Europe and Central Asia Economic Update Office of the Chief Economist May 2018 WORLD BANK ECA ECONOMIC UPDATE MAY 2018 Cryptocurrencies and Blockchain Office of the Chief Economist © 2018 International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank 1818 H Street NW, Washington, DC 20433 Telephone: 202-473-1000; Internet: www.worldbank.org Some rights reserved 1 2 3 4 21 20 19 18 This work is a product of the staff of The World Bank with external contributions. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this work do not necessarily reflect the views of The World Bank, its Board of Executive Directors, or the governments they represent. The World Bank does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this work. The boundaries, colors, denominations, and other information shown on any map in this work do not imply any judgment on the part of The World Bank concerning the legal status of any territory or the endorsement or acceptance of such boundaries. Nothing herein shall constitute or be considered to be a limitation upon or waiver of the privileges and immunities of The World Bank, all of which are specifically reserved. Rights and Permissions This work is available under the Creative Commons Attribution 3.0 IGO license (CC BY 3.0 IGO) http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/3.0/igo. Under the Creative Commons Attribution license, you are free to copy, distribute, transmit, and adapt this work, including for commercial purposes, under the following conditions: Attribution —Please cite the work as follows: World Bank. 2018. “Cryptocurrencies and Blockchain.” Europe and Central Asia Economic Update (May), Washington, DC: World Bank. Doi: 10.1596/978-1- 4648-1299-6. License: Creative Commons Attribution CC BY 3.0 IGO Translations—If you create a translation of this work, please add the following disclaimer along with the attribution: This translation was not created by The World Bank and should not be considered an official World Bank translation. The World Bank shall not be liable for any content or error in this translation. Adaptations —If you create an adaptation of this work, please add the following disclaimer along with the attribution: This is an adaptation of an original work by The World Bank. Views and opinions expressed in the adaptation are the sole responsibility of the author or authors of the adaptation and are not endorsed by The World Bank. Third-party content —The World Bank does not necessarily own each component of the content contained within the work. The World Bank therefore does not warrant that the use of any third-party- owned individual component or part contained in the work will not infringe on the rights of those third parties. The risk of claims resulting from such infringement rests solely with you. If you wish to re-use a component of the work, it is your responsibility to determine whether permission is needed for that re-use and to obtain permission from the copyright owner. Examples of components can include, but are not limited to, tables, figures, or images. All queries on rights and licenses should be addressed to World Bank Publications, The World Bank Group, 1818 H Street NW, Washington, DC 20433, USA; e-mail: pubrights@worldbank.org. ISBN (electronic): 978-1-4648-1299-6 DOI: 10.1596/978-1-4648-1299-6 Cover design: World Bank Contents Acknowledgments . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . v Abbreviations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . vii Regional Classification Used in this Report . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . ix Executive Summary. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . xi PART I: Economic Outlook. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1 1 Economic Developments and Prospects. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3 Overview . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3 Growth is strong throughout the region. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4 Growth appears to have peaked . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7 The region has shifted toward more exports. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11 . . . and adapted to technological change. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12 A combination of factors caused the decline in labor productivity after the crisis . . . . . . . . . . . . 12 Notes. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19 References. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19 2 Cryptocurrencies and Blockchain: Hype or Transformational Technologies? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21 Overview. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21 Introduction. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22 Creating digital money without central banks . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24 Creating digital markets without intermediaries. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 32 Blockchain applications in Europe and Central Asia . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 37 Policy challenges. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 45 Notes. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 48 References. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 49 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 51 Part II: Selected Country Pages Albania. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 53 Armenia. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 55 Azerbaijan. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 57 Belarus. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 59 Bosnia and Herzegovina. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 61 Bulgaria. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 63 Croatia. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 65 Georgia. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 67 Kazakhstan. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 69 Kosovo. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 71 Kyrgyz Republic. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 73 Macedonia. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 75 Moldova. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 77 Montenegro. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 79 Poland. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 81 iii iv  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 Romania. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 83 Russian Federation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 85 Serbia. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 87 Tajikistan . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 89 Turkey . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 91 Turkmenistan. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 93 Ukraine. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 95 Uzbekistan. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 97 Boxes 1.1 Similarities between recoveries in Central Europe after 2009 and East Asia in the late 1990s. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13 1.2 A new normal in Armenia . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17 2.1 Equilibrium mechanisms in the bitcoin market . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28 2.2 Providing access to secure insurance. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 34 2.3 Cryptocurrency mining and the demand for electricity in Georgia. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 43 2.4 Will central banks issue digital currencies? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 47 Figures 1.1 Industrial production growth has soared since 2016, globally and in Europe and Central Asia. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5 1.2 Commodity prices have followed the economic upswing. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6 1.3 Acceleration of growth has resulted in lower unemployment. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7 1.4 Normalization of inflation in Europe and Central Asia continues . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8 1.5 Housing prices in the European Union have risen since 2013. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9 1.6 The Purchasing Managers’ Index reached an all-time high in Europe and Central Asia in 2018. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10 1.7 Government deficits in the region have fallen sharply since 2009 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11 1.8 Since the crisis, production in Europe and Central Asia has shifted toward exports. . . . . 12 B1.1.1 Recovery in Central Europe was similar to recovery after Asian financial crisis. . . . . . . . . 13 B1.1.2 Investment rates adjusted immediately to reversal in capital flows. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13 1.9 Even after full recovery, the effects of the global financial crisis remain. . