R-squared Adj. R-squared Sample size A. Two factors (one-level CES production function) (1) K/HE 1.00* 2.50E-08 0.9061 0.8942 81 B. Three factors (two-level CES production function) (1) (K,HE)/L 0.9203 0.9076 81 K/HE 1.01* 0.01 (K,HE)/La 1.00* 2.23E-10 (2) (K,HE)/E 0.8952 0.8742 67 K/HE 1.65* 0.12 (K,HE)/Ea 1.00* 6.76E-11 (3) (K,E)/HE 0.7674 0.7209 67 K/E 0.17 0.19 (K,E)/HEa 1.00* 8.22E-08 C. Four factors (three-level CES production function) (1) (K,HE,L)/E 0.9037 0.8081 67 K/HE 1.78* 0.11 (K,HE)/La 1.14* 0.02 (K,HE,L)/Eb 1.00* 2.52E-12 (2) (K,HE,E)/L 0.9059 0.8828 67 K/HE ­8.55 12.61 (K,HE)/Ea 0.48* 0.17 (K,HE,E)/Lb 1.00* 4.60E-11 (3) (K,E,HE)/L 0.9062 0.8831 67 K/E 1.57* 0.37 (K,E)/HEa 0.92* 0.02 (K,E,HE)/Lb 1.00* 6.41E-11 Source: Authors. Notes: Legend: K=physical capital; HE=human capital related to educational attainment and labor productivity; L=land resources; E=energy resources. Inputs in parentheses imply that they are nested. a. Two inputs in a nested function. b. Three inputs in a nested function. (*) denotes statistical significance at 5 percent level; (**) at 10 percent level. The elasticities of subtitution and their corresponding standard errors are rounded off to the nearest hundredth. 110 CHAPTER 8. WEALTH ANDPRODUCTION Table A8.1.3 Elasticity Estimates of the Economic and Institutional Indicators, Using the [(K, HE, L)/E] Production Function Variable Elasticity Standard error t-statistic TOPEN 0.47 0.10 4.53 PCREDIT 0.51 0.12 4.25 VA 0.01 0.04 0.28 PIV ­0.01 0.02 ­0.28 GE 0.04 0.10 0.40 RB 0.03 0.07 0.39 RL ­0.07 0.10 ­0.73 CC 0.01 0.09 0.17 Source: Authors. Note: Legend: TOPEN=trade openness; PCREDIT=variable for private sector investment; VA=voice and accountability; PIV=political instability and violence; GE=government effectiveness; RB=regulatory burden; RL= rule of law; and CC=control of corruption. Table A8.1.4 Elasticity Estimates of the Economic and Institutional Indicators, Using the [(K, E, HE)/L] Production Function Variable Elasticity Standard error t-statistic TOPEN 0.50 0.09 5.27 PCREDIT 0.51 0.11 4.83 VA 0.02 0.03 0.45 PIV ­0.01 0.02 ­0.44 GE 0.06 0.09 0.62 RB 0.03 0.07 0.37 RL ­0.08 0.09 ­0.86 CC ­0.02 0.08 ­0.24 Source: Authors. Note: Legend: TOPEN=trade openness; PCREDIT=variable for private sector investment; VA=voice and accountability; PIV=political instability and violence; GE=government effectiveness; RB=regulatory burden; RL=rule of law; and CC=control of corruption. 111 WHERE ISTHEWEALTH OF NATIONS? Table A8.1.5 Level of Gross National Income per Capita, Given a Reduction in the Amount of Land Reduction in the amount of land by Prod. function Baseline* 20% 50% 75% 92% (K,HE,L)/E $8,638.10 $8,068.84 $7,019.27 $5,774.25 $4,297.16 Difference from baseline** (­7%) (­19%) (­33%) (­50%) (K,E,HE)/L $9,096.20 $8,540.27 $7,477.97 $6,147.62 $4,455.06 Difference from baseline** (­6%) (­18%) (­32%) (­51%) Source: Authors. Notes: *Predicted per capita GNI at the mean values of the explanatory variables. **Rounded off to the nearest whole number. Sample size of each production function = 67. 112 CHAPTER 8. WEALTH AND PRODUCTION Annex 2 Three Different CES Approaches 1. A traditional CES production function with two inputs is written as: (a) Physical capital (K) and human capital (H) Y = A aK( - + bH - )-1 (A.1) (b) Physical capital (K) and energy resources (E) Y = A(aK - + bE - ) -1 (A.2) where Y is the per capita gross national income. A is an efficiency parameter. a and b are distribution parameters that lie between zero and one and b represents the substitution parameter. The elasticity of substitution (s) is calculated as: s = (1/[1 + b]). Values of b must be greater than ­1 (a value less than ­1 is economically nonsensical, although it has been observed in a number of studies [Prywes 1986]). If b > ­1, the elasticity of substitution must, of course, be positive. A, the efficiency parameter, is assumed to be a function of the economic (TOPEN and PCREDIT ) and institutional indicators described in the text. Two functional forms of A have been tried: (c) A = e1 TOPEN +2PCREDIT +3VA+4PIV +5GE+6RB+7RL+8CC (A.3) (d) A = 1TOPEN + 2PCREDIT + 3VA + 4PIV + 5GE + 6RB + 7RRL + 8CC (A.4) and the second functional form of A was found to be more appropriate. TOPEN means trade openness; PCREDIT is a variable for private sector investment; VA, voice and accountability; PIV, political instability and violence; GE, government effectiveness; RB, regulatory burden; RL, rule of law; and CC, control of corruption. The scores for each institutional indicator lie between ­2.5 and 2.5, with higher scores corresponding to better outcomes. 2. A two-level nested CES production function with three inputs is investigated for three cases: (a) K and H in the nested function, XKH is a substitute for land resources (L): Y1 = A1 a1 b1K ( -1 +(1- b1)H - 1)1 1 +(1- a1)L- 1 -1 1 (A.5) 113 WHERE ISTHEWEALTH OF NATIONS? (b) K and H in the nested function, XKH is a substitute for energy resources (E): -1 2 Y2 = A2 a2 b2K ( -2 +(1- b2)H - 2 )2 2 +(1- a2)E - 2 (A.6) (c) K and E in the nested function, XKE is a substitute for human capital (H): -1 3 Y3 = A3 a3 b3K ( -3 +(1- b3)E -3 )3 3 +(1- a3)H - 3 (A.7) where ai and bi are substitution parameters. 3. A three-level nested CES production function with four inputs is studied for these three cases: (a) K, H, and L in the nested function, and E as a substitute for XKHL: Y4 = A4 a4 { [b (c K -4 4 )4 4 4 4 +(1- c4)H - + (1- b4)L-4 ]4 4 + (1- a4)E -4 }-1 4 (A.8) (b) P, H, and E in the nested function, and L as a substitute for XKHE : Y5 = A5 a5 { [b(c K -5 5 )5 5 5 5 +(1- c5)H - + (1- b5)E -5 ]5 5 + (1- a5)L-5} -1 5 (A.9) (c) K, E, and H in the nested function, and L as a substitute for XKEH : Y6 = A6 a6 { [b(c K -6 6 ) 6 6 6 6 +(1- c6)E - + (1- b6)H -6 ] 6 6+ (1- a6)L-66} -1 6 (A.10) where ai, ri, bi are substitution parameters; and 0 < ai, bi, ci < 1. 114 CHAPTER 8. WEALTHANDPRODUCTION The substitution elasticities for these CES approaches can be described as follows: i = 1 Gives the elasticity of substitution between K and 1+i H when i = 1,2,4,5 Gives the elasticity of substitution between K and E when i = 1,6 i = 1 Gives the elasticity of substitution between K/H 1+ i and L when i = 4 Gives the elasticity of substitution between K/H and E when i = 5 Gives the elasticity of substitution between K/E and H when i = 6 i = 1 Gives the elasticity of substitution between K/H 1+ i and L when i = 1 Gives the elasticity of substitution between K/H and E when i = 2 Gives the elasticity of substitution between K/E and H when i = 3 Gives the elasticity of substitution between K/H/L and E when i = 4 Gives the elasticity of substitution between K/H/E and L when i = 5 Gives the elasticity of substitution between K/E/H and L when i = 6 The nested CES production functions are estimated using the nonlinear estimation method via the STATA program. The nonlinear estimation program uses an iterative procedure to find the parameter values in the relationship that cause the sum of squared residuals (SSR) to be minimized. It starts with approximate guesses of the parameter values (also called starting values), and computes the residuals and then the SSR. The starting values are a combination of arbitrary values and coefficient estimates of a nested CES production function. For example, the starting values of equation (A.1) are arbitrary. A set of numbers is tried until convergence is achieved. On the other hand, the starting values of 115 WHERE ISTHE WEALTH OF NATIONS? equation (A.5) are based on the coefficient estimates of equation (A.1). Next, it changes one of the parameter values slightly and computes again the residuals to see whether the SSR becomes smaller or larger. The iteration process goes on until there is convergence--it finds parameter values that, when changed slightly in any direction, cause the SSR to rise. Hence, these parameter values are the least squares estimate in the nonlinear context. Endnotes 1. Where prices are not defined, we measure the change in the ratio of the inputs resulting from a change in the marginal rate at which one factor can be substituted for another (Chiang 1984). 2. A bibliographical compilation of studies can be found in Wagner (2004). One exception to the observation that there is little empirical work is Berndt and Field (1981), who did look at limited natural resource substitution between capital, labor, energy, and materials. The studies generally found low elasticities between capital and materials. They did not, however, look at land as an input in the way we do here. Nor did they work with national-level data. 3. This model makes the further assumption of homothetic weak separability for groups of inputs. Homothetic weak separability means that the marginal rate of substitution between inputs in a certain group is independent of output and of the level of inputs outside that group (Chiang 1984). 4. Per capita dollar values at nominal 2000 prices are used. 5. For energy it would be inappropriate to take the stock value of the asset, as what is relevant for production is the flow of energy available to the economy. This is given by production plus net imports. With the other assets (K, H, and L) it is also the flow that matters, but it is more reasonable to assume that the flow is proportional to the stock. We do note, however, in the conclusions that even this assumption needs to be changed in future work. 6. Data can be obtained from the website: http://www.worldbank.org/wbi/governance/pubs/ govmatters4.html. 7. Hnatkovska and Loayza (2004) use openness and credit as a measure of financial depth, which they find to have a positive impact on growth. Data for this indicator can be obtained from the following website: http://www.worldbank.org/research/projects/ finstructure/database.htm. 116 CHAPTER 8. WEALTH ANDPRODUCTION 8. An imputation method was tried to fill the missing values for some of the countries to keep all 208 countries in the estimation. Most of the results, however, were not found to be reasonable. For example, the imputed value of physical capital for a low-income country turned out to be too high compared with the average value of physical capital of its income group. Hence, the imputation method was not used since it poses more problems in the estimates than using the complete case method. 9. See annex 2 for more details. 10. A negative elasticity of substitution is economically nonsensical--it implies a decline in the availability of one input can be made up by a decline in the availability of other factors. Nevertheless, some production function studies do find such negative values. 11. In the regression where the residuals are expressed as a function of the institutional variables, we did find significant values for a few institutional variables, especially the rule of law, which was encouraging as that variable also emerges as important in other evaluations of intercountry differences in this study. Unfortunately, the result did not hold when the more appropriate method was used. 117 PART 4 INTERNATIONAL EXPERIENCE Chapter 9. Developing and Using Environmental Accounts Chapter 9 DEVELOPING AND USING ENVIRONMENTAL ACCOUNTS Having committed themselves to achieving sustainable development, governments face a number of challenges beyond the traditional concerns of their natural resources and environmental agencies. One of the most important of these is integrating economic policies with policies for the management of natural resources and the environment. Policy makers setting environmental standards need to be aware of the likely consequences for the economy, while economic policy makers must consider the sustainability of current and projected patterns of production and consumption. Such integration and adoption of the notion of sustainable development by governments have been the motivation for developing environmental accounting. Environmental accounts can provide policy makers with the following: · Indicators and descriptive statistics to monitor the interaction between the environment and the economy, and progress toward meeting environment goals · A quantitative basis for strategic planning and policy analysis to identify more sustainable development paths and the appropriate policy instruments for achieving these paths After providing a context to explore the usefulness of the system of integrated environmental and economic accounting (SEEA) as an operational framework for monitoring sustainability and its policy use, this chapter summarizes the four general components of the environmental accounts.1 The second part of the chapter reviews a few policy applications of economic accounting (EA) in industrialized and developing countries and indicates potential applications, which may not be fully exploited at this time. WHERE ISTHEWEALTH OFNATIONS? Developing the Environmental Account: A Bird's Eye View E nvironmental and resource accounting has evolved since the 1970s through the efforts of individual countries or practitioners, developing their own frameworks and methodologies to represent their environmental priorities. Since the early 1990s, the United Nations Statistics Division, the European Union (EU), the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD), the World Bank, in-country statistical offices, and other organizations have made a concerted effort to standardize the framework and methodologies. The United Nations (UN) published an interim handbook on environmental accounting in 1993 (UN 1993), as well as an operational handbook (UN 2000). The former was revised as Integrated Environmental and Economic Accounting 2003 (SEEA). The discussion below describes the different methodologies and how they are related to the revised SEEA. Environmental accounts have four main components: · Natural resource asset accounts, which deal mainly with stocks of natural resources and focus on revising the balance sheets of the system of national accounts (SNA). · Pollutant and material (energy and resources) flow accounts, which provide information at the industry level about the use of energy and materials as inputs to production and final demand, and the generation of pollutants and solid waste. These accounts are linked to the supply and use tables of the SNA, which are used to construct input-output (IO) tables. · Environmental protection and resource management expenditures, which identify expenditures in the conventional SNA incurred by industry, government, and households to protect the environment or manage resources. · Environmentally adjusted macroeconomic aggregates, which include indicators of sustainability such as the environmentally adjusted net domestic product (eaNDP). 122 CHAPTER 9. DEVELOPING AND USING ENVIRONMENTAL ACCOUNTS Environmental Accounts and Concepts of Sustainability A s discussed in earlier chapters, many of the concerns about resource depletion and environmental degradation are reflected in the concept of sustainable development, defined as "... development that meets the needs of the present without compromising the ability of future generations to meet their own needs" (World Commission on Environment and Development 1987). Consistent with Hicks's notion of income (Hicks 1946), sustainability requires nondecreasing levels of capital stock over time or, at the level of the individual, nondecreasing per capita capital stock. Indicators of sustainability could be based on either the value of total assets every period, or by the change in wealth and the consumption of capital (depreciation) in the conventional national accounts. Economic sustainability can be defined as strong or weak, reflecting controversy over the degree to which one form of capital can substitute for another. Weak sustainability requires only that the combined value of all assets remain constant. Strong sustainability is based on the concept that natural capital is a complement to manufactured capital, rather than a substitute. An indicator of strong sustainability, therefore, requires that all natural capital is measured in physical units. A less extreme version of strong sustainability accepts some degree of substitutability among assets, but recognizes that there are some critical assets which are irreplaceable. The corresponding measure of sustainability would be partly monetary (for those assets, manufactured and natural, which are not critical and for which substitution is allowed) and partly physical, for natural assets which are critical. Asset Accounts Natural resource asset accounts follow the structure of the asset accounts of the SNA, with data for opening stocks, closing stocks, and changes during the year. The changes that occur during the period are divided into those that are the result of economic activity (for example, extraction of minerals or harvesting of forests) and those that are the result of natural processes (for example, growth, births, and deaths). There is some controversy over how to treat new discoveries of minerals: as an economic change (the result of exploration activities) or as part of other 123 WHERE ISTHEWEALTH OFNATIONS? volume changes. The monetary accounts for resources have an additional component, like manufactured capital, for revaluation. Measurement of the physical stocks can present problems both as to what to measure as well as how to measure. In some earlier versions of subsoil (mineral) asset accounts, only economically proven stocks were included in the asset accounts. Some countries have modified this to include a portion of probable and possible stocks, based on the probability of these stocks becoming economically feasible to mine. Certain resources, like marine-capture fisheries, are not observed directly and require biological models to estimate stocks and changes in stocks. Two methods have been used to value assets: net present value (NPV) and net price (this is just equal to the total resource rent per unit of resource). The NPV method of valuation requires assumptions about future prices and costs of extraction, the rate of extraction, and the discount rate. It is often assumed that net price and level of extraction remain constant, although when information is known about planned extraction paths or expected future prices, this information can be incorporated. A wide range of discount rates have been used by different countries. In much of the early work on environmental accounting (Repetto and others 1989; Bartelmus and others 1992; van Tongeren and others 1991; UN 1993), the net-price method rather than NPV was used to value assets. The net-price method simply applies the net price in a given year to the entire remaining stock. The revised SEEA recommends NPV, and this method has become more widely used than the net-price method in more recent work. Pollution and Material Flow Accounts Pollution and material (including energy and resource) flow accounts track the use of materials and energy and the generation of pollution by each industry and final demand sector. The flows are linked through the use of a common industrial and commodity classification to IO tables and social accounting matrices (SAMs), as exemplified by the Dutch national accounting matrix, including the environmental accounts (NAMEA) framework, which has been adopted by Eurostat (the European Commission's official statistical agency) and the revised SEEA manual. Much of the work on environmental accounts has been pioneered by industrialized countries and reflects their major policy concerns. 