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14 1.10 After the crisis, labor productivity increased at a slower rate . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15 1.11 The contribution of total factor productivity (TFP) to labor productivity growth declined after the crisis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15 1.12 Labor productivity growth in Germany is on a long-term downward trend. . . . . . . . . . . . 16 2.1 As the price of bitcoin soared in 2017, so did competition among miners. . . . . . . . . . . . 26 2.2 Three large mining pools provide half of all network blocks. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27 2.3 Most mining revenue comes from the seignorage (block reward) of the network . . . . . . 29 2.4 Daily price movements of bitcoin continue to be large. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 31 B2.2.1 Farmers in Europe and Central Asia are underinsured . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 34 2.5 Early use of bitcoin was clustered around gambling and the dark web . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 38 2.6 Adoption of bitcoin is negatively correlated with the quality of institutions. . . . . . . . . . . 39 2.7 Europe and Central Asia is the site of many initial coin offerings (ICOs). . . . . . . . . . . . . . 41 B2.3.1 Georgia had the fastest-growing electricity consumption in Europe and Central Asia in 2010–14. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 43 B2.3.2 Unexplained electricity demand in Georgia has risen rapidly since 2009. . . . . . . . . . . . . 44 Tables E.1 Regional classification used in this report. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . ix 1.1 Growth has reached an all-time high in most countries in Europe and Central Asia. . . . . 4 Acknowledgments This Europe and Central Asia (ECA) Economic Update is a joint product of ECA’s Office of the Chief Economist, the Macro and Fiscal Management Global Practice, and the Poverty Global Practice. Part I was prepared by a team in the Chief Economist’s Office led by Hans Timmer and including Roy Sudharshan Canagarajah, Breda Griffith, Bingjie Hu, Georgi Panterov, Charalampos Papamanthou, William Shaw, and Ekaterina Ushakova. Chapter I benefitted from forecasts (presented in Part II) prepared by economists in the Macro and Fiscal Management Global Practice. David Michael Gould, Erik Feyen, Vincent Launay, Christopher David Miller, Stela Mocan, Anthony Molle, and Young Chul Kim provided valuable comments on Part I. Part II was prepared by teams from the Macro and Fiscal Management Global Practice (led by Andrew Burns, Maria De los Angeles Cuqui Gonzalez Miranda, Lalita M. Moorty, and Gallina Andronova Vincelette) and the Poverty Global Practice (led by Luis-Felipe Lopez-Calva), with inputs from the Developments Prospects Group (led by Ayhan Kose). These teams included the following staff: Erdem Atas, Joao Pedro Wagner De Azevedo, Sarah Nankya Babirye, Elena Bondarenko, Cesar Cancho, Marie-Anne Chambonnier, Alexandru Cojocaru, Marcel Chistruga, Pablo Facundo Cuevas, Maria Eugenia Davalos, Agim Demukaj, Mariam Dolidze, Donato De Rosa, Bakyt Dubashov, Olga Emelyanova, Josip Funda, Mismake D. Galatis, Anastasia Golovach, Claudia Gutierrez, Gohar Gyulumyan, Kiryl Haiduk, Sandra Hlivnjak, Stella Ilieva, Maria Gabriela Inchauste Comboni, Saida Ismailakhunova, Charl Jooste, Jonathan George Karver, Yeon Soo Kim, Aurelien Kruse, Sanja Madzarevic-Sujster, Mikhail Matytsin, Kristina Cathrine Mercado, Moritz Meyer, Jose Montes, Evgenij Najdov, Metin Nebiler, Minh Cong Nguyen, Trang Van Nguyen, Catalin Pauna, Habib Nasser Rab, Alisher Rajabov, Nadir Ramazanov, Julio Revilla, Monica Robayo, Paul Andres Corral Rodas, Armineh Manookian Salmasi, Apurva Sanghi, Ilyas Sarsenov, William Hutchins Seitz, Asli Senkal, Lazar Sestovic, Hilda Shijaku, Bojan Shimbov, Emilia Skrok, Karlis Smits, Sangjin Song, David Andrew Stephan, Thi Thanh Thanh Bui, Eskender Trushin, Vincent Belinga De Paul Tsoungui, Christoph Ungerer, Ekaterina Vostroknutova, Pinar Yasar and Bakhrom Ziyaev. Ekaterina Ushakova oversaw the layout and production of the report. Barbara Karni edited and Michael Alwan typeset it. Paul Anthony Clare, Tamar Kobakhidze, Artem Kolesnikov, and Inga Paichadze provided communications and outreach support, including the dedicated webpage (http://www.worldbank.org/en/ region/eca/publication/europe-and-central-asia-economic-update). v Abbreviations ACP Attraction Centers Program BoA Bank of Albania BiH Bosnia and Herzegovina CAD Current account deficit CBA Central Bank of Armenia CBR Central Bank of Russia CBU Central Bank of Uzbekistan CNB Croatian National Bank CPI Consumer price index CROSTAT Croatian Bureau of Statistics DLT Distributed Ledger Technology ECA Europe and Central Asia ECAPOV ECAPOV (ECA Poverty) database of standardized household surveys EEU Euroasian Economic Union EFSD Eurasian Fund for Stabilization and Development EU-SILC European Union Statistics on Income and Living Conditions FDI Foreign direct investment FX Foreign exchange FYR Fiscal year GDP Gross domestic product GoA Government of Azerbaijan HPP Hydro-power plant IBA International Bank of Azerbaijan ICO Initial coin offerings ICT Information and communication technology IFI International financial institution IMF International Monetary Fund IPO Initial public offering IT Information technology LCU Local currency unit MSII Minimum Social Inclusion Income NBG National Bank of Georgia NBKR National Bank of the Kyrgyz Republic NBM National Bank of Moldova NBP National Bank of Poland vii viii  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 NBR National Bank of Romania NBU National Bank of Ukraine NPL Non-performing loans OPEC Organization of the Petroleum Exporting Countries PPA Power Purchasing Agreements PPP Purchasing power parity SAR Special administrative region SDR Special Drawing Rights SME Small and medium enterprise SOE State-owned enterprises SWIFT Society for Worldwide Interbank Financial Telecommunications TFP Total factor productivity TSA Targeted Social Assistance UFRD Uzbekistan Fund for Reconstruction and Development WB World Bank WDI World Development Institute Country Codes Albania ALB Hungary HUN Philippines PHL Argentina ARG India IND Poland POL Armenia ARM Indonesia IDN Portugal PRT Australia AUS Iran, Islamic Rep. IRN Romania ROM Austria AUT Ireland IRL Russian Federation RUS Azerbaijan AZE Italy ITA Saudi Arabia SAU Belarus BLR Japan JPN Serbia SRB Belgium BEL Kenya KEN Singapore SGP Bosnia and Herzegovina BIH Kazakhstan KAZ Slovak Republic SVK Brazil BRA Kosovo XKX Slovenia SVN Bulgaria BRG Kyrgyz Republic KGZ South Africa ZAF Canada CAN Latvia LVA Spain ESP Chile CHL Lithuania LTU Sweden SWE China CHN Luxembourg LUX Switzerland CHE Colombia COL FYR Macedonia MKD Tanzania TZA Croatia HRV Malaysia MYS Tajikistan TJK Czech Republic CZE Malta MLT Cyprus CYP Mexico MEX Thailand THA Denmark DNK Moldova MDA Turkey TUR Dominican Republic DOM Morocco MAR Turkmenistan TKM Estonia EST Montenegro MNE Ukraine UKR Finland FIN New Zealand NZL United Arab Emirates ARE France FRA Nigeria NGA United Kingdom GBR Georgia GEO The Netherlands NLD United States USA Germany DEU Norway NOR Uzbekistan UZB Greece GRC Pakistan PAK Venezuela, RB VEN Hong Kong SAR, China HKG Peru PER Vietnam VNM Regional Classification Used in this Report This report covers 47 countries referred to as Europe and Central Asia (ECA) coun- tries. These are divided into 10 groups: Western Europe, Southern Europe, Central Europe, Northern Europe, Western Balkans, South Caucasus, Central Asia, Russia, Turkey, and Other Eastern Europe. TABLE E.1 Regional classification used in this report European Union Western Southern Central Northern Western Europe Europe Europe Europe Balkans European Austria Greece Bulgaria Denmark Albania Union Belgium Italy Croatia Finland Bosnia and Herzegovina and France Portugal Czech Republic Sweden Kosovo Western Germany Spain Hungary Estonia FYR Macedonia Balkans Ireland Cyprus Poland Latvia Montenegro Europe Luxemburg Malta Romania Lithuania Serbia and The Netherlands Slovak Republic Central United Kingdom Slovenia Asia South Central Russian Other Eastern Caucasus Asia Federation Turkey Europe Eastern Europe Armenia Kazakhstan Belarus and Azerbaijan Kyrgyz Republic Moldova Central Georgia Tajikistan Ukraine Asia Turkmenistan Uzbekistan ix Executive Summary With growth in Europe and Central Asia having peaked at 2.7 percent in 2017, policy mak- ers face new challenges. How can they navigate the expected cyclical downturn? How can they boost underlying potential growth that has slowed, especially since the global finan- cial crisis? How should they adjust regulations and reform policies to benefit from the digi- tal revolution while mitigating the transition costs? This report summarizes the economic outlook for the region and examines the adoption of new blockchain technologies. In doing so, it touches on all three challenges. The 2017 rates of growth of GDP (2.7 percent) and private consumption (2.5 