124 CHAPTER 9. DEVELOPINGANDUSING ENVIRONMENTAL ACCOUNTS Physical Accounts The most widely available accounts are for energy and air emissions, especially emissions linked to the use of fossil fuels. Energy accounts have been constructed by many countries since the dramatic oil-price increases of the 1970s, and because many air pollutants are linked to energy use, it is relatively simple to extend the accounts to include these pollutants. Transboundary flows of atmospheric pollutants that cause acid rain have been a major policy concern throughout Europe for more than two decades. More recently, the concern with climate change has made tracking greenhouse gas emissions a priority. Accounts are also constructed for other air pollutants, water pollutants, solid waste, and other forms of environmental degradation such as soil erosion. In a growing number of countries, especially water-scarce countries (Australia, Botswana, Chile, France, Moldova, Namibia, and Spain), water accounts are a high priority. Monetary Accounts for Environmental Degradation In many countries, assigning an economic value to environmental benefits and damage may be considered the most effective way to influence policy, if not the most efficient way to design policy. However, controversy remains over whether these monetary estimates are properly part of the environmental accounts or a separate analysis of the (physical) accounts. Nevertheless, most countries attempt some valuation using one of two different approaches to valuation (or sometimes both, for comparison): · Maintenance, or avoidance cost approach, which measures the cost of measures to reduce pollution to a given standard · Damage cost approach, which measures the actual damage caused by pollution in, for example, reduced agricultural productivity resulting from soil erosion, increased corrosion of structures from acid rain, or damage to human health from water pollution Willingness to pay can be used to value damage costs, although it is not widely used in environmental accounting efforts by countries at this time. Measuring damages caused by pollution is difficult--although it is theoretically the best method to deal with pollution in the accounts, it has not been used as often as the maintenance cost approach. 125 WHERE ISTHEWEALTH OF NATIONS? Monetary Accounts for Nonmarketed Resources Valuation issues discussed in the SEEA have largely focused on environmental degradation, but other nonmarket goods and services also need to be valued. The use of near-market goods like nonmarket firewood or wild-food products are, in principle, included in the SNA, and many countries have included some estimate of these resources in the conventional national accounts. Water, on the other hand, is an example of an economically important resource that is often either not priced or priced in a way that is not related to its true economic value. Environmental Protection and Resource Management Accounts This third component of the SEEA differs from the others in that it does not add any new information to the national accounts, but reorganizes expenditures in the conventional SNA that are closely related to environmental protection and resource management. The purpose is to make these expenditures more explicit, and thus more useful for policy analysis. In this sense, they are similar to other satellite accounts, such as transportation or tourism accounts, which do not necessarily add new information, but reorganize existing information. This set of accounts has three quite distinct components: · Expenditures for environmental protection and resource management, by public and private sectors · The activities of industries that provide environmental protection services · Environmental and resource taxes or subsidies The environmental protection expenditure (EPE) represents part of society's effort to prevent or to reduce pressures on the environment, but the interpretation of indicators from the EPE accounts can be ambiguous. The EPE concept works best for end-of-pipe, pollution-abatement technologies in which an additional production cost is incurred to reduce pollution. The growing trend in pollution management stresses pollution prevention through redesign of industrial processes rather than end-of- pipe technology. New technology may be introduced, perhaps during the normal course of replacement and expansion of capacity that reduces pollution. However, no consensus exists about what share to attribute 126 CHAPTER 9. DEVELOPINGANDUSING ENVIRONMENTAL ACCOUNTS to the EPE. In some instances, process-integrated measures that reduce pollution may reduce costs and pollution simultaneously. The EU is responding to this problem by collecting data about the use of integrated- process technologies. Surveys of recycling are also included. Macroeconomic Indicators Each of the three sets of accounts considered so far provides a range of indicators, but, with the exception of the asset accounts, these indicators do not directly affect the conventional macroeconomic indicators such as gross domestic product (GDP) and net domestic product (NDP). Many practitioners have searched for a way to measure sustainability by revising conventional macroeconomic indicators or by producing alternative macroindicators in physical units. Physical Indicators Macroeconomic indicators measured in physical units have been proposed either as an alternative to monetary indicators or to be used in conjunction with monetary aggregates in assessing economic performance. Physical indicators reflect a strong sustainability approach. The two major sources of physical macroeconomic indicators are the NAMEA component of the SEEA flow accounts and material flow accounts (MFA), which are closely related to environmental accounts. The NAMEA provides physical macroeconomic indicators for major environmental policy themes: climate change, acidification of the atmosphere, eutrophication of water bodies, and solid waste. These indicators are compiled by aggregating related emissions using some common measurement unit, such as carbon dioxide equivalents for greenhouse gases. The indicators are then compared with a national standard--such as the target level of greenhouse-gas emissions--to assess sustainability. The NAMEA does not, however, provide a single-valued indicator which aggregates across all themes. The MFA provide several macroindicators; the most widely known is total material requirements (TMR) (Bartelmus and Vesper 2000; World Resources Institute 2000). TMR sums all the material use in an economy by weight, including hidden flows, which consist of materials excavated or disturbed along with the desired material, but which do not themselves enter the economy. In contrast to NAMEA theme indicators, TMR provides a single-valued indicator for all material use. 127 WHERE ISTHEWEALTH OF NATIONS? Monetary Indicators The purpose of most monetary environmental macroeconomic aggregates has been to provide a more accurate measure of sustainable income. The first approach revised conventional macroeconomic indicators by adding and subtracting the relevant environmental components from the SEEA, the depletion of natural capital, and environmental degradation (O'Connor 2000). Most economists and statisticians accept the adjustment of NDP for asset depletion, in principle, even though there is not yet a consensus over the correct way to measure it. However, some economists and statisticians have criticized environmentally adjusted NDP (eaNDP) for combining actual transactions (conventional NDP) with hypothetical values (monetary value of environmental degradation). If the costs of environmental mitigation had actually been paid, relative prices throughout the economy would have changed, thereby affecting economic behavior and, ultimately, the level and structure of GDP and NDP. A macroindicator related to eaNDP is adjusted net saving (genuine saving), which is reported in the World Bank's annual World Development Indicators (Kunte and others 1998; Hamilton 2000; World Bank 2005), and discussed earlier in detail in chapter 3. The criticism of eaNDP led to the construction of a second approach to constructing indicators, which asks the question, what would the GDP or NDP have been if the economy were required to meet sustainability standards? These indicators of a hypothetical economy are derived through economic modeling. Two modeling approaches were developed: · Hueting's sustainable national income (SNI), which estimates what the level of national income would be if the economy met all environmental standards using currently available technology (Verbruggen and others 2000) · Greened economy NDP (geNDP), which estimates how the economy would respond if the estimated maintenance costs were internalized in the economy International Experience S everal countries construct environmental accounts on a regular basis with various levels of coverage, employing one or more of the above approaches. Table 9.1 identifies the major countries that are constructing 128 CHAPTER 9. DEVELOPING AND USING ENVIRONMENTAL ACCOUNTS Table 9.1 Countries with Environmental Accounting Programs Flow accounts for Environmental pollutants & materials protection & resource management Macro- Assets Physical Monetary expenditures aggregates Industrialized countries Australia X X X Canada X X X Denmark X X X Finland X X X France X X X Germany X X X X X Italy X X X Japan X X X X X Norway X X Sweden X X X X X United Kingdom X X X United States X X Developing countries Botswana X X Xa Chile X Xa X Korea, Rep. of X X X X X Mexico X X X X X Moldova Xa Namibia X X Xa Philippines X X X X X Occasional studies Colombia X X X Costa Rica X EU-15 X Indonesia X South Africa X X Xa Source: Authors. Note: Other European countries have also constructed environmental accounts but are not included here because of the limited policy analysis of the accounts. EU-15: European Union. a. Accounts for water only. 129 WHERE ISTHEWEALTH OF NATIONS? EA on an ongoing basis in their statistical offices or other government ministries. Most of the work is being done in Australia, Canada, Europe, and a few developing countries. Of the developing countries, Botswana, Namibia, and the Philippines are particularly important because policy analysis was built into the EA project design. There are countless other one-time or academic studies, a few of which are referred to in the second part of this chapter. Applications and Policy Uses of the SEEA B roadly speaking, there are two sorts of applications of environmental accounting. The first is closest to statistical tradition and concerns the development of indicators and descriptive statistics of the various subject areas. The second shows how specific policy analyses can be based on the techniques provided by SEEA. Policy analysis usually requires more specialized expertise in the techniques of economic analysis and modeling, which may be lacking in some statistical offices. Use of Asset Accounts for Monitoring and Policy Making One of the fundamental indicators of a country's well-being is the value of its wealth over time. The discussion of sustainability indicated that there are different views about how wealth should be measured, that is, whether all forms of wealth can be measured in monetary terms (weak sustainability) or in some combination of monetary and physical units (strong sustainability). Asset accounts can contribute to more effective monitoring of national wealth. They can also be used to improve management of natural capital. Monitoring Total Wealth and Changes in Natural Capital The asset accounts provide fundamental indicators to monitor sustainability--the value of wealth and how it changes from one period to the next through depreciation or accumulation. Although total wealth and per capita wealth, expanded to include both manufactured and natural assets, are useful indicators, not many countries compile such figures 130 CHAPTER 9. DEVELOPING AND USING ENVIRONMENTAL ACCOUNTS yet. Instead, many countries have focused on compiling accounts for individual resources, sometimes estimating depletion of natural capital, which is used to compile a more comprehensive measure of depreciation than is found in the conventional national accounts Physical asset accounts. The physical asset accounts provide indicators of ecological sustainability and detailed information for the management of resources. The volume of mineral reserves, for example, is needed to plan extraction paths and indicates how long a country can rely on its minerals. The volume of fish or forestry biomass, especially when disaggregated by age class, helps to determine sustainable yields and the harvesting policies appropriate to that yield. The asset accounts track the changes in stock over time and indicate whether depletion is occurring. Thus, they can show the effects of resource policy on the stock and can be used to motivate a change in policy. For example, the biological depletion of Namibia's fish stocks since the 1960s has provided a very clear picture to policy makers of the devastating impact of uncontrolled, open-access fishing (figure 9.1). Similar accounts of depletion (or accumulation) have been constructed for forests in Australia, Brazil, Canada, Chile, Indonesia, Malaysia, the Philippines, and much of the EU. Figure 9.1 Biomass of Hake, Pilchard, Horse Mackerel in Namibia, 1963­1999 16,000 Horse Mackerel Hake Pilchard 14,000 12,000 tons 10,000 of 8,000 6,000 Thousands 4,000 2,000 0 1963 1965 1967 1969 1971 1973 1975 1977 1979 1981 1983 1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 Year Source: Lange 2003a. 131 WHERE ISTHE WEALTH OF NATIONS? Monetary asset accounts. The physical accounts for individual assets can be used to monitor ecological sustainability. However, the economic value of a resource must also be known for a more complete assessment. The monetary value of different assets, produced and nonproduced, can be combined to provide a figure for total national wealth. This figure can be analyzed to assess the diversity of wealth, its ownership distribution, and its volatility resulting from price fluctuations, an important feature for economies dependent on primary commodities. Most countries with asset accounts for natural capital have typically published the accounts separately for each resource and have not attempted to measure total natural capital (the sum of all resources) total national wealth (the sum of manufactured and natural capital). Among developing countries, Botswana (Lange 2000a) and Namibia (Lange 2003a) are doing so. Among the industrialized countries, Australia (Australian Bureau of Statistics 1999) and Canada (Statistics Canada 2000) have integrated nonproduced natural assets with produced assets in their balance sheets. Managing Resources: Economic Efficiency and Sustainability In the early days of environmental accounting, resource rent was calculated in order to calculate the value of assets, but its usefulness as a resource management tool was not always recognized. The work by Norway (Sorenson and Hass 1998), Eurostat (2000) for subsoil assets, in the Philippines Environment and Natural Resource Accounting Project [ENRAP] 1999; Lange 2000b, Botswana (Lange 2000a), Namibia (Lange and Motinga 1997; Lange 2003a), and in South Africa (Blignaut and others 2000) has included detailed analysis of resource rent. Rent has been used to assess resource management in terms of economic efficiency, sustainability, and other socioeconomic objectives, such as intergenerational equity. Physical Flow Accounts for Pollution and Material Use Data from the physical flow accounts are used to assess pressure on the environment and to evaluate alternative options for reducing pressure on the environment. 132 CHAPTER 9. DEVELOPING ANDUSING ENVIRONMENTAL ACCOUNTS Physical Flow Accounts At their simplest, the flow accounts monitor the time trend of resource use, pollution emissions, and environmental degradation, both by industry and in aggregate. A rising level of emissions, for example, would be a clear warning sign of environmental problems. The overview of environmental trends helps assess whether national goals, typically set in terms of total figures for emissions or material use, are being achieved. A great deal of work has been done throughout the industrialized world to construct time series of pollution emissions and energy use. Similar work has been done for water accounts by a number of countries, including Botswana, Chile, France, Moldova, Namibia, the Philippines, South Africa, and Spain. The example for Botswana shows declining per capita water use and declining water intensity of the economy (measured by the GDP per cubic meter of water used), but the volume of water has still increased because population and GDP growth outweigh the gains in efficiency (table 9.2). Table 9.2 Index of Water Use, GDP Growth, and Population Growth in Botswana, 1993 to 1999 (1993 = 1.00) 1993/94 1994/95 1995/96 1996/97 1997/98 1998/99 Volume of water used 1.00 1.01 1.03 0.99 1.04 1.05 Per capita water use 1.00 0.99 0.98 0.92 0.94 0.93 GDP per m3 water used 1.00 1.02 1.06 1.18 1.22 1.26 Source: Lange and others 2000. Note: m3 = cubic meter Policy Analysis The flow accounts are widely used for policy analysis, for example, to assess the impact of environmental tax reform, to design economic instruments to reduce pollution emissions, and to assess competitiveness under new, more restrictive environmental policies. The EU has been the largest user of the accounts and has used them mainly to address two priorities: greenhouse gas emissions and acid rain. Norway has used the flow accounts for energy and greenhouse gas emissions to assess a policy that many countries are considering: changing the structure of taxes to increase taxes on emissions and resource use, 133 WHERE ISTHEWEALTH OF NATIONS? while simultaneously reducing other taxes by an equal amount in order to remain fiscally neutral, the so-called "double dividend." Norway used its multisector, general-equilibrium model to look specifically at increasing the carbon tax to NKr 700 per ton of carbon dioxide with a compensating decrease in its payroll tax. Policy makers in Norway wanted to know what effects this tax reform would have on economic welfare. Using the general-equilibrium model, Norway initially found that employment and economic welfare would increase while carbon emissions declined. However, closer analysis of the results indicated that the tax reform would result in significant structural change in the economy--certain energy-intensive industries in the metal, chemical, and oil-refining sectors were particularly hard hit by the tax, and would reduce output and employment considerably. Environmental Protection and Resource Management Accounts This set of accounts has several quite distinct components, including: · Expenditures for environmental protection and resource management, by public and private sectors · Activities of industries that provide environmental protection services · Environmental and resource taxes or subsidies Environmental Protection Expenditure Accounts Of the three components of this part of the accounts, EPE accounts have been the most widely constructed, mainly in the United States, Canada, the EU, Japan, and Australia. Some developing countries have also constructed EPE accounts, notably Chile, Colombia, the Republic of Korea, and the Philippines. Eurostat has published a handbook with a detailed list of indicators that can be obtained from the EPE accounts, from the most general (for example, time trend of EPE by sector and domain) to detailed (for example, spending within industries by domain). EPE accounts for the United States, for example, show that, as a percentage of GDP, expenditures have remained constant between 1.7 and 1.8 percent. Of the four developing countries that have compiled EPE, coverage differs from country to country. Only Colombia and the Republic of Korea cover EPE by all sectors. Costa Rica and the Philippines have compiled only EPE by government. 