percent) were faster than at any time since the global financial crisis of a decade ago. Growth was especially strong in Central Europe and in Turkey, but it was robust in other parts of the region as well. Unemployment rates are now close to their 2007 levels in most countries, and average inflation exceeds 2 percent, indicating that little spare capacity is left. Deceleration of growth is expected to be modest, but a sharper correction remains pos- sible. Cyclical forces can easily reinforce one another, and additional shocks—rising pro- tectionism, geopolitical tensions, larger than expected disruptions caused by Brexit—could materialize. There is little room for further monetary stimulus if the expected slowdown is sharper than expected. The region has rebuilt some fiscal buffers, however. The average fiscal deficit in 2017 is estimated at just above 1 percent of GDP, down from 6 percent dur- ing the 2009 crisis and close to levels at the end of the boom that preceded that crisis. Fiscal stimulus is thus an option in several countries in case of a sharper than expected slow- down. Under the baseline scenario of only a modest deceleration, however, a further buildup of fiscal buffers seems the best strategy. Many countries in the region have proven to be fertile ground for the development of cryptocurrencies and blockchain technologies. The emergence of these technologies is part of a broader wave of technologies that facilitate peer-to-peer (P2P) commerce, the indi- vidualization of products, and the flexibilization of production methods. For a variety of reasons, these trends gained traction after the global financial crisis a decade ago. Blockchain technologies aim to organize P2P transactions and P2P informa- tion flows without intermediaries and central banks have opportunities to use blockchain technologies to improve their services. It is unclear how these technologies will develop in the long run; their ultimate impact may be very different from the current applications. In response, policy makers should strike a balance between curbing the hype surrounding these new technologies and un- leashing potentially transformational new opportunities. While encouraging and facilitat- ing these innovations, they should prepare to craft new regulations to create a level playing field for new and old industries, by adjusting financial oversight, consumer protection, and tax administration. They should also address the massive volume of electricity used to mine cryptocurrencies. xi PART I Economic Outlook 1 Economic Developments and Prospects Overview Growth is strong in Europe and Central Asia (ECA), stronger than at any time since the global financial crisis of a decade ago. GDP rose 2.7 percent, and annual private consumption rose 2.5 percent. Growth was especially strong in Central Europe and Turkey, but it was robust in other parts of the region as well. Growth has likely peaked, however. Increased capacity utilization, unemploy- ment rates close to their 2007 levels, and average inflation now exceeding 2 per- cent are all signals that growth is likely to decelerate. The peaking of growth raises several questions • How well is the region prepared for a sharper than expected cyclical down- turn? As fiscal deficits have fallen to an average 1.5 percent of GDP, fiscal policy could be used. But in most countries, monetary tightening would prob- ably be more appropriate. • Why is the underlying structural growth so low? Growth in 2017 was 0.4 per- centage points below the average growth rate between 2000 and 2007. The decelerating growth trend is associated with the shift toward services, the de- cline in capital deepening, and a slower pace of measured total factor produc- tivity (TFP). • Has the economic upswing been used to adjust to the new normal of digital technologies, more flexible employment contracts, and increased tradability of goods and services? An unfinished agenda remains in terms of rethinking social protection and facilitating private sector development in new, interna- tionally competitive sectors. It is important that adjustments toward this new reality continue, even if the expected slowdown materializes or deepens. 3 4  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 Growth is strong throughout the region GDP growth of 2.7 percent in 2017 translated into a robust 2.5 percent increase in per capita GDP, as the population is growing at a mere 0.2 percent a year. This rate of growth was the fastest since 2007 and 0.9 percentage points faster than in 2016 (table 1.1). Growth exceeded 4 percent in 20 of the 47 countries in the region. Ireland and Malta enjoyed growth of more than 5 percent. Romania and Slovenia in Central Europe; Armenia and Georgia in the South Caucasus; and Turkey, Ta- jikistan, and Uzbekistan in Central Asia also reported strong growth. Azerbaijan, Belarus, and the Russian Federation emerged from recession (although their growth was only moderate). Not a single country in the region experienced a contraction in 2017. Private sector demand drove this vigorous performance. Government con- sumption increased by less than 1 percent on average in the region. Private in- vestment rose by more than 4 percent, and growth in investment outpaced GDP growth for the fourth year in a row. The volume of exports and imports expanded by more than 5 percent in 2017, roughly twice as fast as GDP growth.1 The acceleration of growth has been a global phenomenon. Since the summer of 2016, growth of global industrial production has more than doubled, ap- proaching 5 percent in recent months, very close to the 4.8 percent global growth during the 2003–07 boom. TABLE 1.1  Growth has reached an all-time high in most countries in Europe and Central Asia Change in forecast since October 2017 Annual GDP growth (percent) (percentage points) 2017 2018 2019 2017 2018 Region/subregion 2015 2016 (estimate) (forecast) (forecast) 2016 (estimate) (forecast) Europe and Central Asia 1.9 1.8 2.7 2.3 2.1 0.0 0.5 0.4 European Union and Western Balkans 2.2 1.9 2.5 2.2 1.9 0.0 0.4 0.4 European Union 2.2 1.9 2.5 2.2 1.9 0.0 0.4 0.4 Western Europe 2.2 1.8 2.3 2.1 1.7 0.0 0.4 0.4 Northern Europe 2.6 2.5 2.5 2.3 2.1 0.2 0.2 0.2 Central Europe 3.9 3.1 4.6 4.1 3.6 0.2 0.9 0.7 Southern Europe 1.6 1.7 2.2 1.9 1.6 0.0 0.3 0.3 Western Balkans 2.2 3.0 2.4 3.1 3.4 0.1 −0.3 −0.1 Eastern Europe and Central Asia 0.3 1.1 3.7 3.0 3.0 0.0 1.1 0.4 South Caucasus 1.7 −1.6 2.0 2.6 4.0 0.5 1.7 0.8 Central Asia 2.8 2.8 4.4 3.5 3.6 0.0 0.1 0.0 Russian Federation −2.5 −0.2 1.5 1.7 1.8 0.0 −0.2 0.0 Turkey 6.1 3.2 7.4 4.7 4.4 0.0 3.5 1.2 Other Eastern Europe −7.6 0.8 2.5 3.3 3.6 0.1 0.5 0.2 Source: World Bank. Chapter 1: Economic Developments and Prospects ●  5 FIGURE 1.1 Industrial 6 production growth has soared since 2016, 5 Percentage growth 3 months average globally and in Europe 4 over same period a year ago and Central Asia 3 2 1 0 09 09 09 09 03 03 03 03 03 09 03 1 M M M M M M M M M M M 15 16 15 16 18 13 14 14 13 17 17 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 2 3 World Europe and Central Asia Source: World Bank. The ECA region closely followed that acceleration (figure 1.1). The region as a whole outperformed the United States in 2017, and growth of industrial produc- tion in Central Europe and Turkey was on par with growth in China and India. This performance lies in sharp contrast to performance in the aftermath of the European banking and debt crisis, when the region’s performance significantly lagged that of the world as a whole. During this global acceleration, commodity prices rebounded. Copper prices, which are closely linked to the industrial cycle, increased 43 percent between October 2016 and March 2018, more than any other commodity. Oil prices in- creased 30 percent over the same period (figure 1.2, panel a), providing some relief for energy exporters and recipients of remittances in the eastern part of the region. Consistent with their strong relationship with energy prices, grain prices increased 18 percent between October 2016 and March 2018. Other agricultural prices declined, leaving the index of agricultural prices flat. The total nonoil commodity price index increased 10 percent over the last year and a half, largely reflecting the weakening of the U.S. dollar over that period, as all commodity prices are measured in dollars. The dollar depreciated 11 percent against the euro and 6 percent against the Chinese renminbi over this period. Average commodity prices expressed in these two currencies were thus relatively stable. The dollar also depreciated against other currencies in the region. Between October 2016 and March 2018, it fell 16 percent against the Czech koruna, 14 percent against the Albanian lek and the Polish zloty, 9 percent against the Rus- sian ruble and the Hungarian forint, 7 percent against the Romanian leu, and 3 percent against the Kazakh tenge. Only a few regional currencies depreciated during this period against the dollar. The Turkish lira depreciated 27 percent, and the Azeri manat depreciated 5 percent. Metal and oil prices increased in all cur- rencies, and many other commodity prices declined in euros or other currencies in the region. Despite their cyclical upturn, oil prices are nowhere near their historical highs. Indeed, adjusted for inflation, global oil prices are 57 percent below their peak of 6  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 FIGURE 1.2 Commodity prices have followed a. Commodity prices have risen since late 2016. . . the economic upswing 300 Commodity price (dollars per unit) 250 200 150 100 50 0 01 07 01 07 01 07 01 07 01 07 01 07 01 M M M M M M M M M M M M M 00 03 06 09 12 15 18 01 04 07 10 13 16 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 Oil Copper b. . . . but they are nowhere near their historical peaks 300 Commodity price (dollars per unit) 250 200 150 100 50 0 01 04 07 10 01 04 07 10 01 04 07 10 M M M M M M M M M M M M 60 75 81 96 02 17 70 91 12 65 86 07 20 19 20 19 19 19 20 19 19 20 19 19 Oil Copper Source: World Bank. Note: Panel a: Index of nominal prices in U.S. dollars; January 2015 = 100. Panel b: Index of real prices (deflated with U.S. Consumer Price Index), January 2015 = 100. July 2008 and 43 percent below the average level between early 2011 and late 2014 (figure 1.2, panel b).2 There are no signs that oil markets will return to those re- cord prices. Consequently, adjustments in countries that directly or indirectly depend on oil exports should continue. Several of these countries have become more competitive in international markets and begun diversifying their economies, partly as a result of the depre- ciation of real exchange rates since the fall in oil prices late 2014. Unexploited opportunities remain to shift farther away from nontradable production. Domes- tic reforms that correct price distortions, eliminate privileges for state-sponsored companies, and unleash more competition and innovation remain essential. The recent wave of reforms in Uzbekistan sets a good example.3 They will likely lead to further diversification and may trigger reforms in surrounding countries. Chapter 1: Economic Developments and Prospects ●  7 Growth appears to have peaked Signals are mounting that global growth has peaked. With less spare capacity, lower unemployment, rising inflation, and tightening monetary policy, the po- tential for continued rapid growth has diminished, especially in the ECA region. Unemployment is now close to where it was at the height of the boom a de- cade ago (figure 1.3, panel a). The labor market has become tight, especially in Northern Europe. The rapid decline in unemployment is remarkable, given the history of hysteresis in the region’s labor markets. After every major crisis, the typical pattern in Europe was for unemployment rates to settle at higher levels. It is especially encouraging that youth unemployment in the European Union has fallen sharply. It is now back to 2005 levels (figure 1.3, panel b), having fallen FIGURE 1.3 Acceleration of growth has resulted in a. Unemployment in Europe and Central Asia has almost returned to precrisis levels lower unemployment 12 10 Unemployment rate (percent) 8 6 4 2 0 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10 12 14 16 20 20 20 20 19 19 20 19 19 20 20 19 20 20 b. Youth unemployment in the European Union closely tracks unemployment of older workers 10 25 Unemployment rate (percent) Unemployment rate (percent) 8 20 6 15 4 10 00 02 04 06 08 10 12 14 16 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 Workers 25 and older (left-hand axis) Workers under 25 (right-hand axis) Sources: World Economic Outlook, April 2018 (panel a); Eurostat (panel b). 8  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 from 24.0 in 2013 percent to 16.8 percent in 2017 (the overall unemployment rate fell from 9.5 percent to 6.7 percent over this period).4 Average inflation in the western part of the region has been almost 2 percent since early 2017 (figure 1.4). That is a critical change from the deflationary threats in the aftermath of the European banking crises. Between 2012 and 2016, the consumer price index declined in at last one year in Armenia, Bosnia and Herze- govina, Bulgaria, Croatia, Cyprus, Estonia, Finland, Georgia, Greece, Ireland, It- aly, Lithuania, Macedonia, Montenegro, Poland, Romania, the Slovak Republic, Spain, Sweden, and Switzerland. In several of these countries, the GDP deflator still rose, and the drop in consumer prices reflected terms-of-trade gains. Never- theless, the deflationary threat was a serious concern and the manifestation of underutilized resources. None of these countries experienced deflation in 2017. The average inflation rate of 2 percent is close to the target of monetary authorities. As a result, the Euro- pean Central Bank will likely discontinue quantitative easing in 2018; central banks outside the euro area are also expected to tighten their policies. Tightening has already started in Turkey, where inflation has reached double-digit levels. Asset prices have risen even faster than consumer prices (figure 1.5). The in- crease in real estate prices is not nearly as extreme as it was during the boom a decade ago, but in Northern Europe double-digit annual increases were not un- common in 2017. This boom is an additional reason for monetary policy makers to raise interest rates. In the eastern part of the region, monetary policies are likely to tighten in com- ing years, even as inflation has recently fallen (figure 1.4). High inflation in 2015 and 2016 was part of a one-time price adjustment after the fall in oil prices and the subsequent unavoidable depreciations of exchange rates. That adjustment FIGURE 1.4 Normalization of inflation in Europe and 9 Percentage change over three-month Central Asia continues 8 7 average in previous year 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 1 01 08 03 10 05 12 07 02 09 04 M M M M M M M M M M 15 13 14 16 14 18 13 15 17 17 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 Eastern ECA Western ECA Source: World Bank. Note: Western ECA is the unweighted average of 29 countries: Albania, Austria, Belgium, Bulgaria, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Croatia, the Czech Republic, Denmark, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Ireland, Italy, Luxemburg, Latvia, Macedonia, the Netherlands, Portugal, Romania, Serbia, the Slovak Republic, Slovenia, Spain, Sweden, the United Kingdom, and Turkey. Eastern ECA is the unweighted average of nine countries: Armenia, Azerbaijan, Belarus, Georgia, Kazakhstan, the Kyrgyz Republic, Moldova, the Russian Federation, and Tajikistan. Chapter 1: Economic Developments and Prospects ●  9 FIGURE 1.5 Housing prices in the European Union have 12 risen since 2013 8 Annual percentage growth 4 0 4 3 2 1 2 3 4 2 9Q 8Q Q Q 1 Q Q Q Q Q 1 11Q 06 07 12 13 14 16 17 0 0 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 4 8 Nominal housing prices Housing prices deflated with CPI Sources: Data from Eurostat and the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. has been completed. Further inflation should now be controlled by central banks, which have to build their credibility with floating exchange rates. Now that oil prices are recovering, tighter monetary policies make sense, as they can allow higher prices to be absorbed by appreciating currencies. Tighter monetary policy and rising interest rates will restrain domestic growth and reduce capital flows to emerging economies. The capital flows that were searching for yields in emerging economies when interest rates in high-income countries were close to zero will likely decline, moderating growth in countries with large external funding needs. In such an environment, a cyclical downturn is more likely than further acceleration or even stabilization of growth at current levels. That slowdown may already be happening. The Purchasing Managers’ Index, which combines various indicators in the manufacturing sector (new orders, inventory levels, production, deliveries, employment), has fallen in the re- gion since the beginning of 2018 (figure 1.6, panel a). The drop from the peak reached in the last six months was particularly large in France, Germany, Italy, Turkey, and the United Kingdom, even if the index was still above 50, indicat- ing growth (figure 1.6, panel b). The coming cyclical downturn is expected to be modest, mainly because, with few exceptions, there are no signs of overheating that require sharp corrections. Investment ratios are still at balanced levels, and no steep declines in those ratios are expected. Inflation is at normal levels, and monetary tightening can be very gradual. GDP growth for the region is expected to fall from 2.7 percent in 2017 to 2.3 percent in 2018 and 2.1 percent in 2019. The expected slowdown is very similar for the eastern and western parts of the region. However, there are marked differences between smaller subregions. In the eastern part of the region, almost all the slowdown in growth is forecast to come from Turkey, with a modest strengthening of growth in oil-exporting coun- tries. In the western part of the region, the slowdown is expected to be rather evenly distributed among members of the European Union, and some accelera- tion of growth is expected in the Western Balkans. 