134 CHAPTER 9. DEVELOPINGAND USING ENVIRONMENTAL ACCOUNTS Environmental Services Industry While EPE accounts have imposed substantial costs, they have also created opportunities: entirely new industries have arisen to fill the need for environmental services. The second part of the EPE accounts provides a clear definition of environmental services as well as the environmental services industry's contribution to GDP, employment, and exports. For some countries, the environmental services industry has become an important exporter, while other countries are large importers of these services. For example, in France, the environmental services industry accounted for 2.3 percent of GDP and 1.4 percent of employment in 1997. More than half the employment was in solid waste and wastewater management (Desaulty and Templé 1999). Environmental and Resource Taxes The third part of the EPE accounts includes taxes and other fees collected by government for pollution emissions and for resource use, such as levies on minerals, forestry, or fisheries. Environmental taxes and subsidies are important policy instruments for achieving sustainability. Many European countries are exploring the possibility of substituting green taxes for other forms of taxes to achieve a double dividend. The tax component of the EPE account can be very useful in assessing whether the tax regime provides incentives or disincentives for sustainable development, and whether taxes truly reflect the polluter pays principle that many countries have adopted. Taxes on specific natural resources and their use in resource management were discussed in the section on asset accounts. Economywide Indicators of Sustainable Development Many practitioners have searched for a way to measure sustainability either by revising conventional macroindicators or by producing new ones in physical units. Aggregate environmental theme indicators measured in physical units are derived from the NAMEA component of the SEEA. The physical indicators are meant to be used in conjunction with conventional economic indicators to assess environmental health and economic progress. A number of different revised environmental monetary aggregates have been calculated by different countries; all are discussed in the revised SEEA. At this time, there is no consensus over which indicators to use. Because each indicator serves a somewhat different policy purpose, the choice of indicator depends on the policy question. 135 WHERE ISTHEWEALTH OFNATIONS? Physical Indicators of Macrolevel Performance The NAMEA provides physical macroeconomic indicators for major environmental policy themes: climate change, acidification of the atmosphere, eutrophication of water bodies, and solid waste. The indicators can be compared with a national standard--such as the target level of greenhouse-gas emissions--to assess sustainability. A national standard for greenhouse-gas emissions set, for example, in terms of a country's target under the Kyoto Protocol, can be useful. It may not be easy to assess some themes, such as eutrophication, which may have a more local impact, against a national standard. The NAMEA does not provide a single-valued indicator which aggregates across all themes. The material-flow accounts provide another set of physical macroeconomic indicators, of which the most widely known is TMR. The TMR sums all the material use in an economy by weight. Its purpose, like the monetary aggregates, is to provide a single-valued indicator to measure dematerialization--the decoupling of economic growth from material use. The World Resources Institute study of MFA for five industrialized countries finds significant decoupling: since 1975, the material intensity of GDP in all five countries has declined by 20 to 40 percent (figure 9.2). This has been the result of efforts to reduce the volume of solid waste and the shift away from energy- and material-intensive industries toward knowledge-based and service industries. Per capita material intensity has not declined in most countries over this time period. Only Germany showed a decline of 6 percent. Environmentally Adjusted NDP and Related Indicators The most well-known indicator in this category is the eaNDP. Repetto and his colleagues calculated this indicator in their early work on environmental accounting as a way of focusing the attention of policy makers on the importance of environmental degradation and depletion of natural capital. Repetto's work in Indonesia (on petroleum, forests, and land degradation) and Costa Rica (on forests, fisheries, and land degradation) was followed by similar pilot studies in Papua New Guinea and Mexico sponsored by the UN and the World Bank. 136 CHAPTER 9. DEVELOPING AND USING ENVIRONMENTAL ACCOUNTS Figure 9.2. Percentage Change in Material Use in Five Industrialized Countries, 1975­1996 20 10 1996 0 and 1975 10 20 between 30 change % 40 Material intensity of GDP Per capita material intensity 50 Austria Germany Japan Netherlands United States Source: Based on World Resources Institute 2000, table 2, page 20. Notes: Material intensity calculated as domestic processed output per GDP. Per capita material intensity calculated as domestic processed output per population. Domestic processed output domestic extraction imports net additions to stock exports. More recently, a number of countries have calculated partially adjusted eaNDPs, including Germany, Japan, the Republic of Korea, the Philippines, and Sweden. The great differences among countries in terms of the types of coverage and how the maintenance cost approach was implemented make it impossible to directly compare results across countries. The Republic of Korea, for example, assumed the same abatement costs in all industries, whereas the other countries estimated industry-specific abatement costs. Sweden's eaNDP, called Genuine Income, shows the least change from conventional NDP, differing only by 0.6 percent. One reason for this very low figure, despite subtracting some environmental protection expenditures, which other countries did not do, is that it measures only environmental degradation from sulfur and nitrogen. Sweden also excluded degradation not already included in conventional measures of NDP, whereas other studies, notably those of the Republic of Korea and the Philippines, did not explicitly address the issue of potential double counting. The adjustment for Japan and Germany are rather large, mainly because they include the estimated cost of reducing carbon emissions (and for Japan, chlorofluorocarbons). The other studies did not address these global pollutants. 137 WHERE ISTHEWEALTH OF NATIONS? Modeling Approaches to Macroeconomic Indicators Some researchers have criticized eaNDP for combining actual transactions (conventional GDP and NDP) with hypothetical values (monetary value of environmental degradation). The response to this criticism led to the construction of a new set of indicators that seek to estimate what sustainable national income would be if the economy had to change to meet the environmental constraints. Two major approaches were developed--Hueting's SNI and the geNDP. Hueting's SNI is the maximum income that can be sustained without technological development (excluding the use of nonrenewable resources). Using a static, applied general equilibrium model, SNI has been calculated for the Netherlands in 1990 (Verbruggen and others 2000). The authors found that enormous changes would have to occur in order to fulfill the sustainability standards in the short term: SNI is 56 percent lower than national income in the base year; household consumption declines by 49 percent, government consumption by 69 percent, and net investment by 79 percent. An alternative approach, the geNDP, estimates national income looking into a hypothetical future in which economic development must meet certain environmental standards. The impact on the economy is estimated by internalizing the costs of reducing environmental degradation. The purpose of this approach is to provide policy makers with guidance about the likely impacts of alternative development paths and the instruments for achieving them. In these models, technology and other model parameters are not always restricted to what is currently available. Estimates for the Netherlands were carried out by De Boer and others (1994). The Swedish National Institute of Economic Research (NIER) (2000) carried out a similar study focusing specifically on carbon dioxide emissions. General Observations M uch of the use of environmental accounts has been in industrialized countries, especially Australia, Canada, and Europe. The asset accounts are compiled by most countries, but are not generally used 138 CHAPTER 9. DEVELOPINGANDUSING ENVIRONMENTAL ACCOUNTS to assess sustainability. The flow accounts are widely used, both for the construction of indicators and as inputs to policy modeling. The construction of monetary, environmental macroindicators is quite limited, and it is not clear that these indicators have been much used. There are, in addition, four main observations regarding how useful environmental accounts are for policy: · Although some countries are using the environmental accounts quite actively, the accounts are still underutilized, especially in developing countries. · Very few countries have truly comprehensive environmental accounts. · International comparisons are important, but not yet possible, because of differences in methodology, coverage, environmental standards, and other factors. · For a country to fully assess its environmental impact, it must have accounts for the transboundary movement of pollutants via air and water, as well as accounts for its major trading partners to calculate the pollution and material content of products that it imports. The asset accounts have been used to monitor sustainability in various ways, but many countries have not exploited their full potential to monitor characteristics of wealth and changes in wealth over time. This may be the result of the lack of emphasis on conventional asset accounts and measures of wealth. The lack of a consensus in the revised SEEA about a method for measuring the cost of depletion is also a deterrent. The asset accounts could also be more widely used to assist in resource management. Even simple analysis, such as comparison of rent to the taxes on rent and the costs of resource management, is not routinely carried out in countries that compile asset accounts for natural capital. The flow accounts are more widely used for the construction of indicators, environmental profiles, and analysis. Considerable overlap occurs between the SEEA and the sustainability indicators proposed by the United Nations, OECD, and other organizations. Tighter links among these different approaches could be useful. 139 WHERE ISTHEWEALTH OF NATIONS? International Comparability International comparisons are extremely useful for countries in assessing their resource management. The comparisons of water accounts in southern Africa or the environmental damage costs in Europe, for example, are extremely helpful for policy. So far, the comparison of accounts and of the resulting indicators across countries is not generally possible because of the wide range of definitions, coverage, and methodologies used by different countries. Monetary accounts may diverge even more than physical accounts because of the different valuation methodologies, environmental standards, and other assumptions necessary for valuation. With the exception of the genuine saving indicator, it has not been possible to compare monetary environmental macroindicators across countries. Several studies in Europe have shown that the quantities of pollution exported and imported via air and water are very large. Without accurate information about these quantities, the use of environmental accounts for policy will be limited. Similarly, substantial pollution and resources are embodied in international trade. The Swedish study showed that environmental coefficients (whether of pollution emissions or resource use) can diverge substantially among countries, and that a proper assessment of the environmental impact of a country's imports can only be made with information about the environmental coefficients of one's trading partner, from the partner's environmental accounts. In addition, management of global or regional environmental problems, whether climate change or acidification, require comparable environmental accounts for each country. Endnote 1. This chapter is mainly drawn from Lange (2003b) and the SEEA, chapter 11. 140 APPENDIXES SOURCES AND METHODS Appendix 1: Building the Wealth Estimates Appendix 2: Wealth Estimates by Country, 2000 Appendix 3: Genuine Saving Estimates by Country, 2000 Appendix 4: Chanage in Wealth per Capita, 2000 Appendix 1 BUILDING THE WEALTH ESTIMATES This appendix details the construction of the wealth and genuine saving estimates. The wealth estimates are composed of the following components: · Total wealth · Produced capital · Machinery and structures · Urban land · Natural capital · Energy resources (oil, natural gas, hard coal, lignite) · Mineral resources (bauxite, copper, gold, iron, lead, nickel, phosphate, silver, tin, zinc) · Timber resources · Nontimber forest resources · Cropland · Pastureland · Protected areas Intangible capital is calculated as a residual, the difference between total wealth and the sum of produced and natural capital. WHERE ISTHEWEALTH OF NATIONS? Total Wealth T otal wealth can be calculated as Wt = C(s)e­r(s­t)ds ; where Wt t is the total value of wealth, or capital, in year t ; C(s) is consumption in year s; r is the social rate of return from investment.1 The social rate of return from investment is equal to: r = + C ; where r is the pure rate C of time preference, h is the elasticity of utility with respect to consumption. Under the assumption that h = 1, and that consumption grows at a constant rate, then total wealth can be expressed as: Wt = C(t)e­ (s­t )ds (A.1) t The current value of total wealth at time t is a function of the consumption at time t and the pure rate of time preference. Expression (A.1) implicitly assumes that consumption is on a sustainable path, that is, the level of saving is enough to offset the depletion of natural resources. The calculation of total wealth requires that, in computing the initial level of consumption, the following issues be considered: · The volatility of consumption. To solve this problem we used the average of three years of consumption. · Negative rates of adjusted net saving. When adjusted net saving is negative, countries are consuming natural resources, jeopardizing the prospects for future consumption. A measure of sustainable consumption needs to be derived in this instance. Hence, the following adjustments were made: · Wealth calculation considered consumption series for 1998­2000. · For the years in which adjusted net saving was negative, adjusted net saving was subtracted from consumption to obtain sustainable consumption, that is, the consumption level that would have left the capital stock intact. · The corrected consumption series were then expressed in constant 2000 dollars. · The average of constant dollars consumption between 1998 and 2000 was used as the initial level of consumption. 144 APPENDIX 1 BUILDINGTHE WEALTH ESTIMATES For computation purposes, we assumed the pure rate of time preference to be 1.5 percent (Pearce and Ulph 1999), and we limited the time horizon to 25 years. This time horizon roughly corresponds to a generation. We adopted the 25-year truncation throughout the calculation of wealth. Machinery, Equipment, and Structures F or the calculation of physical capital stocks, several estimation procedures can be considered. Some of them, such as the derivation of capital stocks from insurance values or accounting values or from direct surveys, entail enormous expenditures and face problems of limited availability and adequacy of the data. Other estimation procedures, such as the accumulation methods and, in particular, the perpetual inventory method (PIM), are cheaper and more easily implemented since they only require investment data and information on the assets' service life and depreciation patterns. These methods derive capital series from the accumulation of investment series and are the most popular. The PIM is, indeed, the method adopted by most OECD countries that make estimations of capital stocks (Bohm and others 2002; Mas and others 2000; Ward 1976). In our estimations of capital stocks we also use the PIM. The relevant expression for computing Kt, the aggregate capital stock value in period t, is then given by: 19 Kt = I (1­ )i t ­i (A.2) i=0 where I is the value of investment in constant prices and a is the depreciation rate. In equation (A.2) we implicitly assume that the accumulation period (or service life) is 20 years.2 The depreciation pattern is geometric with a = 5 percent assumed to be constant across countries and over time.3 Finally, note that equation (A.2) implies a "One-Hoss- Shay" retirement pattern--the value of an asset falls to zero after 20 years. To estimate equation (A.2) we need long investment series or, alternatively, initial capital stocks.4 Unfortunately, initial capital stocks are not available 145 WHERE ISTHE WEALTH OF NATIONS? for all the countries considered in our estimation, and even in the cases in which there are published data (such as for some OECD, countries), their use would introduce comparability problems with other countries for which those data do not exist. The investment series for the 65 countries with complete data coverage extend from 1960 to 2000. For 16 countries, complete investment series are not available, but for the missing years we have data on output, final consumption expenditure (private and public), exports, and imports. With this information we can derive investment series from the national accounting identity Y = C + I + G + (X - M) by subtracting net exports from gross domestic saving. In all the cases, the ratios of the investment computed this way and the original investment in the years in which both series are available are very close to one. Still, to ensure the comparability between both investment series, we divided the investment estimates derived from the accounting identity by the country-specific median of these ratios for each country. With investment series for 81 countries covering the period 1960­2000, it is even possible to compute capital series estimates that go back to 1979. For the rest of the countries for which the original investment series are not complete (because of lack of data on gross-fixed capital formation or on the required terms to apply the national accounting identity over the period 1960­2000), we tried to overcome the data limitations using a quite conservative approach. We extended the investment series by regressing the logarithm of the investment output ratio on time, as in Larson and others (2000). However, we did not extrapolate output, limiting the extension of the investment series to cases in which a corresponding output observation was available. Urban Land I n the calculation of the value of a country's physical capital stock, the final physical capital estimates include the value of structures, machinery, and equipment, since the value of the stocks is derived (using the perpetual inventory model) from gross capital formation data that account for these elements. In the investment figures, however, only 146 APPENDIX 1 BUILDINGTHEWEALTH ESTIMATES land improvements are captured. Thus, our final capital estimates do