10  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 FIGURE 1.6 The Purchasing Managers’ Index reached a. Recent weakening was stronger in Europe and Central Asia than in the rest of the world an all-time high in Europe and Central Asia in 2018 60 58 56 54 Index value 52 50 48 46 44 01 07 01 07 01 07 01 07 01 M M M M M M M M M 14 15 16 17 18 14 15 16 17 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 Europe and Central Asia World b. Weakening occurred in all of the region’s major economies 65 Max October 2017–March 2018 63 61 March 2018 59 Index value 57 55 53 51 49 47 March 2016 45 lic ce y ry ly d n n y m an ke tio ai an Ita do ga ub an Sp r m ra l Tu Po un ng p Fr er de Re H Ki G Fe h d ec ite n ia Cz Un ss Ru Source: World Bank. Note: A value of more than 50 indicates expansion. Although there are good reasons to expect only a modest deceleration of growth, a sharper correction is possible. Cyclical forces can easily reinforce one another, and additional shocks—including rising protectionism, geopolitical ten- sions, and larger than expected disruptions from Brexit—could slow growth. Does the region have the capacity for countercyclical policies? There is no room for further monetary stimulus; at most, the expected monetary tightening could be delayed slightly. The region has rebuilt some fiscal buffers. The average fiscal deficit is estimated to have been just above 1 percent of GDP in 2017, down from 6 percent of GDP during the 2009 crisis; it is close to levels at the end of the boom that preceded that crisis (figure 1.7). Fiscal stimulus is thus an option in several countries in the event of a sharper than expected slowdown. Under the baseline scenario of only a modest deceleration, further buildup of fiscal buffers seems the best strategy. Chapter 1: Economic Developments and Prospects ●  11 FIGURE 1.7 Government deficits in the region have 0 05 06 09 02 08 03 04 07 01 10 15 16 12 13 14 17 fallen sharply since 2009 0 11 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 0 1 General government balance in ECA (percent of GDP) 2 3 4 5 6 7 Source: World Economic Outlook, April 2018. Two additional questions are worth investigating. Did countries in the region use the recovery to adjust the structure of their economies, to better equip them for future challenges? Why has potential growth been slower since the crisis than it was during the boom that preceded it? The rest of this chapter addresses these questions. The region has shifted toward more exports. . . The biggest and most important adjustment during the recovery has been the shift of production capacity toward exports. Despite the slowdown in global trade, the share of exports in GDP is now 10 percentage points higher than it was during the 2000s (figure 1.8). This shift is important, because the economic struc- ture during the 2003–07 boom, when growth in many countries in the region was driven largely by expansion of nontradable sectors, was no longer sustainable. During that boom, capital inflows, oil revenues, and inflows of remittances re- sulted in increased domestic spending and a related loss in international com- petitiveness. In the new normal after the crisis, all three forms of foreign inflows are more moderate. The change has created the opportunity to become more competitive in international markets while reducing investments in real estate and other nontradable sectors. Imports have also increased as a share of GDP, albeit by less than exports. The overall current account surplus of the region has thus increased, largely because the deficits that Central European countries financed with massive capital in- flows during the boom have disappeared. These inflows came with a sharp de- cline in investment ratios in those countries. This adjustment is similar to the correction in East Asia after the 1998 financial crisis (box 1.1). During the 1990s, emerging East Asian economies received large capital inflows after they opened up to global markets, just as Central Europe did later, during the 2000s. The reversal of capital flows in 1998 had similar effects on East Asia as the 2008 crisis did on Central Europe. 12  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 FIGURE 1.8 Since the crisis, production in Europe and 50 Central Asia has shifted toward exports 45 40 Percent 35 30 25 00 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 Nominal export share of GDP Nominal import share of GDP Source: World Bank. . . . and adapted to technological change Apart from this macroeconomic adjustment, countries are adapting to the rapid change in technologies caused by the digital revolution, which has far-reaching consequences for the way production, labor, and commerce are organized. The analysis of how countries are adapting is beyond the scope of this chapter. Chap- ter 2 examines ECA’s involvement in some of these new technologies. In both regions, large current account deficits during the boom were financed with capital inflows that were reversed during the crisis. Emerging economies in East Asia received large capital inflows during the 1990s, after they opened their economies to global markets. Central European economies received large flows of foreign direct investment and other capital before and during their accession to the European Union. Their aggregate current account deficit widened to more than 8 percent of GDP in 2007. Heavy borrowing in foreign markets increased the vulnerability of both corporate and financial sectors to capital flow reversals (Truman 2013). In both cases, the reversal of capital inflows led to a steep and immediate decline in investment rates. In East Asia the loss in income was larger, so the immediate fall in investment rates was greater. Investments rates bounced back subsequently, but they remained below the preceding boom levels. A combination of factors caused the decline in labor productivity after the crisis Growth in ECA returned to precrisis levels in 2017. It has not been strong enough to compensate for the production losses that have occurred since the crisis, how- ever (figure 1.9). Moreover, as little spare capacity is left, it is unlikely that these losses can be recouped in the coming years. Thus not only actual growth but also potential growth has declined since the crisis. Chapter 1: Economic Developments and Prospects ●  13 BOX 1.1 Similarities between recoveries in Central Europe after 2009 and East Asia in the late 1990s The recovery of economies in Central Europe from was much greater. Five years after the crisis began, the 2008–09 global financial crisis was comparable GDP in East Asia was 37 percent below its precri- to the recovery of East Asia following the 1998 sis level. In Central Europe, the corresponding loss financial crisis. Both recoveries took about eight was 20 percent. years. In East Asia, however, the impact of the crisis FIGURE B1.1.1 Recovery in Central Europe was similar to recovery after Asian financial crisis a. The postcrisis loss in real GDP in b. . . . but recovery from the global Central Europe was smaller than in East Asia… financial crisis took as long t-1 t t+1 t+2 t+3 t+4 t+5 t+6 t+7 t+8 t-10 t-8 t-6 t-4 t-2 t t+2 t+4 t+6 t+8 0 4 2 precrisis average growth rate 10 Real GDP growth minus 0 Real GDP index minus 2 counter factual 20 4 6 30 8 40 10 12 50 14 16 60 East Asia and Pacific (t = 1998; 1997 = 100) 18 East Asia and Pacific (t = 1998) Central Europe (t = 2009; 2008 = 100) Central Europe (t = 2009) Source: Data from World Development Indicators and Eurostat. Note: The postcrisis counterfactual real GDP series were constructed assuming that annual GDP growth remained at the precrisis average growth rates. East Asia and Pacific includes Indonesia, Lao PDR, Malaysia, the Philippines, Thailand, and Vietnam. FIGURE B1.1.2 Investment rates adjusted immediately to reversal in capital flows a. Central European economies ran larger current b. . . . and experienced lower investment account deficits during the precrisis boom period . . . rates in the years after the crisis 10 35 8 30 as share of GDP (percent) Current account balance 6 Investment as share of GDP (percent) 4 25 2 0 t-10 t-8 t-6 t-4 t-2 t t+2 t+4 t+6 t+8 20 2 4 15 6 8 10 10 t-10 t-8 t-6 t-4 t-2 t t+2 t+4 t+6 t+8 Central Europe East Asia and Pacific Central Europe East Asia and Pacific Source: Data from World Development Indicators and Eurostat. Note: East Asia and Pacific includes Indonesia, Lao PDR, Malaysia, the Philippines, Thailand, and Vietnam. (Continued next page) 14  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 BOX 1.1 (continued) In both regions, large current account defi- than 8 percent of GDP in 2007. Heavy borrowing cits during the boom were financed with capital in foreign markets increased the