not entirely reflect the value of urban land. Drawing on Kunte and others (1998) urban land was valued as a fixed proportion of the value of physical capital. Ideally, this proportion would be country-specific. In practice, detailed national balance sheet information with which to compute these ratios was not available. Thus, as in Kunte and others (1998), we used a constant proportion equal to 24 percent:5 Ut = 0.24Kt (A.3) Energy and Mineral Resources I n this section, the methodology used in the estimation of the value of nonrenewable resources is described. At least three reasons lie behind the difficulties in such calculations. First, the importance of the inclusion of natural resources in the national accounting systems has been recognized only in the last decades, and although efforts to broaden the national accounts are being made, they are mostly limited to international organizations (such as the UN or the World Bank). Second, there are no private markets for subsoil resource deposits to convey information on the value of these stocks. Third, the stock size is defined in economic terms-- reserves are "that part of the reserve base which could be economically extracted or produced at the time of determination"--and, therefore, it is dependent on the prevalent economic conditions, namely technology and prices.6 Despite all these difficulties, dollar values were assigned to the stocks of the main energy resources (oil, gas, and coal7) and to the stocks of 10 metals and minerals (bauxite, copper, gold, iron ore, lead, nickel, phosphate rock, silver, tin, and zinc) for all the countries that have production figures. The approach used in our estimation is based on the well-established economic principle that asset values should be measured as the present discounted value of economic profits over the life of the resource. This 147 WHERE ISTHEWEALTH OFNATIONS? value, for a particular country and resource, is given by the following expression: t+T ­1 Vt = q 1+ r)(i-t) i i/( i=t (A.4) where pi qi is the economic profit or total rent at time i (pi denoting unit rent and qi denoting production), r is the social discount rate, and T is the lifetime of the resource. Estimating Future Rents Though well understood and hardly questioned, this approach is rarely used for the practical estimation of natural asset values since it requires the knowledge of actual future rents. Instead, simplifications of (A.4) that implicitly predict future rents based on more or less restrictive assumptions (such as constant total rents, optimality in the extraction path) are used. The simplification used here assumes that the unit rents grow at rate g : r = g = 1+ ( ­1)(1+ r )T , where = 1.15isthecurvatureofthecost function, assumed to be isoelastic (as in Vincent 1996). Then, the effective discount rate is r*, r* = r ­ g , and the value of the resource stock can be expressed as: 1+ g Vt = tqt 1+ 1 r* 1 1­ (1+ r*)T (A.5) This expression is used to value resource stocks when extraction will extend beyond the year 2000. Choice of T To guide the choice of an exhaustion-time value, we computed the reserves to production ratios for all the countries, years, and resources.8 Table A1 provides the median of these ratios for the different resources. 148 APPENDIX 1 BUILDINGTHEWEALTH ESTIMATES Table A.1 Median Lifetime Years Energy Metals and Minerals Oil 17 Bauxite 178 Gas 36 Copper 38 Hard coal 122 Gold 16 Soft coal 192 Iron ore 133 Lead 18 Nickel 27 Phosphate 28 Tin 28 Silver 22 Zinc 17 With the exception of the very abundant coal, bauxite, and iron, the reserves-to-production ratios tend to be around 20 to 30 years. As in World Bank (1997), we chose the smaller T = 20 for all the resources and countries. From a purely pragmatic point of view, the choice of a longer exhaustion time would demand increasing the time horizon for the predictions of total rents (to feed equation [A.4]). On the other hand, rents obtained further in the future have less weight since they are more heavily discounted. Finally, the level of uncertainty increases the more remote the future is. Under uncertainty, it is unlikely that companies or governments develop reserves to cover more than 20 years worth of production. Timber Resources T he predominant economic use of forests has been as a source of timber. Timber wealth is calculated as the net present value of rents from roundwood production. The estimation then requires data on roundwood production, unit rents, and the time to exhaustion of the forest (if unsustainably managed). The annual flow of roundwood production is obtained from the Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations database 149 WHERE ISTHEWEALTH OF NATIONS? (FAOSTAT).9 Calculating the rent is more complex. Theoretically, the value of standing timber is equal to the discounted future stumpage price received by the forest owner after taking out the costs of bringing the timber to maturity. In practice, stumpage prices are usually not readily available, and we calculated unit rents as the product between a composite weighted price times a rental rate. The composite weighted price of standing timber is estimated as the average of three different prices (weighted by production): (1) the export unit value of coniferous industrial roundwood; (2) export unit value of nonconiferous industrial roundwood; and (3) an estimated world average price of fuelwood. Where country level prices are not available, the regional weighted average is used.10 Forestry production-cost data are not available for all countries. Consequently, regional rental rates ([price-cost]/price) were estimated using available studies and consultation with World Bank forestry experts. Since we applied a market value to standing timber, it was necessary to distinguish between forests available and forests not available for wood supply because some standing timber is simply not accessible or economically viable. The area of forest available for wood supply was estimated as forests within 50 kilometers of infrastructure. Rents were capitalized using a 4 percent discount rate to arrive at a stock of timber resources. The concept of sustainable use of forest resources is introduced via the choice of the time horizon over which the stream is capitalized. If roundwood harvest is smaller than net annual increments, that is, the forest is sustainably harvested, the time horizon is 25 years. If roundwood harvest is greater than the net annual increments, then the time to exhaustion is calculated. The time to exhaustion is based on estimates of forest volume divided by the difference between production and increment. The smaller of 25 years and the time to exhaustion is then used as the resource lifetime. Roundwood and fuelwood production data are for the year 2000, taken from FAOSTAT forestry data online. Data on industrial roundwood (wood in rough) for coniferous and nonconiferous production were obtained from the United Nations Food and Agriculture Organization (UNFAO 2000) yearbook: Forest Products 1997­2001. Fuelwood price data are from FAOSTAT forestry data online. Roundwood export prices are calculated from data from UNFAO Forestry Products 1997­2001. 150 APPENDIX 1 BUILDINGTHE WEALTH ESTIMATES Studies used as a basis for estimating rental rates were Fortech 1997; Whiteman 1996; Tay and others 2001; Lopina and others 2003; Haripriya 1998; Global Witness 2001; Eurostat 2002. Nontimber Forest Resources T imber revenues are not the only contribution forests make. Nontimber forest benefits such as minor forest products, hunting, recreation, watershed protection, and option and existence values are significant benefits not usually accounted. This leads to forest resources being undervalued. A review of nontimber forest benefits in developed and developing countries reveals that returns per hectare per year from such benefits vary from $190 per hectare in developed countries to $145 per hectare in developing countries (based on Lampietti and Dixon 1995 and on Croitoru and others 2005, and adjusted to 2000 prices). We assume that only one-tenth of the forest area in each country is accessible, so this per hectare value is multiplied by one-tenth of the forest area in each country to arrive at annual benefits. Nontimber forest resources are then valued as the net present value of benefits over a time horizon of 25 years.9 Cropland C ountry-level data on agricultural land prices are not widely published, and even if local data were available, it is arguable that land markets are so distorted that a meaningful comparison across countries would be difficult. We have therefore chosen to estimate land values based on the present discounted value of land rents, assuming that the products of the land are sold at world prices. The return to land is computed as the difference between market value of output crops and crop-specific production costs. Nine representative crops were taken mainly based on their production significance in terms of sowing area, production volume, and revenue. With these three aspects taken into consideration the following nine representative crops were considered: maize, rice, wheat, bananas, grapes, apples, oranges, soybeans, 151 WHERE ISTHEWEALTH OFNATIONS? and coffee. Maize, rice, and wheat were calculated individually because they occupy most of the world's agricultural land resources. Bananas, grapes, apples, and oranges were used as proxies for the broader category of fruits and vegetables. Soybeans and coffee were used as proxies for the broader categories of oil crops and beverages, respectively. Roots, pulses, and other crops were calculated as the residual of total arable and permanent cropland minus the sowing areas of the above nine categories. The annual economic return to land is measured as a percentage of each crop's production revenue, otherwise known as the rental rate. The calculated rental rates were obtained from a series of sector studies. For example, the rental rate for rice uses information on rental rates for the Lao People's Democratic Republic (67.6 percent), Egypt (30.6 percent), and Indonesia (56.1 percent) to obtain a world rental rate for rice of 51 percent. The other rental rates used are 30 percent for maize (from China, Egypt, Yemen), 34 percent for wheat (from Egypt, Yemen, Mongolia, Ecuador), 27 percent for soybeans (from China, Brazil, Argentina), 8 percent for coffee (from Nicaragua, Peru, Vietnam, Costa Rica), 42 percent for bananas (from Brazil, Colombia, Costa Rica, Cote d'Ivoire, Ecuador, Martinique, Suriname, Yemen), 31 percent for grapes (from Moldova, Argentina), 36 percent for apples and oranges (the value is based on the average for bananas and grapes, as no sector studies were found). The crop-specific ratios are then multiplied by values of production at world prices. This has the effect of assigning higher land rents to more- productive soils. However, applying average crop-specific ratios in this manner probably understates the value of the most-productive lands and overstates the value of the least-productive land within a country. A country's overall land rent is calculated as a weighted average (weighted by sowing areas) of rents from the 10 crop categories. Return to land for the 10th category (roots, pulses, and other crops) is calculated differently. Since there is no representative crop for it, the land rent is calculated as 80 percent of the weighted average (weighted by sow area) of the three major cereals. This is based on the assumption that roots, pulses, and other crops yield lower returns to land per hectare. In order to reflect the sustainability of current cultivation practices, the annual return in 2000 is projected to the year 2020 based on growth in production (land areas are assumed to stay constant). Between 2020 and 2024, the value of production was held constant. The growth rates are 152 APPENDIX 1 BUILDINGTHEWEALTH ESTIMATES 0.97 percent and 1.94 percent in developed and developing countries, respectively (Rosengrant and others 1995). The discounted present value of this flow was then calculated using a discount rate of 4 percent. Pastureland P astureland is valued using methods similar to those for cropland. The returns to pastureland are assumed to be a fixed proportion of the value of output. On average, costs of production are 55 percent of revenues, and therefore, returns to pastureland are assumed to be 45 percent of output value. Value of output is based on the production of beef, lamb, milk, and wool valued at international prices. As with croplands, this rental share of output values is applied to country- specific outputs of pastureland valued at world prices. The present value of this flow is then calculated using a 4 percent discount rate over a 25-year time horizon. In order to reflect the sustainability of current grazing practices, the annual return in 2000 is projected to the year 2020 based on growth in production (land areas are assumed to stay constant). Between 2020 and 2025, the value of production was held constant. The growth rates are 0.89 percent and 2.95 percent in developed and developing countries respectively (Rosengrant and other 1995). The discounted present value of this flow was then calculated using a discount rate of 4 percent. Protected Areas P rotected areas provide a number of benefits that range from existence values to recreational values. They can be a significant source of income from a thriving tourist industry. These values are revealed by a high willingness to pay for such benefits. The establishment and good maintenance of protected areas preserve an asset for the future, and 153 WHERE ISTHEWEALTH OF NATIONS? therefore protected areas form an important part of the natural capital estimates. The willingness to pay to preserve natural regions varies considerably, and there is no comprehensive data set on this. Protected areas (the World Conservation Union [IUCN] categories I­VI) are valued at the lower of per-hectare returns to pastureland and cropland--a quasi-opportunity cost. These returns are then capitalized over a 25-year time horizon, using a 4 percent discount rate. Limiting the value of protected areas to the opportunity cost of preservation probably captures the minimum value, but not the complete value, of protected areas. Data on protected areas are taken from the World Database of Protected Areas (WDPA), which is compiled by the United Nations Environment Programme World Conservation Monitoring Centre (UNEP-WCMC). Given the frequent revisions to the database, the data used are for 2003. In the cases of missing data on protected areas, they were assumed to be zero. Calculating Adjusted Net Saving A djusted net saving measures the change in value of a specified set of assets, that is, the investment/disinvestment in different types of capital (produced, human, natural). The calculations are not comprehensive in that they do not include some important sources of environmental degradation such as underground water depletion, unsustainable fisheries, and soil degradation. This results from the lack of internationally comparable data, rather than intended omissions. A detailed description of the methodology to obtain adjusted net saving can be found at the World Bank's Environmental Economics website (www.worldbank.org/environmentaleconomics). The following table summarizes the definitions, data sources, and formulas used in the calculations. 154 APPENDIX 1 BUILDING THE WEALTH ESTIMATES Table A.2 Calculating Adjusted Net Saving Item Definition Formula Sources Technical notes Observations Gross national The difference GNS = GNI ­ private WDI, OECD, UN saving (GNS) between GNI and consumption ­ public public and private consumption + net consumption plus net current transfers current transfer. Depreciation The replacement (data taken directly UN Where country data were UN data are not available after (Depr) value of capital used from source or unavailable, they were estimated 1999 for most countries. Missing up in the process of estimated) as follows. Available data on data are estimated. production. depreciation as a percentage of GNI were regressed against the log of GNI per capita. This regression was then used to estimate missing depreciation data. Regression: Dep/GNI = a + (b* Ln(GNI/cap)). The regression was estimated on a five-yearly basis (that is, regression in 1970 was used to estimate depreciation as a percent GNI in years 1970­1974.) Where data were missing for only a couple of years in a country, the same rate of depreciation as a percentage of GNI was applied. Net national Difference between NNS = GNS ­ Depr saving (NNS) gross national saving and the consumption of fixed capital. Education Public current (data taken directly Current education When data are missing, The variable does not include expenditure operating from source or expenditure (public): estimation is done as follows: private investment in education. (EE) expenditures in estimated) UNESCO (1) for gaps between two data It only includes public education, including points, missing information is expenditures, for which wages and salaries filled by calculating the average internationally comparable and excluding of the two data points; (2) for data are available. Notice that capital investments gaps after the last data point education expenditure data are in buildings and available, missing information only available up to 1997. equipment. is filled on the assumption that One dollar's current expenditure on education expenditure is a education does not necessarily yield constant share of GNI. exactly one dollar's worth of human capital (see, for example, Jorgensen and Fraumeni 1992). However, an adjustment from standard national accounts is needed. In national accounts, nonfixed-capital expenditures on education are treated strictly as consumption. If a country's human capital is to be regarded as a valuable asset, expenditures on its formation must be seen as an investment. 