vulnerability of inflows that were reversed during the crisis. Emerg- both corporate and financial sectors to capital flow ing economies in East Asia received large capital reversals (Truman 2013). In both cases, the rever- inflows during the 1990s, after they opened their sal of capital inflows led to a steep and immediate economies to global markets. Central European decline in investment rates. In East Asia the loss in economies received large flows of foreign direct income was larger, so the immediate fall in invest- investment and other capital before and dur- ment rates was greater. Investments rates bounced ing their accession to the European Union. Their back subsequently, but they remained below the aggregate current account deficit widened to more preceding boom levels. FIGURE 1.9 Even after full recovery, the e ects of the a. Annual growth in the European Union is back to the precrisis average. . . global financial crisis remain 5 4 Annual GDP growth (percent) 3 2 1 0 00 20 5 20 6 09 20 2 20 8 03 20 4 07 01 10 15 16 12 96 20 9 98 13 14 17 97 0 0 0 0 0 1 11 9 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 19 19 19 19 2 3 4 5 Real GDP growth in the European Union Average growth in the European Union, 1996–2017 b. . . . but lasting damage remains 4 2 Cumulative GDP loss after crisis, 0 relative to precrisis trend 2 96 97 98 20 9 00 20 1 02 20 3 04 20 5 06 20 7 08 09 10 20 1 12 13 14 15 16 17 0 1 0 0 9 0 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 19 20 19 20 19 19 20 20 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 Source: Eurostat. Chapter 1: Economic Developments and Prospects ●  15 In the region’s middle-income countries, slower labor productivity growth caused most of the deceleration in potential growth; only 0.35 percentage points of the slowdown in potential growth can be attributed to slowing labor supply growth (World Bank 2018). The changing pace of capital deepening cannot ex- plain this slowdown in labor productivity, most of which is reflected in total factor productivity (TFP), the unexplained factor in production functions (figure 1.10). Differences across countries were considerable, and many idiosyncratic events occurred. But after the crisis, every country in the region except Ireland experi- enced a decline in the contribution of TFP to labor productivity growth (figure 1.11). In most countries, TFP actually fell. FIGURE 1.10 After the crisis, labor productivity increased 4 Annual growth of real GDP per worker at a slower rate 3 in all ECA countries (percent) 2 1 0 90 19 1 92 19 3 94 19 5 96 19 7 98 20 9 00 20 1 02 20 3 04 20 5 06 20 7 08 20 9 10 20 1 20 2 20 3 14 9 0 1 1 9 0 9 0 1 9 9 0 1 0 20 19 20 19 20 19 20 19 19 20 19 20 2 3 4 5 6 Capital deepening contribution TFP growth contribution Labor productivity growth Source: Penn World Table 9.0 dataset. FIGURE 1.11 The contribution 12 of total factor productivity Contribution by TFP to labor productivity growth (TFP) to labor productivity 10 growth declined after the crisis 2009–14 (percentage points) 8 6 TJK 4 GEO MDA 2 KAZ KGZ SRB POL LVA IRL LTU SVK 0 ESP PRT GBR SWE EST FRA RUS ROU BLR HUN CZE UKR ARM10 4 2 MLT BEL AUT 2 MKD 4 6 8 12 ITA HRV BIH LUX FIN 2 CYP GRC AZE 4 Contribution by TFP to labor productivity growth 2003–08 (percentage points) Source: Penn World Table 9.0 dataset. 16  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 Labor productivity growth can be decomposed into three components: • changes in labor productivity within each economic sector (the within-sector component) • changes in labor productivity resulting from the reallocation of labor across sectors (the shift component) • a cross component that represents the interaction between the change in labor productivity within a given sector and the change in labor input share of that sector.5 As the third component is numerically insignificant, analysis of labor produc- tivity growth can be based on the within-sector and shift components. This de- composition reveals three important trends in the drivers of labor productivity in Germany and some countries in ECA (figure 1.12). • The deceleration in labor productivity growth in Germany started during the 1980s and continued in subsequent decades. Most of it was caused by weaker productivity growth within sectors. This pattern is also evident in other major European countries. • The contribution of sectoral shifts to overall labor productivity growth in Ger- many changed markedly over time. Between the 1970s and the start of the 2000s, the shift of employment toward more productive sectors increased la- bor productivity growth by about half a percentage point. The contribution of sectoral shifts to labor productivity growth fell to zero after 2000 and turned negative around the time of the 2008 global financial crisis. The long-term trend of labor shifting toward sectors with higher labor productivity, and likely higher capital intensity, came to an end when the digital economy start- ed in earnest (see below). The contribution to labor productivity growth of the shift of labor to more productive sectors was greater in Central European countries than in Germany before the crisis, but as in Germany, it diminished FIGURE 1.12 Labor productivity growth in 6 Germany is on a 5 Labor productivity growth (percent) long-term downward trend 4 3 2 1 0 71 75 79 83 87 91 95 99 03 07 11 15 1 20 19 19 20 19 19 19 20 19 20 19 19 2 3 4 Within-sector component Shift component Source: Data from KLEMS dataset (available at http://www.euklems.net/). Data for years before 1995 are KLEMS estimates. Note: Labor productivity is calculated as real value added per hour worked. Chapter 1: Economic Developments and Prospects ●  17 after the crisis. This change is in line with the boom and bust in the growth in FDI flows to these countries (EBRD 2015; World Bank 2018). During the boom period, FDI inflows created high-productivity jobs. These flows plummeted after the crisis. The contribution of the sectoral shift to productivity declined also in Armenia after the crisis (box 1.2). • Major crises—the second oil crisis of the late 1970s and the global financial crisis—led to a permanent loss in productivity. Even where productivity growth returned to the original (downward) trend, the damage of the crisis was not recouped. Productivity remains below the levels that would have been achieved had the crisis not occurred. The lasting impact of deep crises on productivity growth may have been caused by the loss of capital and skills that become obsolete or by a loss in confidence by workers who suffered ex- tended bouts of unemployment. The reasons for the long-term decline in within-sector labor productivity growth, in many ECA countries and globally, have been debated in the economic literature. The change in within-sector labor productivity can be decomposed into changes generated by capital deepening and changes that cannot be ex- plained (TFP). The contribution of capital deepening shrank significantly in sev- eral, but not all, countries during the years around the 2008 crisis. And almost all countries experienced a decline in within-sector TFP growth. The literature has suggested several possible causes for the slowdown in TFP. First, deep reforms led to a temporary rise in productivity growth in several ECA BOX 1.2 A new normal in Armenia Armenia’s economy changed markedly following led to an increase in labor productivity of 4 per- the global crisis. Per capita GDP growth fell from centage points a year. Within-sector productivity 8.4 percent a year in 2003–09 to 3.2 percent a year growth contributed only 2.7 percentage points to in 2010–16. Labor productivity growth was similar overall labor productivity growth, perhaps because in the two periods (6.7 percent a year before the elevated domestic demand reduced competitive crisis and 6.2 percent after), but migration flows, pressures on the supply side. employment levels, and the composition of labor These patterns reversed in the aftermath of the productivity growth changed dramatically. crisis. Emigration slowed, the population increased During the boom, many people found jobs by 1.7 percent between 2010 and 2016, and the abroad, especially toward the end of the period, construction sector and other nontradable sectors when oil revenues skyrocketed in Russia. As a laid off workers. As a result, the share of the popu- result, Armenia’s population declined by almost 5 lation that was employed fell to 34 percent. The percent between 2003 and 2009. At the same time, impact of sectoral shifts on productivity growth many jobs were created in construction and other turned negative, and the within-sector contribu- nontradable sectors, to satisfy domestic demand tion to annual labor productivity growth increased fueled by remittances. The combination of emi- to 7.4 percentage points. The increase may have gration and job creation boosted the share of the reflected increased competition, as domestic population that was employed from 36 percent in demand declined and production shifted toward 2003 to 40 percent in 2009. During those six years, goods and services that are tradable in interna- the shift toward capital-intensive construction tional markets. 