155 WHERE ISTHE WEALTH OF NATIONS? Item Definition Formula Sources Technical notes Observations Energy Product of unit ED = production Quantities: OECD, Energy depletion covers crude Prices refer to international rather depletion resource rents volume * average British Petroleum, oil, natural gas, and coal (hard than local prices, to reflect the (ED) and the physical international market International Energy and lignite). social cost of energy depletion. quantities of energy price* unit resource Agency, International Unit resource rent is calculated This differs from national accounts extracted. It covers rent Petroleum as (unit world price ­ average methodologies, which may use coal, crude oil, and Encyclopedia, United cost) / unit world price. Notice local prices to measure energy natural gas. Nations, World Bank, that marginal cost should be GDP. This difference explains national sources. used instead of average cost eventual discrepancies in the Prices: OECD, British in order to calculate the true values for energy depletion and Petroleum, national opportunity cost of extraction. energy GDP. sources. Costs: IEA, Marginal cost is, however, World Bank, national difficult to compute. sources Mineral Product of unit MD = production Quantitites: USGS Mineral depletion covers tin, Prices refer to international rather depletion resource rents volume * average (2005) mineral gold, lead, zinc, iron, copper, than local prices, to reflect the (MD) and the physical international market yearbook. Prices: nickel, silver, bauxite, and social cost of energy depletion. quantities of mineral price* unit resource UNCTAD monthly phosphate. This differs from national accounts extracted. It covers rent commodity price Unit resource rent is calculated methodologies, which may use tin, gold, lead, zinc, bulletin. Costs: as (unit price ­ average cost) / local prices to measure mineral iron, copper, nickel, World Bank, national unit price. Notice that marginal GDP. This difference explains silver, bauxite, and sources cost should be used instead of eventual discrepancies in the phosphate. average cost in order to calculate values for mineral depletion and the true opportunity cost of mineral GDP. extraction. Marginal cost is, however, difficult to compute. Net forest Product of unit NFD = (roundwood Round wood In a country where increment Net forest depletion is not the depletion resource rents production production: FAOSTAT exceeded wood extraction, no monetary value of deforestation. (NFD) and the excess of ­increment) * average forestry database. adjustment to net adjusted Data on roundwood and fuelwood roundwood harvest price* rental rate Increments: World saving was made, no matter production are different from over natural growth. Bank, FAO, UNECE, what the absolute volume or deforestation, which represents a WRI, country-specific value of wood extracted. permanent change in land use, and sources. Rental rates: Increment per hectare on thus is not comparable. various sources productive forest land is adjusted Areas logged out but intended to allow for country-specific for regeneration are not included characteristics of the timber in deforestation figures (see WDI industry. definition of deforestation), but are counted as producing timber depletion. Net forest depletion only includes timber values and does not include the loss of nontimber forest benefits and nonuse benefits. CO damages A conservative figure Data on carbon Data lag by several years so 2 CO2D = emissions CO2 damages include the social (CO2D) of $20 marginal (tons)* $20 emissions can be the data for missing years are cost of permanent damages global damages obtained from the estimated. This is done by taking caused by CO2 emissions. This per ton of carbon WDI the ratio of average emissions may differ (sometimes in large emitted was taken from the last three years of measure) from the market value of from Fankhauser available data to the average CO2 emissions reductions traded in (1994). of the last three years' GDP in emissions markets. constant local currency unit. This ratio is then applied to the missing years' GDP to estimate carbon dioxide emissions. The atomic weight of carbon is 12 and for carbon dioxide 44, and carbon is only (12/44) of the emissions. Damages are estimated per ton but the emissions data are per kilo ton. The CO2 emissions data have therefore been multiplied by 20*(12/44)*1000. 156 APPENDIX 1 BUILDING THEWEALTH ESTIMATES Item Definition Formula Sources Technical notes Observations PM10 Willingness to pay PM10D = disability damages to avoid mortality adjusted life years lost (PM10D) and morbidity due to PM emissions attributable to * WTP particulate emissions. Adjusted net Net national saving ANS = NNS + EE saving (ANS) plus education ­ ED ­ MD ­ NFD expenditure and ­ CO2D ­ PM10D minus energy depletion, mineral depletion, net forest depletion, carbon dioxide damage, and particulate emissions damage. Source: Authors. Endnotes 1. A proof that the current value of wealth is equal to the net present value of consumption can be found in Hamilton and Hartwick 2005. 2. The choice of a service life of 20 years tries to reflect the mix of relatively long-lived structures and short-lived machinery and equipment in the aggregate capital stock and investment series. In a study that derives cross-country capital estimates for 62 countries, Larson and others (2000) also use a mean service life of 20 years for aggregate investment. 3. Again, by choosing a 5 percent depreciation rate we try to capture the diversity of assets included in the aggregate investment series. 4. That is, K t = t i=0 It (1-)i + K0 for t < 20. -i 5. Kunte and others (1998) based their estimation of urban land value on Canada's detailed national balance sheet information. Urban land is estimated to be 33 percent of the value of structures, which in turn is estimated to be 72 percent of the total value of physical capital. 6. U.S. Geological Survey definition. It is clear that an increase in, say, oil price or a reduction in its extraction costs would increase the amount of "economically extractable" oil and therefore increase the reserves. Indeed, U.S. oil production has surpassed several times the proved reserves in 1950. 7. Coal is subdivided into two groups: hard coal (anthracite and bituminous) and soft coal (lignite and subbituminous). 157 WHERE ISTHE WEALTH OF NATIONS? 8. The World Bank database provides good coverage on production data for the 14 resources. Oil and gas reserves data from various issues of The Gas and Oil Journal are also fairly complete. However, reserves data on coal from The World Energy Conference and on metals and minerals from the U.S. Bureau of Mines' Mineral Commodity Summaries are less complete. In fact, for the 10 metals and minerals, the reserves-to-production ratios were computed for a limited number of countries starting in 1987, due to data limitations. 9. When data are missing and if a country's forest area is less than 50 square kilometers, the value of production is assumed to be zero. 10. After consultation with World Bank forestry experts, some country-level prices were replaced by the regional average. 158 Appendix 2 WEALTH ESTIMATES BY COUNTRY, 2000 Wealth Estimates by Country, 2000, $ per Capita Produced capital Country Subsoil Timber Natural + urban Intangible Total name Population assets resources NTFR PA Cropland Pastureland capital land capital wealth Albania 3,113,000 300 38 72 247 1,660 1,574 3,892 1,745 11,675 17,312 Algeria 30,385,000 11,670 68 16 161 859 426 13,200 8,709 ­3,418 18,491 Antigua and Barbuda 72,310 0 0 28 0 1,003 468 1,500 38,796 91,554 131,849 Argentina 35,850,000 3,253 105 219 350 3,632 2,754 10,312 19,111 109,809 139,232 Australia 19,182,000 11,491 748 551 1,421 4,365 5,590 24,167 58,179 288,686 371,031 Austria 8,012,000 485 829 144 2,410 1,298 2,008 7,174 73,118 412,789 493,080 Bangladesh 131,050,000 83 4 2 9 810 52 961 817 4,221 6,000 Barbados 267,000 988 0 0 0 190 210 1,388 18,168 127,181 146,737 Belgium- Luxembourg 10,690,000 20 254 20 0 575 2,161 3,030 60,561 388,123 451,714 Belize 240,000 0 344 1,272 0 5,201 133 6,950 9,710 36,275 52,935 Benin 6,222,000 15 321 96 207 603 90 1,333 771 5,791 7,895 Bhutan 805,000 0 1,888 849 1,291 589 328 4,945 2,622 180 7,747 Bolivia 8,428,000 934 100 1,426 232 1,550 541 4,783 2,110 11,248 18,141 Botswana 1,675,000 246 172 1,681 299 55 730 3,183 8,926 28,483 40,592 Brazil 170,100,000 1,708 609 724 402 1,998 1,311 6,752 9,643 70,528 86,922 Bulgaria 8,170,000 244 126 102 217 1,650 1,108 3,448 5,303 16,505 25,256 Burkina Faso 11,274,000 0 239 142 100 547 191 1,219 821 3,047 5,087 Burundi 6,807,000 4 23 3 7 1,130 44 1,210 206 1,443 2,859 Cameroon 15,117,000 914 348 357 187 2,748 179 4,733 1,749 4,271 10,753 Canada 30,770,000 18,566 4,724 1,264 5,756 2,829 1,631 34,771 54,226 235,982 324,979 Cape Verde 435,000 0 0 44 0 585 82 711 3,902 28,329 32,942 WHERE IS THE WEALTH OF NATIONS? Produced capital Country Subsoil Timber Natural + urban Intangible Total name Population assets resources NTFR PA Cropland Pastureland capital land capital wealth Chad 7,861,000 0 311 366 80 787 316 1,861 289 2,307 4,458 Chile 15,211,000 5,188 986 231 1,095 2,443 1,001 10,944 10,688 56,094 77,726 China 1,262,644,992 511 106 29 27 1,404 146 2,223 2,956 4,208 9,387 Colombia 42,299,000 3,006 134 266 253 1,911 978 6,547 4,872 33,241 44,660 Comoros 558,000 0 17 3 0 872 75 967 1,270 5,792 8,030 Congo, Rep. of 3,447,000 7,536 0 1,450 3 329 13 9,330 6,343 ­12,158 3,516 Costa Rica 3,810,000 2 629 117 657 5,811 1,310 8,527 8,343 44,741 61,611 Côte d'Ivoire 15,827,000 2 367 102 11 2,568 72 3,121 997 10,125 14,243 Denmark 5,340,000 4,173 211 25 1,377 2,184 3,775 11,746 80,181 483,212 575,138 Dominica 71,530 0 .. 146 0 5,274 553 5,973 15,310 37,802 59,084 Dominican Republic 8,353,000 286 27 37 461 1,980 386 3,176 5,723 24,511 33,410 Ecuador 12,420,000 5,205 335 193 1,057 5,263 1,065 13,117 2,841 17,788 33,745 Egypt, Arab Rep. of 63,976,000 1,544 0 0 0 1,705 0 3,249 3,897 14,734 21,879 El Salvador 6,209,000 0 105 4 4 404 395 912 4,109 31,455 36,476 Estonia 1,370,000 384 1,382 341 490 1,114 2,572 6,283 18,685 41,802 66,769 Ethiopia 64,298,000 0 63 16 167 353 197 796 177 992 1,965 Fiji 812,000 77 0 227 0 1,381 522 2,208 4,192 38,480 44,880 Finland 5,172,000 58 6,115 1,259 1,090 843 2,081 11,445 61,064 346,838 419,346 France 58,893,000 87 307 77 1,026 2,747 2,091 6,335 57,814 403,874 468,024 Gabon 1,258,000 24,656 1,570 841 1 1,480 37 28,586 17,797 ­3,215 43,168 Gambia, The 1,312,000 0 0 83 4 345 81 514 672 5,179 6,365 Georgia 5,262,000 66 0 129 66 737 802 1,799 595 10,642 13,036 Germany 82,210,000 269 263 39 1,113 1,176 1,586 4,445 68,678 423,323 496,447 Ghana 18,912,080 65 290 76 7 855 43 1,336 686 8,343 10,365 Greece 10,560,000 318 82 101 57 3,424 573 4,554 28,973 203,445 236,972 Grenada 101,400 0 0 0 0 572 67 640 16,128 38,544 55,312 Guatemala 11,385,000 301 517 57 181 1,697 218 2,971 3,098 24,411 30,480 Guinea- Bissau 1,367,000 0 195 362 0 1,180 121 1,858 549 1,566 3,974 Guyana 759,000 1,147 680 2,886 12 5,324 252 10,301 3,333 2,176 15,810 Haiti 7,959,000 0 8 3 3 668 112 793 601 6,840 8,235 Honduras 6,457,000 24 727 189 282 1,189 595 3,005 3,064 5,497 11,567 Hungary 10,024,000 536 152 42 366 2,721 1,131 4,947 15,480 56,645 77,072 160 APPENDIX 2 WEALTH ESTIMATES BY COUNTRY, 2000 Produced capital Country Subsoil Timber Natural + urban Intangible Total name Population assets resources NTFR PA Cropland Pastureland capital land capital wealth India 1,015,923,008 201 59 14 122 1,340 192 1,928 1,154 3,738 6,820 Indonesia 206,264,992 1,549 346 115 167 1,245 50 3,472 2,382 8,015 13,869 Iran, Islamic Rep. of 63,664,000 11,370 0 26 109 1,989 611 14,105 3,336 6,581 24,023 Ireland 3,813,000 385 222 51 172 1,583 8,122 10,534 46,542 273,414 330,490 Israel 6,289,000 10 0 6 1,350 1,757 877 3,999 44,153 246,570 294,723 Italy 57,690,000 361 0 51 543 2,639 1,083 4,678 51,943 316,045 372,666 Jamaica 2,580,000 856 157 29 609 824 152 2,627 10,153 35,016 47,796 Japan 126,870,000 28 38 56 364 710 316 1,513 150,258 341,470 493,241 Jordan 4,887,000 9 16 4 89 580 234 931 5,875 24,740 31,546 Kenya 30,092,000 1 235 129 113 361 529 1,368 868 4,374 6,609 Korea, Rep. of 47,008,000 33 0 30 441 1,241 275 2,020 31,399 107,864 141,282 Latvia 2,372,000 0 1,155 279 668 1,506 1,877 5,485 12,979 28,734 47,198 Lesotho 1,744,000 0 4 2 1 239 269 515 3,263 11,699 15,477 Madagascar 15,523,000 0 174 171 36 955 345 1,681 395 2,944 5,020 Malawi 10,311,000 0 184 56 26 474 45 785 542 3,873 5,200 Malaysia 23,270,000 6,922 438 188 161 1,369 24 9,103 13,065 24,520 46,687 Mali 10,840,000 0 121 276 44 1,420 295 2,157 621 2,463 5,241 Mauritania 2,508,159 1,311 14 29 21 1,128 480 2,982 1,038 3,938 7,959 Mauritius 1,187,000 0 0 3 0 577 62 642 11,633 48,010 60,284 Mexico 97,966,000 6,075 199 128 176 1,195 721 8,493 18,959 34,420 61,872 Moldova 4,278,000 0 3 17 52 2,435 752 3,260 4,338 1,173 8,771 Morocco 28,705,000 106 22 24 7 993 453 1,604 3,435 17,926 22,965 Mozambique 17,691,000 0 340 392 9 261 57 1,059 478 2,695 4,232 Namibia 1,894,000 46 0 962 260 204 881 2,352 5,574 28,981 36,907 Nepal 23,043,000 0 233 38 81 767 111 1,229 609 1,964 3,802 Netherlands 15,919,000 2,053 27 7 527 1,035 3,090 6,739 62,428 352,222 421,389 New Zealand 3,858,000 3,596 1,648 611 11,786 5,824 19,761 43,226 36,227 163,481 242,934 Nicaragua 5,071,000 9 475 146 184 867 410 2,092 1,719 9,403 13,214 Niger 10,742,000 1 9 28 152 1,598 187 1,975 286 1,434 3,695 Nigeria 126,910,000 2,639 270 24 6 1,022 78 4,040 667 ­1,959 2,748 Norway 4,491,000 49,839 573 586 1,339 567 1,925 54,828 119,650 299,230 473,708 Pakistan 138,080,000 265 7 4 94 549 448 1,368 975 5,529 7,871 Panama 2,854,000 0 176 228 726 3,256 664 5,051 11,018 41,594 57,663 Paraguay 5,270,000 0 882 1,005 78 2,193 1,215 5,372 4,480 25,747 35,600 Peru 25,939,000 934 153 570 98 1,480 341 3,575 5,562 29,908 39,046 161 WHERE IS THE WEALTH OF NATIONS? Produced capital Country Subsoil Timber Natural + urban Intangible Total name Population assets resources NTFR PA Cropland Pastureland capital land capital wealth Philippines 76,627,000 30 90 17 59 1,308 45 1,549 2,673 15,129 19,351 Portugal 10,130,000 41 438 107 385 1,724 934 3,629 31,011 172,837 207,477 Romania 22,435,000 1,222 290 65 175 1,602 1,154 4,508 8,495 16,110 29,113 Russian Federation 145,555,008 11,777 292 1,228 1,317 1,262 1,342 17,217 15,593 5,900 38,709 Rwanda 7,709,000 2 81 9 27 1,849 98 2,066 549 3,055 5,670 Senegal 9,530,000 4 238 147 78 608 196 1,272 975 7,920 10,167 Seychelles 81,131 0 0 84 0 0 0 84 28,836 96,653 125,572 Singapore 4,018,000 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 79,011 173,595 252,607 South Africa 44,000,000 1,118 310 46 51 1,238 637 3,400 7,270 48,959 59,629 Spain 40,500,000 50 81 105 360 2,806 971 4,374 39,531 217,300 261,205 Sri Lanka 18,467,000 0 58 24 166 485 84 817 2,710 11,204 14,731 St. Kitts and Nevis 44,286 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 35,711 64,457 100,167 St. Lucia 155,996 0 0 13 0 3,394 108 3,516 13,594 49,090 66,199 St. Vincent 111,992 0 0 12 0 2,106 109 2,228 10,486 36,518 49,232 Suriname 425,000 4,451 293 1,173 7,626 2,113 210 15,866 5,818 25,444 47,128 Swaziland 1,045,000 0 314 113 0 372 467 1,267 3,628 22,844 27,739 Sweden 8,869,000 263 2,434 908 1,549 1,120 1,676 7,950 58,331 447,143 513,424 Switzerland 7,180,000 0 493 50 2,195 809 2,396 5,943 99,904 542,394 648,241 Syrian Arab Rep. 16,189,000 6,734 0 6 0 1,255 730 8,725 3,292 ­1,598 10,419 Thailand 60,728,000 469 92 55 855 2,370 96 3,936 7,624 24,294 35,854 Togo 4,562,000 7 163 25 21 649 50 915 800 5,394 7,109 Trinidad and Tobago 1,289,000 30,279 42 46 112 444 54 30,977 14,485 12,086 57,549 Tunisia 9,564,000 1,610 27 12 8 1,546 736 3,939 6,270 26,328 36,537 Turkey 67,420,000 190 64 34 86 2,270 861 3,504 8,580 35,774 47,859 United Kingdom 58,880,000 4,739 44 14 495 583 1,291 7,167 55,239 346,347 408,753 United States 282,224,000 7,106 1,341 238 1,651 2,752 1,665 14,752 79,851 418,009 512,612 Uruguay 3,322,000 0 0 88 22 3,621 5,549 9,279 10,787 98,397 118,463 Venezuela, R. B. de 24,170,000 23,302 0 464 1,793 1,086 581 27,227 13,627 4,342 45,196 Zambia 9,886,000 134 276 716 78 477 98 1,779 694 4,091 6,564 Zimbabwe 12,650,000 301 211 341 70 350 258 1,531 1,377 6,704 9,612 Source: Authors. Note: NTFR: non-timber forest resources; PA: protected areas. 162 Appendix 3 GENUINE SAVING ESTIMATES BY COUNTRY, 2000 Revenue Saving, 2000, % of GNI Gross Consumption Net Net national of fixed national Education Energy Mineral forest PM10 CO2 Genuine Country name saving capital saving expenditure depletion depletion depletion damage* damage saving Afghanistan .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. Albania 19.4 9.0 10.4 2.8 1.4 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.4 11.4 Algeria 41.1 11.2 29.9 4.5 39.7 0.1 0.1 0.7 1.0 ­7.3 American Samoa .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. Andorra .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. Angola 54.8 10.6 44.2 4.4 55.9 0.0 0.0 .. 0.5 .. Antigua and Barbuda 19.4 12.6 6.8 3.7 0.0 0.0 0.0 .. 0.3 .. Argentina 13.4 12.1 1.3 3.2 2.4 0.1 0.0 1.6 0.3 0.1 Armenia 4.0 8.1 ­4.2 1.8 0.0 0.1 0.0 2.0 1.1 ­5.4 Aruba .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. Australia 19.5 16.1 3.4 4.9 1.8 1.5 0.0 0.1 0.5 4.3 Austria 22.0 14.5 7.5 5.6 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.2 0.2 12.5 Azerbaijan 18.1 14.9 3.2 3.0 54.5 0.0 0.0 1.0 3.5 ­52.7 Bahamas, The .. 13.2 .. 3.8 0.0 0.0 0.0 .. 0.2 .. Bahrain 27.1 12.7 14.4 4.4 17.6 0.0 0.0 .. 1.5 .. Bangladesh 25.8 5.9 19.9 1.3 1.3 0.0 0.8 0.3 0.4 18.5 Barbados 12.1 12.4 ­0.4 7.2 0.6 0.0 0.0 .. 0.3 .. Belarus 23.8 9.2 14.5 5.4 2.9 0.0 0.0 0.0 2.7 14.3 Belgium 24.3 14.4 9.9 3.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.2 0.3 12.5 Belize 9.2 6.0 3.2 6.2 0.0 0.0 0.0 .. 0.6 .. Benin 10.4 7.7 2.7 2.7 0.2 0.0 1.4 0.3 0.4 3.1 Bermuda .. .. .. 3.3 .. .. .. .. .. .. Bhutan 32.9 9.3 23.6 2.4 0.0 0.0 5.2 .. 0.5 .. Bolivia 11.1 9.2 1.8 4.8 4.8 0.8 0.0 0.7 0.8 ­0.6 Bosnia and Herzegovina 20.8 8.7 12.0 .. 0.2 0.0 0.0 0.4 2.4 .. WHERE IS THE WEALTH OF NATIONS? Gross Consumption Net Net national of fixed national Education Energy Mineral forest PM10 CO2 Genuine Country name saving capital saving expenditure depletion depletion depletion damage* damage saving Botswana 41.9 12.1 29.8 5.6 0.0 0.5 0.0 .. 0.5 .. Brazil 17.8 11.0 6.8 3.7 2.0 0.8 0.0 0.2 0.3 7.2 Brunei .. .. .. 2.9 .. .. .. .. .. .. Bulgaria 13.0 9.8 3.2 3.0 0.3 0.6 0.0 2.1 2.0 1.1 Burkina Faso 11.0 7.1 4.0 2.4 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.5 0.2 5.6 Burundi 0.9 6.1 ­5.2 4.0 0.0 0.0 8.7 0.1 0.2 ­10.2 Cambodia 14.1 7.6 6.5 1.4 0.0 0.0 1.2 0.1 0.1 6.6 Cameroon 14.6 8.9 5.7 2.3 9.4 0.0 0.0 0.7 0.5 ­2.5 Canada 24.6 13.1 11.5 6.9 4.9 0.2 0.0 0.2 0.4 12.7 Cape Verde 9.2 9.5 ­0.3 3.9 0.0 0.0 0.0 .. 0.2 .. Cayman Islands .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. Central African Republic 6.7 7.3 ­0.6 1.6 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.4 0.2 0.5 Chad 0.7 6.8 ­6.1 1.4 0.0 0.0 0.0 .. 0.1 .. Channel Islands .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. Chile 21.3 10.0 11.3 3.5 0.3 6.0 0.0 1.0 0.5 7.0 China 38.8 8.9 29.8 2.0 3.6 0.3 0.1 1.0 1.6 25.5 Colombia 15.5 10.2 5.3 3.1 8.4 0.3 0.0 0.1 0.4 ­0.9 Comoros ­1.2 7.6 ­8.9 4.2 0.0 0.0 0.0 .. 0.2 .. Congo, Dem. Rep. of ­4.6 6.9 ­11.5 0.9 3.3 0.3 0.0 0.0 0.4 ­14.6 Congo, Rep. of 41.0 12.6 28.4 5.9 68.2 0.5 0.0 .. 0.5 .. Costa Rica 13.6 6.2 7.4 5.0 0.0 0.0 0.4 0.3 0.2 11.5 Côte d'Ivoire 8.4 9.1 ­0.7 4.5 4.1 0.0 0.6 0.6 0.6 ­2.1 Croatia 18.1 11.1 7.0 .. 1.3 0.0 0.0 0.3 0.6 .. Cuba .. .. .. 6.1 .. .. .. .. .. .. Cyprus .. 10.6 .. 5.3 0.0 0.0 0.0 .. 0.4 .. Czech Republic 24.5 11.5 13.0 3.9 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.1 1.3 15.4 Denmark 23.5 15.4 8.1 7.9 0.9 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.2 14.8 Djibouti ­2.4 8.5 ­10.9 .. 0.0 0.0 0.0 .. 0.4 .. Dominica 5.7 12.2 ­6.6 5.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 .. 0.3 .. Dominican Republic 19.2 5.4 13.8 2.0 0.0 0.6 0.0 0.2 0.8 14.2 Ecuador 28.3 10.2 18.1 3.2 25.6 0.0 0.0 0.1 1.0 ­5.5 Egypt, Arab Rep. of 16.7 9.5 7.2 4.4 5.6 0.1 0.2 1.4 0.8 3.6 El Salvador 13.9 10.2 3.7 2.4 0.0 0.0 0.7 0.2 0.3 5.0 Equatorial Guinea .. 31.2 .. .. 0.0 0.0 0.0 .. 0.3 .. Eritrea 28.1 5.3 22.8 1.4 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.5 0.5 23.2 Estonia 23.2 14.2 9.0 6.3 0.5 0.0 0.0 0.2 1.8 12.8 Ethiopia 10.5 6.0 4.5 4.0 0.0 0.1 12.4 0.3 0.5 ­4.8 164 APPENDIX 3 GENUINE SAVING ESTIMATES BY COUNTRY, 2000 Gross Consumption Net Net national of fixed national Education Energy Mineral forest PM10 CO2 Genuine Country name saving capital saving expenditure depletion depletion depletion damage* damage saving Faeroe Islands .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. Fiji 4.9 10.4 ­5.4 4.6 0.0 0.2 0.0 .. 0.3 .. Finland 28.3 16.4 12.0 7.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.3 18.6 France 22.0 12.6 9.4 5.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.2 14.3 French Polynesia .. 12.6 .. .. 0.0 0.0 0.0 .. 0.1 .. Gabon 16.6 12.6 4.0 2.7 41.8 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.5 ­35.7 Gambia, The 3.4 7.9 ­4.4 3.4 0.0 0.0 0.5 0.7 0.4 ­2.6 Georgia 12.7 15.6 ­2.9 4.3 0.8 0.0 0.0 2.5 1.2 ­3.0 Germany 20.3 14.9 5.4 4.3 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.2 9.3 Ghana 15.6 7.3 8.4 2.8 0.0 1.5 3.3 0.2 0.7 5.6 Greece 19.1 8.7 10.4 3.1 0.1 0.1 0.0 0.7 0.5 12.2 Greenland .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. Grenada 24.1 11.9 12.3 5.4 0.0 0.0 0.0 .. 0.3 .. Guam .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. Guatemala 12.6 9.8 2.8 1.6 1.1 0.0 1.1 0.2 0.3 1.7 Guinea 17.2 8.0 9.1 2.0 0.0 3.7 1.9 0.6 0.3 4.8 Guinea-Bissau ­15.1 6.9 ­22.1 .. 0.0 0.0 0.0 .. 0.8 .. Guyana 7.9 9.6 ­1.7 3.3 0.0 7.2 0.0 .. 1.4 .. Haiti 27.7 1.8 25.9 1.5 0.0 0.0 0.8 0.2 0.2 26.1 Honduras 25.9 5.6 20.3 3.5 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.2 0.5 23.0 Hong Kong, China 31.8 13.1 18.7 2.8 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.1 21.4 Hungary 23.1 11.8 11.3 4.9 0.7 0.0 0.0 0.4 0.7 14.4 Iceland 14.8 13.5 1.2 5.2 0.0 0.0 0.0 .. 0.2 .. India 24.2 9.6 14.6 3.9 2.3 0.4 0.9 0.7 1.4 12.9 Indonesia 21.0 5.6 15.4 1.4 12.5 1.4 0.0 0.5 1.1 1.3 Iran, Islamic Rep. of 38.0 9.1 28.8 4.0 41.7 0.2 0.0 0.7 1.8 ­11.5 Iraq .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. Ireland 29.5 11.9 17.6 5.7 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.1 0.3 22.7 Isle of Man .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. Israel 17.2 15.1 2.1 6.8 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.3 8.5 Italy 20.1 13.7 6.5 4.4 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.2 0.2 10.3 Jamaica 22.5 11.0 11.6 5.9 0.0 1.5 0.0 0.3 0.8 14.8 Japan 28.4 15.9 12.5 3.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.4 0.1 15.1 Jordan 21.0 10.6 10.4 5.0 0.3 1.3 0.0 0.7 1.1 11.9 Kazakhstan 23.3 9.9 13.4 4.4 41.5 1.0 0.0 0.4 4.2 ­29.2 Kenya 13.4 7.7 5.7 6.0 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.2 0.5 10.9 Kiribati .. 4.8 .. .. 0.0 0.0 0.0 .. 0.2 .. Korea, Dem. People's Republic of .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. 165 WHERE IS THE WEALTH OF NATIONS? Gross Consumption Net Net national of fixed national Education Energy Mineral forest PM10 CO2 Genuine Country name saving capital saving expenditure depletion depletion depletion damage* damage saving Korea, Rep. of 34.0 12.2 21.7 3.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.8 0.5 23.6 Kuwait 40.0 6.5 33.5 5.0 48.7 0.0 0.0 2.0 0.6 ­12.9 Kyrgyz Republic 15.5 7.8 7.7 3.4 1.3 0.0 0.0 0.2 2.1 7.4 Lao PDR 21.1 7.7 13.4 1.8 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.2 0.1 14.8 Latvia 18.2 10.7 7.5 5.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.3 0.5 11.8 Lebanon 2.1 10.2 ­8.1 2.5 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.6 0.5 ­6.6 Lesotho 16.9 6.4 10.5 7.3 0.0 0.0 2.1 0.4 .. .. Liberia .. 8.5 .. .. 0.0 8.0 2.3 0.0 0.6 .. Libya .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. Liechtenstein .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. Lithuania 13.9 10.2 3.7 5.2 0.5 0.0 0.0 0.7 0.6 7.1 Luxembourg 36.0 13.4 22.6 3.7 0.0 0.0 0.0 .. 0.3 .. Macao, China 47.2 12.6 34.6 3.6 0.0 0.0 0.0 .. 0.2 .. Macedonia, FYR 23.5 9.9 13.6 4.9 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.3 1.9 16.3 Madagascar 9.0 7.3 1.7 1.8 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 2.9 Malawi 3.0 6.8 ­3.8 4.4 0.0 0.0 1.6 0.2 0.3 ­1.4 Malaysia 40.1 11.8 28.3 4.7 11.4 0.0 0.0 0.1 1.0 20.5 Maldives 36.8 10.6 26.2 6.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 .. 0.5 .. Mali 13.9 7.1 6.8 2.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.5 0.1 8.3 Malta 15.4 7.5 7.9 4.9 0.0 0.0 0.0 .. 0.4 .. Marshall Islands .. 7.8 .. .. 0.0 0.0 0.0 .. .. .. Mauritania 16.7 7.5 9.1 3.7 0.0 19.9 0.8 .. 1.9 .. Mauritius 25.1 10.8 14.2 3.3 0.0 0.0 0.0 .. 0.4 .. Mayotte .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. Mexico 21.0 10.6 10.4 5.0 5.9 0.1 0.0 0.5 0.4 8.4 Micronesia, Federated States of .. 8.9 .. .. 0.0 0.0 0.0 .. .. .. Moldova 15.6 7.1 8.6 3.5 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.5 2.9 8.7 Monaco .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. Mongolia 29.1 10.8 18.3 5.7 0.0 1.9 0.0 0.5 4.7 16.8 Morocco 22.9 9.4 13.4 4.8 0.0 0.6 0.0 0.2 0.7 16.8 Mozambique 11.2 7.4 3.8 3.8 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.4 0.2 7.0 Myanmar .. .. .. 0.9 .. .. .. .. .. .. N. Mariana Islands .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. Namibia 27.5 13.1 14.4 7.4 0.0 0.3 0.0 0.2 0.3 21.0 Nepal 21.8 2.4 19.5 3.2 0.0 0.0 3.3 0.1 0.4 18.9 Netherlands 26.1 14.7 11.4 4.9 0.5 0.0 0.0 0.4 0.2 15.1 Netherlands Antilles .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. 166 APPENDIX 3 GENUINE SAVING ESTIMATES BY COUNTRY, 2000 Gross Consumption Net Net national of fixed national Education Energy Mineral forest PM10 CO2 Genuine Country name saving capital saving expenditure depletion depletion depletion damage* damage saving New Caledonia .. 12.4 .. .. 0.0 0.0 0.0 .. 0.4 .. New Zealand 17.7 10.9 6.8 6.9 1.3 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.4 11.8 Nicaragua 17.3 9.1 8.2 3.7 0.0 0.1 0.9 0.0 0.6 10.3 Niger 2.6 6.7 ­4.0 2.3 0.0 0.0 4.1 0.4 0.4 ­6.7 Nigeria 25.7 8.4 17.3 0.9 50.8 0.0 0.0 0.8 0.6 ­33.9 Norway 36.9 16.2 20.7 6.1 8.0 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.2 18.5 Oman 29.9 11.7 18.1 3.9 47.8 0.0 0.0 .. 0.6 .. Pakistan 19.9 7.8 12.1 2.3 3.1 0.0 0.8 1.0 0.9 8.6 Palau .. 10.9 .. .. 0.0 0.0 0.0 .. 1.2 .. Panama 24.9 7.9 17.0 4.5 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.3 0.3 20.8 Papua New Guinea .. 8.9 .. .. 17.8 11.7 0.0 0.0 0.4 .. Paraguay 14.5 9.5 5.0 3.9 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.4 0.3 8.2 Peru 18.1 10.2 7.8 2.6 1.4 1.6 0.0 0.6 0.3 6.5 Philippines 26.7 8.2 18.5 2.8 0.0 0.1 0.8 0.4 0.6 19.5 Poland 18.8 11.0 7.8 6.3 0.5 0.1 0.0 0.7 1.1 11.7 Portugal 18.8 15.3 3.5 5.7 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.4 0.3 8.5 Puerto Rico .. 11.2 .. .. 0.0 0.0 0.0 .. 0.1 .. Qatar .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. Romania 15.5 9.7 5.8 3.6 4.4 0.1 0.0 0.2 1.4 3.3 Russian Federation 37.1 10.0 27.1 3.5 39.6 0.4 0.0 0.6 3.4 ­13.4 Rwanda 12.7 7.1 5.6 3.5 0.0 0.0 3.0 0.0 0.2 5.9 Samoa .. 9.5 .. 4.0 0.0 0.0 1.8 .. 0.3 .. São Tomé and Principe ­3.3 8.0 ­11.2 .. 0.0 0.0 0.0 .. 1.2 .. Saudi Arabia 29.4 10.0 19.5 7.2 51.0 0.0 0.0 1.0 1.2 ­26.5 Senegal 11.6 8.1 3.5 3.7 0.0 0.1 0.3 .. 0.6 .. Serbia and Montenegro ­2.6 8.7 ­11.3 .. 2.3 0.3 0.0 0.2 3.5 .. Seychelles 19.5 9.5 10.1 6.3 0.0 0.0 0.0 .. 0.2 .. Sierra Leone 2.7 6.4 ­3.8 3.9 0.0 0.0 6.3 0.4 0.5 ­7.1 Singapore 47.7 14.0 33.7 2.3 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.4 0.4 35.2 Slovak Republic 22.9 11.0 12.0 4.0 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.1 1.1 14.7 Slovenia 23.8 12.0 11.8 5.4 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.2 0.5 16.5 Solomon Islands .. 8.5 .. 3.8 0.0 0.1 10.4 .. 0.3 .. Somalia .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. South Africa 15.7 13.3 2.4 7.5 0.0 1.0 0.3 0.2 1.6 6.9 Spain 23.0 12.9 10.1 4.4 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.4 0.3 13.7 Sri Lanka 21.9 5.2 16.7 2.9 0.0 0.0 0.5 0.3 0.4 18.4 St. Kitts and Nevis 32.9 12.9 20.0 3.9 0.0 0.0 0.0 .. 0.2 .. 167 WHERE IS THE WEALTH OF NATIONS? Gross Consumption Net Net national of fixed national Education Energy Mineral forest PM10 CO2 Genuine Country name saving capital saving expenditure depletion depletion depletion damage* damage saving St. Lucia 16.3 11.7 4.6 7.7 0.0 0.0 0.0 .. 0.3 .. St. Vincent 19.3 11.1 8.2 4.7 0.0 0.0 0.0 .. 0.3 .. Sudan 7.6 9.2 ­1.5 0.9 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.6 0.3 ­1.6 Suriname ­0.6 9.1 ­9.7 .. 12.1 2.1 0.0 .. 1.4 .. Swaziland 13.4 9.1 4.3 5.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.2 9.1 Sweden 22.3 14.0 8.3 7.7 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.1 15.8 Switzerland 32.8 14.5 18.3 4.9 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.2 0.1 22.9 Syrian Arab Rep. 24.3 9.6 14.7 3.5 34.5 0.1 0.0 0.8 1.9 ­19.1 Taiwan, China 25.6 12.3 13.3 .. 0.0 0.0 0.0 .. 0.4 .. Tajikistan 1.7 7.0 ­5.3 2.0 0.7 0.0 0.0 0.2 2.5 ­6.7 Tanzania 12.4 7.4 5.1 2.4 0.0 0.2 0.0 0.2 0.3 6.8 Thailand 30.9 14.9 15.9 3.6 1.6 0.0 0.3 0.4 1.0 16.3 Togo 0.9 7.5 ­6.6 4.2 0.0 0.2 4.3 0.3 0.8 ­7.9 Tonga ­13.7 9.6 ­23.3 4.7 0.0 0.0 0.1 .. 0.4 .. Trinidad and Tobago 28.7 12.4 16.3 4.2 29.7 0.0 0.0 0.0 2.1 ­11.4 Tunisia 24.3 10.0 14.3 6.4 4.8 0.6 0.2 0.3 0.6 14.1 Turkey 20.1 6.8 13.2 3.1 0.3 0.0 0.0 1.2 0.7 14.1 Turkmenistan 50.5 8.9 41.6 .. 182.7 0.0 0.0 0.3 7.7 .. Uganda 15.0 7.3 7.7 1.9 0.0 0.0 6.1 0.0 0.2 3.4 Ukraine 25.6 19.4 6.2 6.4 7.4 0.0 0.0 1.0 6.7 ­2.5 United Arab Emirates .. .. .. .. .. .. .. 0.0 .. .. United Kingdom 15.0 11.5 3.5 5.3 1.1 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.2 7.3 United States 17.4 11.7 5.7 4.2 1.2 0.0 0.0 0.3 0.3 8.2 Uruguay 11.2 11.6 ­0.4 2.7 0.0 0.0 0.0 1.9 0.2 0.2 Uzbekistan 18.2 8.4 9.8 9.4 42.1 0.0 0.0 0.6 5.2 ­28.6 Vanuatu .. 9.8 .. 6.9 0.0 0.0 0.0 .. 0.2 .. Venezuela, R. B. de 28.5 7.2 21.3 4.4 27.3 0.3 0.0 0.0 0.8 ­2.7 Vietnam 31.7 7.9 23.8 2.8 8.7 0.1 1.0 0.4 1.1 15.5 Virgin Islands (U.S.) .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. West Bank and Gaza ­5.5 8.2 ­13.6 .. 0.0 0.0 0.0 .. .. .. Yemen, Rep. of 34.4 8.9 25.5 .. 43.2 0.0 0.0 0.5 0.6 .. Zambia 4.0 7.9 ­3.9 2.0 0.0 2.5 0.0 .. 0.4 .. Zimbabwe 11.9 8.5 3.3 6.9 0.0 0.6 0.0 0.5 1.3 7.8 Source: Authors. *Data for particulate matter damage are for 2001. .. means missing values. 168 Appendix 4 CHANGE IN WEALTH PER CAPITA, 2000 Change in Wealth per Capita, 2000, $ per Capita % Adjusted Change in GNI per Population net saving wealth per Saving gap % Country name capita growth rate per capita capita of GNI Albania 1,220 0.4 145 122 Algeria 1,670 1.4 ­93 ­409 24.5 Antigua and Barbuda 8,700 2.0 911 94 Argentina 7,718 0.9 154 ­109 1.4 Australia 19,703 1.1 963 46 Austria 23,403 0.2 3,032 2,831 Bangladesh 373 1.7 71 41 Barbados 9,344 0.3 588 520 Belgium-Luxembourg 21,756 0.3 2,811 2,649 Belize 3,230 2.7 303 ­150 4.6 Benin 360 2.6 14 ­42 11.5 Bhutan 532 2.9 111 ­111 20.9 Bolivia 969 2.0 9 ­127 13.1 Botswana 2,925 1.7 1,021 814 Brazil 3,432 1.2 265 64 Bulgaria 1,504 ­1.8 80 238 Burkina Faso 230 2.5 15 ­36 15.8 Burundi 97 1.9 ­10 ­37 37.7 Cameroon 548 2.2 ­8 ­152 27.7 Canada 22,612 0.9 3,006 2,221 Cape Verde 1,195 2.7 43 ­81 6.8 WHERE ISTHE WEALTH OFNATIONS? % Adjusted Change in GNI per Population net saving wealth per Saving gap % Country name capita growth rate per capita capita of GNI Chad 174 3.1 ­8 ­74 42.6 Chile 4,779 1.3 406 129 China 844 0.7 236 200 Colombia 1,926 1.7 ­6 ­205 10.6 Comoros 367 2.5 ­17 ­73 19.9 Congo, Rep. of 660 3.2 ­227 ­727 110.2 Costa Rica 3,857 2.1 464 107 Côte d'Ivoire 625 2.3 ­5 ­100 16.0 Denmark 29,009 0.4 4,376 4,014 Dominica 3,344 ­0.3 ­53 7 Dominican Republic 2,234 1.6 341 198 Ecuador 1,170 1.5 ­51 ­293 25.1 Egypt, Arab Rep. of 1,569 1.9 91 ­45 2.9 El Salvador 2,075 1.5 113 37 Estonia 3,836 ­0.5 570 681 Ethiopia 101 2.4 ­4 ­27 27.1 Fiji 2,055 1.4 ­23 ­109 5.3 Finland 22,893 0.1 4,334 4,236 France 22,399 0.5 3,249 2,951 Gabon 3,370 2.3 ­1,183 ­2,241 66.5 Gambia, The 305 3.4 ­5 ­45 14.6 Georgia 601 ­0.5 4 16 Germany 22,641 0.1 2,180 2,071 Ghana 255 1.7 16 ­18 7.2 Greece 10,706 0.3 1,431 1,327 Grenada 3,671 0.7 650 533 Guatemala 1,676 2.6 37 ­123 7.3 Guyana 870 0.4 ­49 ­108 12.4 Haiti 503 2.0 133 106 Honduras 897 2.6 213 53 Hungary 4,370 ­0.4 676 765 India 446 1.7 67 16 Indonesia 675 1.3 20 ­56 8.4 170 APPENDIX 4 CHANGE INWEALTH PER CAPITA, 2000 % Adjusted Change in GNI per Population net saving wealth per Saving gap % Country name capita growth rate per capita capita of GNI Iran, Islamic Rep. of 1,580 1.5 ­142 ­398 25.2 Ireland 21,495 1.3 4,964 4,199 Israel 17,354 2.6 1,540 268 Italy 18,478 0.1 1,990 1,947 Jamaica 2,954 0.8 471 371 Japan 37,879 0.2 5,906 5,643 Jordan 1,727 3.1 236 28 Kenya 343 2.3 40 ­11 3.2 Korea, Rep. of 10,843 0.8 2,694 2,415 Latvia 3,271 ­0.8 412 551 Madagascar 245 3.1 9 ­56 22.7 Malawi 162 2.1 ­2 ­29 18.2 Malaysia 3,554 2.4 767 227 Mali 221 2.4 20 ­47 21.2 Mauritania 382 2.9 ­30 ­147 38.4 Mauritius 3,697 1.1 645 514 Mexico 5,783 1.4 545 155 Moldova 316 ­0.2 38 56 Morocco 1,131 1.6 200 117 Mozambique 195 2.2 15 ­20 10.0 Namibia 1,820 3.2 392 140 Nepal 239 2.4 46 2 Netherlands 23,382 0.7 3,673 3,176 New Zealand 12,679 0.6 1,550 1,082 Nicaragua 739 2.6 81 ­18 2.4 Niger 166 3.3 ­10 ­83 50.3 Nigeria 297 2.4 ­97 ­210 70.6 Norway 36,800 0.7 6,916 5,708 Pakistan 517 2.4 54 ­2 0.4 Panama 3,857 1.5 829 585 Paraguay 1,465 2.3 131 ­93 6.4 Peru 1,991 1.5 148 15 Philippines 1,033 2.3 211 114 171 WHERE ISTHE WEALTH OF NATIONS? % Adjusted Change in GNI per Population net saving wealth per Saving gap % Country name capita growth rate per capita capita of GNI Portugal 10,256 0.6 943 750 Romania 1,639 ­0.1 80 89 Russian Federation 1,738 ­0.5 ­164 4 Rwanda 233 2.9 14 ­60 26.0 Senegal 449 2.6 31 ­27 6.1 Seychelles 7,089 0.9 1,162 904 Singapore 22,968 1.7 8,258 6,949 South Africa 2,837 2.5 246 ­2 0.1 Spain 13,723 0.7 1,987 1,663 Sri Lanka 868 1.4 166 116 St. Kitts and Nevis 6,746 4.7 1,612 ­63 0.9 St. Lucia 4,103 1.5 507 253 St. Vincent 2,824 0.2 365 336 Swaziland 1,375 2.5 129 8 Sweden 26,809 0.1 4,278 4,191 Switzerland 37,165 0.6 8,611 8,020 Syrian Arab Republic 1,064 2.5 ­175 ­473 44.5 Thailand 1,989 0.8 351 259 Togo 285 4.0 ­20 ­88 30.8 Trinidad and Tobago 5,838 0.5 ­541 ­774 13.3 Tunisia 1,936 1.1 291 176 Turkey 2,980 1.7 476 273 United Kingdom 24,606 0.3 1,882 1,725 United States 35,188 1.1 3,092 2,020 Uruguay 5,962 0.6 137 20 Venezuela, R. B. de 4,970 1.8 ­94 ­847 17.0 Zambia 312 2.0 ­13 ­63 20.4 Zimbabwe 550 2.0 53 ­4 0.7 Source: Authors. Note: Countries with saving gap are those with negative changes in wealth per capita. 172 REFERENCES Adams, Richard H. Jr., and John Page. 2003. "International Migration, Remittances and Poverty in Developing Countries." Policy Research Working Paper 3179, World Bank, Washington DC. Aronsson T., P.-O. Johansson, K.-G. Lofgren. 1997. Welfare Measurement, Sustainability and Green National Accounting. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd. Arrow, K. J., P. Dasgupta, and K.-G. Mäler. 2003a. "Evaluating Projects and Assessing Sustainable Development in Imperfect Economies." Environmental and Resource Economics 26 (4): 647­85. ------. 2003b. "The Genuine Savings Criterion and the Value of Population." Economic Theory 21(2­3): 217­25. Arrow, K. J., and others. 2004. "Are We Consuming Too Much?" Journal of Economic Perspectives 18 (3): 147­72. Atkinson, G., and K. Hamilton. 2003. "Savings, Growth and the Resource Curse Hypothesis." World Development 31:1793­1807. Australian Bureau of Statistics. 1999. Consolidated Balance Sheet. ABS: Canberra. Auty, Richard M., ed. 2001. Resource Abundance and Economic Development. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Barro R., and J. W. Lee. 2000. "International Data on Educational Attainment: Updates and Implications." CID Working Paper 42, Center for International Development, Harvard University, Cambridge MA. Bartelmus, P., E. Lutz, and S. Schweinfest. 1992. "Integrated Environmental and Economic Accounting: A Case Study for Papua-New Guinea." Environmental Working Paper 54, World Bank, Washington, DC. Bartelmus P., and A. Vesper. 2000. "Green accounting and material flow analysis: Alternatives or complements?" Wuppertal Institute Paper No. 106. Beck, T., A. Demirgüç-Kunt, and R. Levine. 1999. "A New Database on Financial Development and Structure." World Bank Economic Review 14 (3): 597­605. REFERENCES Becker, G. S. 1964. Human Capital: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis, With Special Reference to Education. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER), Columbia University Press. Behrman, Jere R., and Paul J. Taubman. 1982. "Human Capital." In Encyclopedia of Economics, ed. Douglas Greenwald, 474­76. New York: McGraw-Hill Book Company. Berndt, E. R., and B. C. Field., eds. 1981. Modeling and Measuring Natural Resource Substitution. Cambridge MA: MIT Press. Berry L., J. Olson, and D. Campbell. 2003. "Assessing the Extent, Cost and Impact of Land Degradation at the National Level: Findings and Lessons Learned from Seven Pilot Countries." Photocopy. Paper commissioned by the Global Mechanism of the UN Commission to Combat Desertification. Rome: Global Mechanism of the UNCCD. Bjorklund, Anders, and Christian Kjellstrom. 2002. "Estimating the Return to Investments in Education: How Useful Is the Standard Mincer Equation?" Economics of Education Review 21: 195­210. Blignaut, J. N.; R. M. Hassan. 2001. "A Natural Resource Accounting Analysis of the Contribution of Mineral Resources to Sustainable Development in South Africa." South African Journal of Economic and Management Sciences, N.S. v0, n.0 (Supplement April 2001) Bohm, B., A. Gleiss, M. Wagner, and D. Ziegler. 2002. "Dissagregated Capital Stock Estimation for Austria--Methods, Concepts and Results." Applied Economics 34: 23­37. Caselli, F. Forthcoming. "The Missing Input: Accounting for Cross-Country Income Differences." In Handbook of Economic Growth, ed. P. Aghion and S. Durlauf. Amsterdam: North Holland. Chang, K. 1994. "Capital-Energy Substitution and the Multi-Level CES Production Function." Energy Economics 16 (1): 22­26. Chiang, A. C. 1984. Fundamental Methods of Mathematical Economics. 3rd edition. Singapore: McGraw-Hill Book Company. Croitoru L., P. Gatto, M. Merlo, and P. Paiero., ed. 2005. Valuing Mediterranean Forests-- Towards the Total Economic Value. Rome: CABI Publishing. Dasgupta, P. 2001. Human Well-Being and the Natural Environment. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Dasgupta, P., and K.-G. Mäler. 2000. "Net National Product, Wealth, and Social Well- Being. Environment and Development Economics 5: 69­93. De Boer, B., M. de Haan, and M. Voogt. 1994. "What would Net Domestic Product have been in an environmentally sustainable economy?" Presented in Papers and Proceedings of the Meeting on National Accounts and the Environment, 16-18 March, London. Desaulty, D. and P. Templé. 1999. "In 1997, France Spent 145 Billion Francs on Environmental Protection." Les données de l'environnement--Economie, No. 46, Orleans: Institut Français de l'Environnement. Dixit A., P. Hammond, and M. Hoel. 1980. "On Hartwick's Rule for Regular Maximum Paths of Capital Accumulation and Resource Depletion." Review of Economic Studies 47 (3): 551­56. 174 REFERENCES Dixon, J., K. Hamilton, and A. Kunte. 1997. "Measuring the Wealth of Nations," Expanding the Measure of Wealth: Indicators of Environmentally Sustainable Development. Environmentally Sustainable Development Studies and Monographs, Series 17. Washington, DC: World Bank. ENRAP (Environment and Natural Resources Accounting Project). 1999. ENRAP- SHELF (Searchable Hyperlink Electronic Library of Files) CD-ROM. CD containing all accounts and technical reports from the Philippine Environmental and Natural Resource Accounting Project. Manila: ENRAP. Eurostat. 2000. Accounts for Sub-Soil Assets: Results of Pilot Studies in European Countries. Luxembourg: Eurostat. ------. 2002. Natural Resource Accounts for Forests. Detailed Tables. Luxembourg: European Communities. Fankhauser, S. 1994. "The Social Costs of Greenhouse Gas Emissions: An Expected Value Approach." Energy Journal 15 (2): 157­84. Ferreira, S., K. Hamilton, and J. Vincent. 2003. "Comprehensive Wealth and Future Consumption." Photocopy. World Bank, Washington, DC. Ferreira, S., and J. Vincent. 2005. "Genuine Savings: Leading Indicator of Sustainable Development?" Economic Development and Cultural Change 53: 737­54. Fisher, I. 1906. Nature of Capital and Income. New York: Macmillan. Fortech--Dames & Moore Company. 1997. "Marketing of PNG Forest Products Milestone 2 Project: Logging and Processing Costs in Papua New Guinea." Australia: Forestry Technical Services Pty, Ltd. Global Witness. 2001. "Taylor-made: The Pivotal Role of Liberia's Forests and Flag of Convenience in Regional Conflict." United Kingdom: Global Witness Limited. http://www.globalwitness.org/campaigns/forests/liberia/downloads/taylormade2.pdf Greene, W. 2000. Econometric Analysis. 