18  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 countries. Productivity growth subsequently fell when major aspects of the re- form agenda were completed. In Central Europe, reforms connected to EU acces- sion initially boosted the growth of GDP and productivity. Reform momentum, and productivity growth, slowed after EU accession, in the mid-2000s (World Bank 2018). In Central Asia and the South Caucasus, TFP growth accelerated in the 1990s with institutional reforms in the early transition period. It plunged by the beginning of 2000s, perhaps because such benefits diminished as the room for further reforms narrowed. Second, across the world, technological changes in advanced and emerging economies affected the measurement and growth of productivity. The digital revolution that began in the 1990s led to a massive shift of resources to informa- tion and communications technology (ICT) industries. The output of these indus- tries is notoriously difficult to measure (for example, how does one value free Internet services financed by advertisements?). If the value of these new services is understated, then aggregate measurements of productivity may also be under- stated, particularly if growth slows in more traditional industries that are losing labor and capital to the ICT sector. Given the magnitude of the slowdown, how- ever, not all of it can be attributed to measurement issues (Syverson 2016). The shift to ICT industries may also be connected to lower productivity. It is costly and time consuming to overcome the special difficulties involved in com- mercializing novel technologies (David 1990). Because it may take time to realize the return on the labor and capital moving to these new industries, shifts of labor and capital to (initially) low-return industries may depress aggregate productiv- ity growth. In the United States, for example, the slowdown before the 2008 crisis occurred mainly in industries that produce information technology (IT) services or use such services intensively (Fernald 2015; Gordon 2016). Third, declining flexibility in some advanced countries may be reducing pro- ductivity growth. Business dynamism has declined in the United States, as re- flected in the drop in reallocation rates for jobs (after 1990) and workers (after 2000) (Davis and Haltiwanger 2014), and the pace of startup creation in the United States declined over the 2000s (Haltiwanger 2011). Across OECD coun- tries, productivity growth in the most advanced firms remained robust over the 2000s, but the difference in productivity levels between leading and lagging firms widened (Andrews, Criscuolo, and Gal 2015; Haltiwanger 2011). This phenome- non may have deepened the productivity slowdown if barriers to the reallocation of labor and capital intensified. Fourth, long-term trends in the global economy may be contributing to the slowdown in productivity growth. Aging and other demographic factors may account for part of the decline (Maestas, Mullen, and Powell 2016). The slow- down in global trade integration following the crisis may also be contributing to slower TFP growth (Adler and others 2017). No single factor is responsible for the observed deceleration of productivity growth: long-term trends, sectoral shifts, reform momentums, and global crises all play roles. No silver bullet can reignite productivity growth. Policy makers need a diverse set of instruments to encourage innovation, build up skills and infrastructure, and facilitate competition. Chapter 1: Economic Developments and Prospects ●  19 Notes 1. That used to be the rule globally, but after the global financial crisis a decade ago, that ratio came down closer to one. As illustrated in earlier ECA Economic Updates, the glob- al decline in the income elasticity of trade has not materialized in Europe and Central Asia. 2. Current real copper prices are also 57 percent below their historical peak, which was reached in April 1974. 3. A key reform in Uzbekistan was the elimination of the dual exchange rate, which re- duced domestic price distortions and opened up new export opportunities. The govern- ment also reduced import duties and is harmonizing the duty code with Eurasian Eco- nomic Union norms. 4. The much higher rate for youth unemployment is normal, for a variety of reasons. Search unemployment is much higher for people entering the labor market than for workers who already have jobs. Cyclical changes in unemployment also tend to be more pronounced for young people. During crisis periods, the lack of job vacancies dispropor- tionately hurts people entering the labor market for the first time. During economic re- coveries the opposite happens, as the opening up of new vacancies disproportionately benefits newcomers to the labor market. 5. This decomposition is based on sector-level data on real value added and the number of hours worked. We follow the methodology of Molnar and Chalaux (2015). References Adler, Gustavo, Romain Duval, Davide Furceri, Sinem Kilic Celik, Ksenia Koloskova, and Marcos Poplawski-Ribeiro. 2017. “Gone with the Headwinds: Global Productivity.” IMF Staff Discussion Note 2017/04, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC. Andrews, Dan, Chiara Criscuolo, and Peter N. Gal. 2015. Frontier Firms, Technology Diffusion and Public Policy: Micro Evidence from OECD Countries. The Future of Productivity: Main Background Papers. OECD Publishing, Paris. http://www. oecd.org/eco/growth/Frontier-Firms-Technology-Diffusion-and-Public- Policy-Micro-Evidence-from-OECD-Countries.pdf. David, Paul A. 1990. “The Dynamo and the Computer: An Historical Perspective on the Modern Productivity Paradox.” American Economic Review 80 (2): 355–61. http://www.dklevine.com/archive/refs4115.pdf. Davis, Steven, and John Haltiwanger. 2014. “Labor Market Fluidity and Economic Performance.” NBER Working Paper 20479, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA. http://www.nber.org/papers/w20479. EBRD (European Bank of Reconstruction and Development). 2015. Transition Report 2015–16: Rebalancing Finance. London: European Bank for Reconstruction and Development. Fernald, John G. 2014. “Productivity and Potential Output before, during, and after the Great Recession,” NBER Macroeconomics Annual 29: 1–51. https://doi. org/10.1086/680580. Gordon, Robert J. 2016. “Perspectives on the Rise and Fall of American Growth.” American Economic Review 106 (5): 72–76. DOI: 10.1257/aer.p20161126. 20  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 Haltiwanger, John. 2011. “Firm Dynamics and Productivity Growth.” European Investment Bank Papers 16 (1): 116–36. https://ssrn.com/abstract=1984016. Maestas, Nicole, Kathleen J. Mullen, and David Powell. 2016, “The Effect of Population Aging on Economic Growth, the Labor Force and Productivity.” NBER Working Paper 22452, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA. http://www.nber.org/papers/w22452. Molnar, M., and T. Chalaux. 2015. “Recent Trends in Productivity in China: Shift- Share Analysis of Labour Productivity Growth and the Evolution of the Productivity Gap.” OECD Economics Department Working Paper 1221, OECD Publishing, Paris. http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5js1j15rj5zt-en. Syverson, Chad. 2016. “Challenges to Mismeasurement Explanations for the U.S. Productivity Slowdown.” NBER Working Paper 21974, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA. http://www.nber.org/papers/w21974. World Bank. 2018. “Global Economic Prospects Broad-Based Upturn, but for How Long?” January. Washington, DC. 2 Cryptocurrencies and Blockchain: Hype or Transformational Technologies? Overview • The emergence of cryptocurrencies and blockchain technologies is part of a broader wave of technologies that facilitate peer-to-peer (P2P) commerce, in- dividualization of products, and flexibilization of production methods. For a variety of reasons, this wave gained traction after the global financial crisis a decade ago. Large digital platforms, such as Alibaba, Amazon, Uber, and Airbnb, are replacing many brick-and-mortar stores, service companies, and long-term employment relationships. • Blockchain technologies aim to go one step farther. They organize P2P trans- actions and P2P information flows without companies that operate digital platforms. Whether these technologies will completely eliminate middlemen or whether new forms of trusted intermediaries will emerge remains to be seen. • Cryptocurrencies are the first—and therefore most developed—application of blockchain technologies. They create money without central banks and facili- tate payments without financial institutions. The success of several cryptocur- rencies puts competitive pressure on transaction methods by existing finan- cial institutions. However, serious limitations have become apparent. Decentralized organization of markets without trusted intermediaries can be very costly, and the volatility of the value of cryptocurrencies is a big obstacle to their becoming an alternative to legal tender. 