4th edition. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall. Gretton, Paul, and Umme Salma. 1996. "Land Degradation and the Australian Agricultural Industry." Industry Commission Staff Information Paper, Government of Australia, Camberra. Gylfason, Thorvaldur. 2001. "Natural Resources, Education and Economic Development." European Economic Review 45: 847­59. Hamilton, K. 1994. "Green Adjustments to GDP." Resources Policy 20 (3): 155­68. ------. 1995. "Sustainable Development, the Hartwick Rule and Optimal Growth." Environmental and Resource Economics 5: 393­411. ------. 2000. "Greening the National Accounts: Formal Models and Practical Measurement." In Greening the Accounts, ed. J. L. R. Proops and S. Simon. Cheltenham, U.K.: Edward Elgar Publishers. ------. 2005. "Testing Genuine Saving." Policy Research Working Paper 3577, World Bank, Washington, DC. Hamilton, K., and M. Clemens. 1999. "Genuine Savings Rates in Developing Countries." World Bank Economic Review 13 (2): 333­56. 175 REFERENCES Hamilton, K., and J. M. Hartwick. 2005. "Investing Exhaustible Resource Rents and the Path of Consumption." Canadian Journal of Economics 38 (2): 615­21. Hamilton, K., and C. Withagen. 2004. "Savings, Welfare and Rules for Sustainability." Photocopy. World Bank, Washington, DC. Hamilton, K., G. Ruta, and L. Tajibaeva. Forthcoming. "Capital Accumulation and Resource Depletion: A Hartwick Rule Counterfactual." Environmental and Resource Economics. Haripriya, G.S. 1998. "Forest Resource Accounting: Preliminary Estimates for the State of Maharashtra." Development Policy Review 16: 131­51. Hartwick, John M. 1977. "Intergenerational Equity and the Investing of Rents from Exhaustible Resources." American Economic Review 66: 972­74. Hicks, J. R. 1946. Value and Capital. 2nd Edition. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Hnatkovska, V., and N. Loayza. 2004. "Volatility and Growth." In Managing Volatility and Crises: A Practitioner's Guide, ed. B. Pinto and others. Washington, DC: World Bank. Jorgensen, D. W. and B. M. Fraumeni. 1992. "The Output of the Education Sector." In Zvi Griliches, ed., Output Measurement in the Service Sectors. Chicago: University of Chicago Press." Jorgensen, Dale W., and Eric Yip. 2001. "Whatever Happened to Productivity Growth." In New Developments in Productivity Analysis, ed. Charles R. Hulten, Edwin R. Dean, and J. Michael Harper. NBER Studies in Income and Wealth 63. Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press. Kaufmann, D., A. Kraay, and M. Mastruzzi. 2005. "Governance Matters IV: Governance Indicators for 1996­2004." Policy Research Working Paper 3630, World Bank, Washington DC. Kemfert, C. 1998. "Estimated Production Elasticities of a Nested CES Production Function Approach for Germany." Energy Economics 20: 249­64. Kemfert, C., and H. Welsch. 2000. "Energy-Capital-Labor Substitution and the Economic Effects of CO2 Abatement: Evidence for Germany." Journal of Policy Modeling 22 (6): 641­60. Kent, A. 1972. "Optimal Growth When the Stock of Resources is Finite and Depletable." Journal of Economic Theory 4 (2): 256­67. Kunte, A., K. Hamilton, J. Dixon, and M. Clemens. 1998. "Estimating National Wealth: Methodology and Results." Environment Department Paper 57, World Bank, Washington, DC. Lampietti, J., and J. Dixon. 1995. "To See the Forest for the Trees: A Guide to Non- Timber Forest Benefits." Environment Department Paper 13. World Bank, Washington DC. Lange, G.-M. 1997. "Strategic Planning for Sustainable Development in Indonesia Using Natural Resource Accounts." In Economy and Ecosystems in Change: Analytical and Historical Approaches, ed. J. van den Bergh and J. van der Straaten. Aldershott, U.K.: Edward Elgar Publishing. 176 REFERENCES ------. 2000a. "The Contribution of Minerals to Sustainable Economic Development in Botswana." Report to the Botswana Natural Resource Accounting Programme, National Conservation Strategy Agency and Ministry of Finance, Central Statistics Office. Gaborone, Botswana. ------. 2000b. "The Use and Policy Applications of the Philippine System of Environmental and Natural Resource Accounts." Report for the Philippines National Statistical Coordinating Board. Manila. ------. 2003a. "Fisheries Accounting in Namibia." In Natural Resource Accounting and Economic Development: Theory and Practice, ed. C. Perrings and J. Vincent. Cheltenham, U.K.: Edward Elgar Publishers. ------. 2003b. "Policy Application of Environmental Accounting." Environment Department Paper 88. Washington DC: World Bank. Lange, G., and D.J. Motinga. 1997. "The Contribution of Resource Rents from Minerals and Fisheries to Sustainable Economic Development in Namibia, 1980 to 1995. Research Discussion Paper 19. Directorate of Environmental Affairs, Ministry of Environment and Tourism: Windhoek, Namibia. Lange, G.-M., J. Arntzen, S. Kabaija, and M. Monamati. 2000. "Botswana's Natural Resource Accounts: The Case of Water." Report to the Botswana Natural Resource Accounting Programme, National Conservation Strategy Agency and Ministry of Finance, Central Statistics Office. Gaborone, Botswana. Lange, G.M., R. Hassan, and K. Hamilton. 2003. Environmental Accounting in Action: Case Studies from Southern Africa. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing. Lange, G.-M., and M. Wright. 2004. "Sustainable Development in Mineral Economies: the Example of Botswana." Environment and Development Economics 9 (4): 485­505. Larson, Donald F., Rita Butzer, Yair Mundlak, and Al Crego. 2000. "A Cross-Country Database for Sector Investment and Capital." The World Bank Economic Review 14 (2): 371­91. Lopina, Olga, Andrei Ptichnikov, and Alexander Voropayev. 2003. Illegal Logging in Northwestern Russia and Exports of Russian Forest Products to Sweden. Russia: World Wildlife Fund. Manne, A., and R. Richels. 1992. Buying Greenhouse Insurance: The Economic Costs of CO2 Emission Limits. Cambridge MA: MIT Press. Mas, Matilde, Francisco Perez, and Ezequiel Uriel. 2000. "Estimation of the Stock of Capital in Spain." Review of Income and Wealth 46 (1): 103­16. Mitra, T. 1978. "Efficient Growth with Exhaustible Resources in a Neoclassical Model." Journal of Economic Theory 17 (1): 114­29. Millennium Ecosystem Assessment. 2005. Ecosystems and Human Well-Being: Synthesis. Washington, DC: Island Press. NIER (National Institute for Economic Research). 2000. Environmental Impacts of Swedish Trade-Results of a pilot study. Stockholm. 177 REFERENCES O'Connor, M. 2000. "Toward a Typology of Environmentally-Adjusted National Sustainability Indicators: Key Concepts and Policy Applications." Working Paper 95.2000. Milano: Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei. Paldam, Martin, and Gert Tinggaard Svendsen. Forthcoming. "Social Capital Database for a Cross-Country Study." In Trust, Social Capital and Economic Growth: an International Comparison, ed. M. Paldam and G. T. Svendsen. Cheltenham, U.K.: Edward Elgar Publishing. Pandey, K., K. Bolt, U. Deichman, K. Hamilton, B. Ostro, and D. Wheeler. 2005."The Human Cost of Air Pollution: New Estimates for Developing Countries." Development Research Group and Environment Department, World Bank, Washington, DC. Pearce, D. W. 1993. "Blueprint 3: Measuring Sustainable Development." Earthscan: London. Pearce, D. W., and G. Atkinson. 1993. "Capital Theory and the Measurement of Sustainable Development: An Indicator of Weak Sustainability." Ecological Economics 8 (2): 103­108. Pearce, D. W., and D. Ulph. 1999. "A Social Discount Rate for the United Kingdom." In Environmental Economics: Essays in Ecological Economics and Sustainable Development, ed. D. W. Pearce, 268­285. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing. Pezzey, J. 1989. "Economic Analysis of Sustainable Growth and Sustainable Development." Environment Department Working Paper 15, World Bank, Washington, DC. Pritchett, L. 1996. "Where Has All the Education Gone?" Policy Research Working Paper 1581, World Bank, Washington, DC. ------. 2000. "The Tyranny of Concepts: CUDIE (Cumulated, Depreciated, Investment Effort) is Not Capital." Journal of Economic Growth 5 (December): 361­84. Prywes, M. 1986. "A Nested CES Approach to Capital-Energy Substitution." Energy Economics 8: 22­28. Psacharopoulos, George, and Harry Anthony Patrinos. 2004. "Returns to Investment in Education: A Further Update." Education Economics 12 (2): 111­34. Repetto, R., W. Magrath, M. Wells, C. Beer, and F. Rossini. 1989. Wasting Assets: Natural Resources in the National Accounts. Washington: World Resources Institute. Rosengrant, M. W., M. Agcaoili-Sombilla, and N.D. Perez. 1995. "Global Food Projections to 2020: Implications for Investment." Food, Agriculture, and the Environment Discussion Paper 5, International Food Policy Research Institute, Washington DC. Sachs, J., and A. Warner. 1995. "Natural Resource Abundance and Economic Growth." Development Discussion Paper 517a. Harvard Institute for International Development, Cambridge, MA. Sala-i-Martin, X. 1997. "I Just Ran Two Million Regressions." American Economic Review 87 (2): 178­183. Samuelson, P. 1961. "The Evaluation of `Social Income': Capital Formation and Wealth." In F. A. Lutz and D. C. Hague (eds.), The Theory of Capital. New York: St. Martin's Press. 178 REFERENCES Sarraf, M., and M. Jiwanji. 2001. "Beating the Resource Curse: The Case of Botswana." Environment Department Working Paper 83, Environmental Economics Series, World Bank, Washington, DC. Schultz, T. W. 1961. "Investments in Human Capital." American Economic Review 51 (1): 1­17. Schultz, T. P. 1988. "Education Investments and Returns." In Handbook of Development Economics, Volume 1, ed. H. Chenery and T. N. Srinivasan. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science Publishers, B.V. Smith, Adam. 1776. An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1977. Solow, R. 1986. "On the Intergenerational Allocation of Natural Resources." Scandinavian Journal of Economics 88 (1): 141­49. Sorensen, K. and J. Hass. 1998. Norwegian Economic and Environmental Accounts Project. Statistics Norway: Oslo. Statistics Canada. 2000. "Agricultural Land Use and Supply." Ottawa: Statistics Canada. Stiglitz, J. E. 1974a. "Growth with Exhaustible Natural Resources: Efficient and Optimal Growth Paths." Symposium on the Economics of Exhaustible Resources. Review of Economic Studies 41: 123­37. ------. 1974b. "Growth with Exhaustible Natural Resources: The Competitive Economy." Symposium on the Economics of Exhaustible Resources. Review of Economic Studies 41: 139­52. Tay, John, John Healey, and Colin Price. 2001. "Financial Assessment of Reduced Impact Logging Techniques in Sabah, Malaysia." In Applying Reduced Impact Logging to Advanced Sustainable Forest Management. Bangkok, Thailand: UNFAO. Tol, R. 2005. "The Marginal Damage Cost of Carbon Dioxide Emissions: An Assessment of the Uncertainties." Energy Policy 33: 2064­2074. United Nations. 1993. Integrated Environmental and Economic Accounting. Series F 61. New York: United Nations. ------. 2000. Handbook of National Accounting: Integrated Environmental and Economic Accounting--An Operational Manual. New York: United Nations. ------. 2003. Handbook of National Accounting: Integrated Environmental and Economic Accounting--An Operational Manual. New York: United Nations. UNFAO (United Nations Food and Agriculture Organization). 2000. "Global Forest Resources Assessment 2000: Main Report." Forestry Paper 140, Rome, UNFAO. USGS (U.S. Geological Survey). 2005. Mineral Commodity Summaries. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office. ------. Web page: www.usgs.gov. 179 REFERENCES van der Hout, Peter. 2000. "Testing the Applicability of Reduced Impact Logging in Greenheart Forest in Guyana." International Forestry Review 2 (1). Oxford: Commonwealth Forestry Association. van Tongeren, J., S. Schweinfest, and E. Lutz. 1991. "Integrated Environmental and Economic Accounting: A Case Study of Mexico." Environment Working Paper 50, World Bank, Washington, DC. Verbruggen, H., R. Dellink, R. Gerlagh, and M. Hofkes. 2000. "Calculations of a sustainable national income: Four variants." In H. Verbruggen, ed., Final Report on Calculations of a Sustainable National Income according to Hueting's Methodology. Institute for Environmental Studies. Vrije Universiteit: Amsterdam, The Netherlands. Vincent, J. 1996. "Resource Depletion and Economic Sustainability in Malaysia." Development Discussion Paper 542, Harvard Institute for International Development, Cambridge, MA. Wagner, G. 2004. "Environmental Macroeconomics Bibliography." Available at http://www.gwagner.net/work/environmental macroeconomics.html. Ward, M. 1976. The Measurement of Capital: The Methodology of Capital Stock Estimates in OECD Countries. Paris: OECD. Weitzman, M. L. 1976. "On the Welfare Significance of National Product in a Dynamic Economy." Quarterly Journal of Economics 90 (1): 156­62. Weitzman, M.L. and K.-G. Löfgren. 1997. On the Welfare Significance of Green Accounting as Taught by Parable, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 32: 139-53. Whiteman, Adrian. 1996. "Economic Rent and the Appropriate Level of Forest Products Royalties in 1996." Jakarta, Indonesia: U.K. Tropical Forest Management Programme, Jakarta, Indonesia. World Bank. 1996. Monitoring Environmental Progress: A Report on Work in Progress. Washington, DC: World Bank. World Bank. 1997. Expanding the Measure of Wealth: Indicators of Environmentally Sustainable Development. Environmentally Sustainable Development Studies and Monographs Series No. 17. Washington, DC: World Bank. ------. 2002. World Development Indicators 2002. Washington, DC: World Bank. ------. 2004. World Development Indicators 2004. Washington, DC: World Bank. ------. 2005. World Development Indicators 2005. Washington, DC: World Bank. World Commission on the Environment and Development (WCED). 1987. Our Common Future. Oxford: Oxford University Press. WRI (World Resources Institute). 2000. The Weight of Nations: Material Outflows from Industrial Economies. Washington DC. 180 INDEX Boxes, figures, and tables are indicated by b, f, and t. accounts. See environmental accounts; system Bangladesh, soil degradation and changes in of economic and environmental wealth in, 39b accounts (SEEA) Benin, changes in wealth in, 64t, 65 acid rain, 37­38 Bolivia, genuine saving calculation adjusted net savings. See genuine saving for, 39­40, 40f Africa Botswana See also specific countries and regions changes in wealth in, 64t, 65 changes in wealth in selected countries, diamond mining in, 25, 38, 49 63­65, 64t environmental accounts in, 129t, 130 soil degradation and changes in wealth in, 39b fiscal issue management in, 12 agriculture, 27, 27t, 151­53 genuine savings rates in, 45 See also natural resources and natural capital money asset accounts, 132 air pollution. See pollution natural resource rents in, 7 Algeria natural resources in, xv changes in wealth in, 66 physical flow accounts in, 133, 133t intangible capital in, 28, 28­29b sustainable development in, 49 Angola water accounts in, 125 diamond mining in, 38 Brazil genuine savings rates in, 42, 45 cropland in, 152 Arctic, value of, 23 physical asset accounts in, 131 Argentina resource rents in, 53 cropland in, 152 total wealth estimates for, 26 resource rents in, 55, 55f Bulgaria, changes in wealth in, 67 Asia Burkina Faso, changes in wealth in, 64t, 65 See also specific countries and regions Burundi soil degradation and changes in wealth in, 39b land resources in, 31 asset accounts. See environmental accounts wealth estimate for, 20 Australia environmental accounts in, 129t, 130, 138 Cameroon, resource rents in, 55, 55f EPE (environmental protection expenditure) Canada accounts in, 134 environmental accounts in, 129t, money asset accounts, 132 130, 138 physical asset accounts in, 131 EPE (environmental protection expenditure) soil degradation and changes in wealth in, 39b accounts in, 134 water accounts in, 125 money asset accounts, 132 Azerbaijan physical asset accounts in, 131 genuine savings rates in, 43, 45 Cape Verde, changes in wealth in, 64t, 65 savings gap in, 68 capital. See specific types INDEX capital stocks eaNDP in, 136 hypothetical estimates of, 50­52 environmental protection expenditure (EPE) measuring, 21­22 accounts in, 134 produced, xiv, 5 Cote d'Ivoire carbon dioxide emissions, 62, 63, 74, 134­35, cropland in, 152 136, 138 resource rents in, 55, 55f Caribbean region Croatia, total wealth estimates for, 26 intangible capital in, 28 cropland, 151­53 savings gap in, 68 See also agriculture; natural resources and subsoil assets in, 27, 27t natural capital CC (control of corruption) index, 105 Central Asia Denmark, resource rents in, 55, 55f changes in wealth in, 67 diamond mining, xv, 7, 24, 25, 38­40, 49 genuine savings rates in, 42­43 discount rate, use of, 25 savings gap in, 68 "double dividend," 134, 135 soil degradation and changes in wealth in, 39b "Dutch disease," 49 subsoil assets in, 27, 27t Chad, wealth estimate for, 20 eaNDP. See environmentally adjusted net changes in wealth, xvi­xvii, 61­69 domestic product accounting for, 62­63, 63t East Asia across countries, 65­67, 66­67f, 169­72t See also specific countries conclusions on, 67­68 agriculture in, 27, 27t generation of well-being and, xv­xvii genuine savings rates in, 42 genuine savings, testing, 71­83 savings gap in, 68 Ghanaian example, 62­63, 63t, 68 Eastern Europe investing resource rents, importance of, 49­60 See also specific countries population dynamics, importance of, 61­69 changes in wealth in, 67 recent genuine savings estimates, 35­47 genuine savings rates in, 42­43 savings gaps, 68, 169­72t economic accounting. See environmental in selected African countries, 63­65, 64t accounts; system of economic and soil degradation and, 39b environmental accounts (SEEA) child mortality, lowering, xiii­xiv economic organization, efficiency of, 105 Chile See also wealth and production environmental protection expenditure (EPE) economic sustainability, 122 accounts in, 134 ecosystems, value of, 24 physical asset accounts in, 131 Ecuador physical flow accounts in, 133 changes in wealth in, 66 resource rents in, 54 cropland in, 152 water accounts in, 125 education and schooling China expenditures on, 73­74, 82 cropland in, 152 human capital and, 89­91b, 92, 93, 98 genuine savings rates in, 42, 45 intangible capital and, 94­95t, 94­98, 96f resource rents in, 54 investment in, 13­14 Colombia wealth and production and, 106 cropland in, 152 Egypt environmental protection expenditure (EPE) cropland in, 152 accounts in, 134 resource rents in, 54 common industrial and commodity elasticity of substitution, xviii, 101­02, 103­07, classifications, 124 109­10t, 113­16 Congo, Republic of El Salvador changes in wealth in, 64t, 65 intangible capital residual in, 96­98, 97t diamond mining in, 38 remittances in, 97, 98 intangible capital in, 28­29b emigrated workers and human capital, 92 consuming rents. See resource rents energy control of corruption (CC) index, 105 accounts, 125 Convention to Combat Desertification, 39b rents, 43, 43f Costa Rica resources, 36 cropland in, 152 wealth estimates and, 147­49, 149t 182 INDEX ENRAP (Philippines Environment and Natural flow accounts and, 133 Resource Accounting Project), 132 physical asset accounts in, 131 environmental accounts, xix, 121­40 Eurostat (European Commission's official asset accounts, 130­32, 131f statistical agency) flow account tracking, components of, 122 124, 132, 134 economic efficiency and sustainability, 132 environmental protection and resource FAOSTAT (Food and Agriculture Organization management accounts, 134 of United Nations database), 149­50 environmental protection expenditure fisheries, 23, 24f, 25, 38, 87, 131 accounts (EPE), 126­27, 134­35 forest resources, 37, 149­51 general observations on, 138­40 See also natural resources and natural capital international comparisons, 140 France international experience, 128­30, 129t environmental services industry, 135 macroeconomic indicators, 127­28 physical flow accounts in, 133 monetary indicators, 128 future consumption, present value of, xiv physical indicators, 127­28 monetary asset accounts, 132 Gabon NAMEA framework, 124, 127, 135 changes in wealth in, 64t, 65 overview, 122 intangible capital in, 28­29b physical accounts, 131, 131f produced capital in, 54, 54t physical flow accounts for pollution and produced capital stock in, xvi material use, 124­26, 127, 132­34, geNDP (greened economy NDP), 128, 138 133t, 136, 139 generalized trust indicator, 92 SEEA, applications and policy use of, 130­38 Genuine Income (Sweden), 136 See also system of economic and genuine investment rates, 55, 55f, 56 environmental accounts (SEEA) genuine saving sustainability and, 123­28 calculation of, 154­58 asset accounts, 123­24 carbon dioxide emissions and, 62, 63 environmental protection and resource by country as percent of GNI, 163­68t management accounts, 126­27 described, xv­xvii, 5, 9 monetary accounts for environmental monetary indicators and, 128 degradation, 125 negative genuine savings rates, 36, 38, 46, monetary accounts for nonmarketed 163­68t resources, 126 population and, 62 physical accounts, 125 recent estimates, xv­xvi, 35­47, 163­68t pollution and material flow accounts, calculation of, 36­40, 37f 124­26, 127, 136, 139 consuming resource rents and, 43f, usefulness of, 139 43­44, 46 environmentally adjusted net domestic product country example of calculation of, (eaNDP), 122, 128, 136­37, 138 39­40, 40f environmental protection. See environmental defined, 35 accounts; pollution income and saving, 44, 44t, 46 environmental services industry, 135 interpretation of genuine savings estimates, EPE (environmental protection expenditure) 38­39, 39b accounts, 126­27, 134­35 regional disparities in, 40­43 estimates of wealth. See wealth estimates, savings and growth, 45­46 construction of testing, xvii, 71­83, 80t Estonia, changes in wealth in, 67 conclusions on, 81­82 Ethiopia, wealth estimate for, 20 data and methodology of estimation, Europe 73­75 See also specific countries and regions empirical results, 75­77f, 75­80 environmental accounts in, 129t, 130, 138 specification of empirical test for, 72­73 subsoil assets in, 27, 27t usefulness of, 61 European Union (EU) wealth estimates and, 143­58 environmental and resource accounting Georgia, changes in wealth in, 67 in, 122 Germany environmental protection expenditure (EPE) eaNDP in, 136, 136f accounts in, 134 MFAs and, 136 183 INDEX Ghana institutional development indicators, 105 changes in wealth in, 63t, 64t, 65, 68 See also wealth and production genuine savings rates in, 45 institutional quality, 92­93, 93t, 98 resource rents in, 54 intangible capital residual, xvii­xviii, 87­99 governance, xiv, 92­93, 93t, 98 calculation of, xiv­xv, 23, 28b government country examples, 96­98, 97t effectiveness (GE) index, 105 decomposition of, 96f, 96­98 expenditures, 10, 11, 15 definition of intangible capital, xiv, 4, 4t greened economy NDP (geNDP), elasticities, 93­94, 94t 128, 138 investment in, 12­14, 13t greenhouse-gas emission, 136 levels of intangible capital, 6, 26, 26t, 28­29, See also pollution 28­29b, 159­62t green taxes, 135 marginal returns, 94­95, 95t gross national income, 36, 37f meaning of intangible capital, 87­91, 88f, gross national savings, 35 89t, 89­91b growth-environmental trade-off, 36 regression analysis of, 91­95, 93t growth theory, 81 wealth production and, 106 Guyana, intangible capital in, 28­29b Integrated Environmental and Economic Accounting 2003 (SEEA), 122, 124, Hartwick rule for sustainability 126, 139 consuming rents and, 7 IO tables, 124 counterfactual, xvi, 49­60 conclusions on, 56­57 Japan empirical results of hypothetical, 52­56, eaNDP in, 136, 136f 53f, 54f, 55f, 58­60t environmental protection expenditure (EPE) hypothetical estimates of capital stocks, accounts in, 134 50­52 wealth estimate for, 20 defined, xvi, 16, 38, 49 Jordan elasticity of substitution and, xviii changes in wealth in, 66 monitoring of, 102 genuine savings rates in, 41 high-resource dependent economies, 28­29b, judicial system, investment in, 13, 13t, 14, 31, 32 97, 98 Hueting's sustainable national income (SNI), See also rule of law 128, 138 human capital, 87­99 Kazakhstan emigrated workers and, 92 genuine savings rates in, 43 institutions and, 87­99 savings gap in, 68 intangible capita residual and, xiv, 23, 88f, Kenya 88­89 changes in wealth in, 64t, 65 measurement of, 89­91b genuine savings rates in, 42 monetary measures of, 90­91b Korea, Republic of physical measures of, 89­90b environmental protection expenditure (EPE) remittances and, 92 accounts in, 134 schooling and, 89­91b produced capital in, 54, 54t wealth and production. See wealth and produced capital stock in, xvi production resource rents in, 53 Hungary, changes in wealth in, 67 Kyoto Protocol, 136 India labor productivity, 106 genuine savings rates in, 42 land resources resource rents in, 53 agricultural, xviii, 151­53 Indonesia elasticity of substitution and, xviii, 106 cropland in, 152 in poorer countries, 30­31, 31f eaNDP in, 136 protected land areas, 23, 153­54 physical asset accounts in, 131 sustainability of, 4t, 7 inflated currencies, effect of, 49 urban land in wealth estimates, 146­47 input and outputs, measuring. Lao People's Democratic Republic, See wealth and production cropland in, 152 184 INDEX Latin America Morocco, genuine savings rates in, 41 See also specific countries Mozambique, changes in wealth in, 64t, 65 genuine savings rates in, 42 intangible capital in, 28 NAMEA environmental accounts framework, savings gap in, 68 124, 127, 135 soil degradation and changes in wealth Namibia in, 39b changes in wealth in, 64t, 65, 66 subsoil assets in, 27, 27t diamond mining in, 38 Latvia, changes in wealth in, 67 environmental accounts in, 129t, 130, 132 Libya, total wealth estimates for, 26 money asset accounts, 132 physical asset accounts in, 131, 131f machinery, equipment and structures in wealth physical flow accounts in, 133 estimates, 145­46 water accounts in, 125 Madagascar national capacity, endowments by region, 27, 27t changes in wealth in, 64t, 65 natural capital. See natural resources and resource rents in, 55, 55f natural capital wealth estimate for, 20 natural resource asset accounts. See Malaysia environmental accounts natural resources in, xv natural resources and natural capital physical asset accounts in, 131 See also specific resources resource rents in, 7, 54 development and, 7­8 Mali, changes in wealth in, 64t, 65 endowments by region, 27, 27t manufacturing and services sectors growth, xviii high-income countries and, 4t, 6, 29­30 Martinique, cropland in, 152 low-income countries and, xiiif, xiii­xiv, xv material flow accounts (MFAs), 127, 136 measuring, 23, 24, 24f Mauritius, changes in wealth in, 64t, 65 overexplotation, incentives to reduce, 15 Mexico rents. See resource rents eaNDP in, 136 savings and investment and, 8­9 resource rents in, 54 sustainability and, xviii MFAs. See material flow accounts transition from dependence on, xix­xx Middle East wealth and, xiiif, xiii­xiv, 5­7, 26, 26t, 35 genuine savings rates in, 41 Nepal savings gap in, 68 genuine savings rates in, 42 subsoil assets in, 27, 27t wealth estimate for, 20 middle-income countries, savings rate in, 15 nested CES production function, estimation of, millennium capital assessment, xiii, 3­18, 5t, 103­07, 113­16 143­58 Netherlands, geNDP in, 138 fiscal policy and comprehensive wealth, 10­12 net national savings, 35, 36, 37f, 82 intangible capital residual, investing in, net present value (NPV), 21­22, 22f, 25, 131 12­14, 13t Nicaragua, cropland in, 152 natural resources and development, 4t, 7­8 Niger, land resources in, 31 policies and institutions, 8­9 Nigeria savings and investment, 9­10 changes in wealth in, 64t, 65 Millennium Ecosystem Assessment (2005), 39b genuine investment rate of, 55, 55f, 56 mineral and energy resources in wealth genuine savings rates in, 42, 45 estimates, 49t, 147­49 intangible capital in, 28, 28­29b mineral rents, 43, 43f land resources in, 31 Moldova resource rents in, 53­54 changes in wealth in, 67 savings and investment in, xvi intangible capital in, 28­29b wealth estimate for, 20 land resources in, 31 Nile Delta, soil degradation and changes in physical flow accounts in, 133 wealth in, 39b water accounts in, 125 nonmarketed resources, monetary accounts monetary accounts for, 126 asset accounts, 132 North Africa for environmental degradation, 125 genuine savings rates in, 41 for nonmarketed resources, 126 savings gap in, 68 Mongolia, cropland in, 152 subsoil assets in, 27, 27t 185 INDEX Norway health damages from, 38 environmental accounting and, 132 monetary accounts for environmental environmental taxes in, 133­34 degradation, 125 resource rents in, 55, 55f natural resources and development and, 8 wealth estimate for, 20 physical accounts and, 125 NPV. See net present value pollution and material flow accounts, 124­26, 127, 136 OECD countries population intangible capital in, 88­89, 89t changes in wealth per capita and, 61­69 PIM use in, 145, 146 dynamics, importance of, 61­69 wealth estimate for, 20 growth, 16­17, 82 oil resources portfolio management, xiv, xvi, xix countries with, xvi, 28 poverty reduction, xiii, 3, 98 shock, effect of, 81­82 private discount rate, 25 Organisation for Economic Co-operation and produced capital, xiv, 5, 6, 22 Development (OECD), 122, 139 See also wealth and production See also OECD countries production function, xviii, 101 overexplotation of resources, incentives to productivity, boosting, 15 reduce, 15 protected land areas, 23, 153­54 Pacific, agriculture in, 27, 27t quasi-fiscal risks, 12 Papua New Guinea, eaNDP in, 136 paradox of plenty, 49 regulatory burden (RB) index, 105 pastureland, 153 remittances See also natural resources and natural capital human capital and, 92 PCREDIT, 105 impact on poverty reduction, 98 perpetual inventory model (PIM), xiv, 5, 21­22, as part of intangible capital residual, 13, 14, 22f, 50, 145 96, 96t Peru rents from natural resources, 7 cropland in, 152 República Bolivariana de Venezuela intangible capital residual in, 96­98, 97t changes in wealth in, 66 Philippines genuine savings rates in, 42, 46 changes in wealth in, 66 intangible capital in, 28, 28­29b eaNDP in, 136 produced capital in, xvi, 54, 54t environmental accounts in, 129t, 130 resource rents in, 53 environmental protection expenditure (EPE) Republic of Congo. See Congo, Republic of accounts in, 134 Republic of Korea. See Korea, Republic of physical asset accounts in, 131 resource depletion physical flow accounts in, 133 See also resource rents Philippines Environment and Natural Resource effect of, 7, 8­9 Accounting Project (ENRAP), 132 environmental accounts. See environmental physical asset accounts, 131, 131f accounts physical flow accounts for pollution and material genuine savings calculations and, 36 use, 124­26, 127, 132­34, 133t, savings and investment and, 8­9 136, 139 resource management accounts and PIM. See perpetual inventory model environmental protection, 126­27 policies and institutions, 8­9 resource rents political instability and violence (PIV) index, 105 consuming, 7, 43f, 43­44, 46 pollution effect of, 49 acid rain, 37­38 environmental accounting and, 132 air, 37­38, 125 genuine savings and, 43­44 carbon dioxide emissions. See carbon dioxide Hartwick rule counterfactual, xvi, 49­60 emissions hypothetical estimates of capital eaNDP and, 136 stocks, 50­52 environmental accounts. See environmental investing, 49­60 accounts taxation on, 135 global, 136 volatile prices and, 49 greenhouse-gas emission, 136 Romania, changes in wealth in, 67 186 INDEX rule of law, xviii, 13t, 14 Sub-Saharan Africa See also judicial system, investment in agriculture in, 27, 27t indicators, 92­94, 93t, 94t, 95t, 96t, 98 changes in wealth in, 68 Russian Federation genuine savings rates in, 42 changes in wealth in, 67 intangible capital in, 28 diamond mining in, 38 saving gap in, 68 genuine savings rates in, 43 wealth estimate for, 20 intangible capital in, 28­29b subsistence and natural resources, 8 Rwanda, changes in wealth in, 64t, 65 subsoil assets, 24, 26, 27, 31, 35, 87 See also specific resource SAMs (social accounting matrices), 124 substitutability of assets, 101 saving gaps, xvi, 65, 68 Suriname, cropland in, 152 savings and investment sustainability, xix, 15­17b See also genuine saving consumption and wealth, 29b depletion of natural resources and, 8­9 defining, 35 in developed and developing countries, 10, 14­15 economic, 122 development and, xv growth-environmental trade-off and, 36 efforts in savings, 56­57 Hartwick rule. See Hartwick rule for sustainability genuine investment rates, 55, 55f, 56 negative genuine savings rates and, 36, 38 negative savings, 15 Swaziland, changes in wealth in, 64t, 65 sustainability and, 15­17, 56­57 Sweden transition to, xix­xx, 10 eaNDP in, 136 savings gaps, xvi­xvii, 66, 168­72t measurement of human capital and, 91b Scandinavia Swedish National Institute of Economic See also specific countries Research (NIER), 138 wealth estimate for, 20 Switzerland, wealth estimate of, 20 schooling. See education and schooling Syrian Arab Republic SEEA. See system of economic and changes in wealth in, 66 environmental accounts intangible capital in, 28­29b Senegal, changes in wealth in, 64t, 65 system of economic and environmental accounts Serengeti Plain, value of, 23 (SEEA), xix, 121, 130­38 Seychelles, changes in wealth in, 64t, 65 economywide indicators of sustainable SNA. See system of national accounts development, 135­37 SNI (Hueting's sustainable national income), environmentally adjusted NDP and related 128, 138 indicators, 122, 128, 136­37 social accounting matrices (SAMs), 124 physical indicators of macrolevel social discount rate, 25 performance, 136 Social Rate of Return on Investment (SRRI), 25 environmental and resource taxes, 134­35 social welfare, 15­17b environmental protection and resource SOEs. See state-owned enterprises management accounts, 134 soil erosion and genuine savings rate, 38, 39b environmental protection expenditure solid waste management, 135 accounts, 134­35 South Africa environmental services industry, 135 changes in wealth in, 64t, 65 general observations on, 139 diamond mining in, 39 modeling approaches to macroeconomic environmental accounting and, 132 indicators, 138 genuine savings rates in, 42 monetary indicators, 128 physical flow accounts in, 133 NAMEA and, 127, 135 South Asia physical asset accounts, 131, 131f agriculture in, 27, 27t physical flow accounts for pollution and genuine savings rates in, 42 material use, 124­26, 127, 132­34, savings gap in, 68 133t, 136, 139 Spain physical indicators, 127 physical flow accounts in, 133 revised manual of, 122, 124, 126, 139 water accounts in, 125 usefulness, 121 SRRI (Estimates of the Social Rate of Return use of asset accounts for monitoring and on Investment), 25 policy making, 130­32 state-owned enterprises (SOEs), 10, 12 system of national accounts (SNA), 122, 123, 126 187 INDEX tangible wealth, 62, 73 wages, comparison of, 98 Tanzania, genuine savings rates in, 42 wastewater management, 135 taxation water resources asset accounts and, 135 accounts, 125, 133, 133t carbon tax, 134­35 subsoil, 87 "double dividend" and, 134, 135 valuation of, 126 environmental and resource taxes, WDPA (World Database of Protected 133­34, 135 Areas), 154 environmental protection and resource wealth, changes in. See changes in wealth management accounts, 126 wealth and production, xviii, 101­16 EPE and, 135 conclusions on, 107­08 flow accounts and, 133­34 estimation of nested CES production green taxes, 135 function, 103­07, 113­16 on rents, 135 regression results, 106­07, 109­11t testing genuine saving. See genuine saving simulation, 107, 110t, 112t Thailand, resource rents in, 53 wealth estimates, construction of, xiv­xv, xviii, timber resources, 37, 149­51 3, 19­32, 35, 143­58 See also natural resources and natural capital adjusted net saving, calculating, 154­57t TMR (total material requirements), 127, 136 architecture of, 21­25, 22f, 24f Tobago country-level, 159­62t changes in wealth in, 66 cropland, 151­53 produced capital in, xvi, 54, 54t data, information from, 25­27, 26­27t, resource rents in, 53 159­62t TOPEN (trade openness), 105 intangible capital and, 28­29 total material requirements (TMR), 127, 136 key conclusions on, 28­29b, 31­32, 159­62t total wealth land resources in poorer countries, estimating, xiv, 23, 144­45 30­31, 31f per capita, 4t, 6 machinery, equipment and structures, 145­46 by region, 26t, 26­27 mineral and energy resources, 147­49, 149t trade openness (TOPEN), 105, 106­07, 108, natural capital in richer countries, 29­30 111t, 113 nontimber forest resources, 151 Trinidad overview of, 25­32 changes in wealth in, 66 pastureland, 153 produced capital in, xvi, 54, 54t protected areas, 153­54 resource rents in, 53 richest and poorest areas, 20­21, 20­21t Tunisia, genuine savings rates in, 41 timber resources, 149­51 Turkey, intangible capital residual in, 97t, total wealth, 144­45 97­98, 172t by region, 26t, 26­27 Turkmenistan, genuine savings rates in, 43 urban land, 146­47 well-being and changes in wealth, xvii­xviii United Kingdom, resource rents in, 55, 55f wild-food products, 126 United Nations, 122, 139 World Bank and environmental and resource United States accounting, 122 eaNDP in, 136, 136f World Database of Protected Areas environmental protection expenditure (EPE) (WDPA), 154 accounts in, 134 World Development Indicators (WDI; World wealth estimate for, 20 Bank 2005), 71, 104 Uzbekistan World Resources Institute, 136 genuine savings rates in, 43, 45 savings gap in, 68 Yemen, cropland in, 152 Venezuela. See República Bolivariana de Zambia, resource rents in, 53 Venezuela Zimbabwe Vietnam, cropland in, 152 changes in wealth in, 64t, 65 voice and accountability (VA) index, 105 resource rents in, 55, 55f 188 W here is the wealth of nations?--a question that marked the beginning of economic science--is today at the center of development policy. A nation's wealth is the basis for production, growth, and welfare. The composition of wealth is both a determinant and a result of the development process. This book describes estimates of wealth and its components for nearly 120 countries. It regards economic policy as a process of portfolio management in which the assets are produced capital, natural resources, and human resources. In this framework, sustainability is an integral part of economic policy making. The rigorous analysis, presented in accessible format, identifies the conditions for sustainable growth and development, providing a useful yardstick for policymakers. The book has four sections. The first part introduces the wealth estimates and highlights the level and composition of wealth across countries. The second part analyzes changes in wealth and their implications for economic policy. The third part deepens the analysis by considering the importance of human and institutional capital, and by linking wealth to production. The fourth part reviews existing applications of resource and environmental accounting in developed and developing countries. This book bridges the gap among finance, environmental, and natural resource ministries. It will be of interest to economists, development practitioners, and decision makers in governments, international organizations, and academia. TMxHSKIMBy363546zv,:':$:&:/ THE WORLD BANK ISBN 0-8213-6354-9