21 22  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 • Other potential applications of blockchain technologies, from smart contracts to decentralized databases and open source social networks, could well be- come more transformational than cryptocurrencies. Current experiments are likely to result in lasting innovations, even if current applications do not stand the test of time. • The emergence of blockchain technologies has triggered a flurry of activities in Europe and Central Asia (ECA), where people use cryptocurrencies for cross-border transactions and as speculative investments. Start-up companies are mining cryptocurrencies and providing blockchain services. Governments are experimenting with blockchain technologies to make their services more secure and more transparent. • Many factors provide a fertile ground for these activities in ECA. Several gov- ernments actively support innovation by start-ups. Governments are eager to digitize and streamline their services. Lack of trust in existing financial inter- mediation makes cryptocurrencies an interesting alternative in some coun- tries. Cryptocurrencies are also used to sidestep oversight of cross-border transfers. Cheap electricity (in Iceland and Georgia, for example) entices the mining of cryptocurrencies. • Cryptocurrencies and blockchain technologies pose a range of policy chal- lenges. They include the need to (a) apply rules of financial oversight, con- sumer protection, and tax administration while at the same time encouraging and facilitating innovation; (b) deal with the massive volume of electricity used to mine cryptocurrencies; and (c) determine whether governments and central banks can use blockchain technologies to improve their services. Poli- cymakers should find a balance between curbing the hype and unleashing potentially transformational new opportunities. International coordination is needed to share best practices, avoid regulatory arbitrage, and explore how to regulate global decentralized networks. Introduction Ten years after an ingenious experiment to create a cryptocurrency that allows secure and anonymous digital transactions to take place without the involve- ment of central banks or commercial banks, cryptocurrencies have become a multibillion-dollar industry. By December 2017, the average price of one bitcoin (the first cryptocurrency) had risen from just a few cents in 2009 to $15,000, dou- bling its value in a single month. These gains attracted many investors across the world. On December 1, 2017, the U.S. Commodity Futures Trading Commission approved trading in bitcoin futures. Although the price of a bitcoin had declined to about $8,000 in April 2018, the value of bitcoins in circulation was about $150 billion as of April 10, 2018. Big companies, and individuals working together in large pools, are compet- ing for the right to add new transactions to the existing chain of transactions. Their revenues, in the form of new bitcoins and transaction fees, are close to $20 million a day. Chapter 2: Cryptocurrencies and Blockchain: Hype or Transformational Technologies? ●  23 In the wake of bitcoin’s success, hundreds of alternative cryptocurrencies have been created. Digital tokens have been issued as general currency; for spe- cific purposes (for example, to rent computer capacity or cloud storage); and as an alternative to traditional shares in companies. Cryptocurrencies have evoked strong reactions. Critics call these virtual cur- rencies a bubble, a scam, and even evil (Krugman 2013; Popper 2018). Supporters predict that cryptocurrencies will ultimately replace money (Rooney 2018). There is less disagreement about the underlying blockchain technology, a pro- tocol to achieve decentralized consensus about the validity of a common data- base, stored in multiple locations. Many recognize that the blockchain protocol can lead to tamper-proof, secure information systems without the need for a single administrator. But even here views differ markedly about how transforma- tional this technology is. Believers foresee utopian societies of self-regulating in- dividuals, without government or trusted intermediaries. Doubters argue that the number of useful applications has been exaggerated, that lack of regulation can have disastrous effects, and that in most cases trusted intermediaries will continue to provide useful services. It is unclear how these technologies will develop in the long run. Conceivably, they could be absorbed by existing institutions, with central banks issuing digital cash, governments using blockchain to maintain information systems, and com- mercial banks putting payment systems on the blockchain.1 Many intermediaries might become obsolete, and many new financial instruments might be created by companies that do not yet exist. The main legacy of cryptocurrencies may not be the blockchain technology but standardized digital IDs using a combination of public and private keys on open-source software.2 Such a development would allow individuals to own more of their data, instead of participating in proprie- tary information networks (Johnson 2018). Whatever the future brings, cryptocurrencies and blockchain protocols are part of a tidal wave of new technologies that is changing the way production and commerce are organized. Digital platforms, the sharing economy, apps, and 3D printers are fragmenting production and facilitating P2P transactions. Many of these new applications originated soon after the global financial cri- sis of 2008, when the bankruptcies of established companies convinced many people that the economy would never be the same again. Investors were looking for new investment opportunities. Workers who had lost their jobs were willing to accept more flexible working relations. Consumers were persuaded to use some of their underutilized assets commercially. The fact that bitcoin was created in 2009, soon after the crisis, was probably no coincidence. Trust in financial institutions had eroded, and the time was ripe to explore fundamentally different approaches. Whatever the future of cryptocur- rencies and blockchain technologies may be, the trends toward decentralization and P2P transactions are unmistakable. Cryptocurrency and blockchain activities are widespread in Europe and Cen- tral Asia (ECA). Massive mining of cryptocurrencies takes place in Iceland, Swe- den, and Georgia. Many Russians own digital wallets, and experiments are ongo- ing in Serbia and Tajikistan to use blockchain technology to make the sending of 24  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 remittances more efficient (UNDP 2018). Estonia is using blockchain software in registries and plans to extend its use to medicine (https://e-estonia.com/). Start- ups in many countries in ECA are contributing to these technologies, attracting finance for their activities via initial coin offerings (ICOs).3 Household invest- ments in cryptocurrencies are not insignificant. Switzerland aims to become a cryptocurrency and blockchain hub and is leading in adjusting regulations to these new technologies. Comprehensive, global information on cryptocurrency and blockchain activi- ties is not available. But anecdotal evidence suggests that ECA is more active than many other parts of the world, likely because of a combination of factors. Gov- ernments of many countries—from Estonia to Georgia and Slovenia—are experi- menting with blockchain technologies. In many countries in the region, a sup- portive business climate encourages start-ups. And, especially in the eastern part of the region, the relatively new financial sector provides fertile ground for ex- periments. The lack of legacy technologies in the financial sector—and the lack of trusted intermediaries—makes exploring new financial instruments attractive. The rest of this chapter is organized as follows. Section 2.2 looks at the suc- cesses and drawbacks of cryptocurrencies, examining whether there is a future for money not issued by central banks. Section 2.3 looks at the possibility of smart contracts. It assesses whether markets can be organized without intermediaries and explores the possibility of secure decentralized databases. Section 2.4 sum- marizes some of the activities in ECA, with an emphasis on the experience in Georgia, which has been particularly active. Section 2.5 addresses the many pol- icy challenges these new technologies have triggered. Creating digital money without central banks Since the emergence of e-commerce, myriad attempts have been made to develop electronic payment systems.4 Many successful and unsuccessful attempts were linked to credit card systems. Attempts to create digital cash are especially thought-provoking. Like coins and banknotes, digital cash should be anonymous and counterfeit-proof. People should be able to use it without the intermediation of banks, in the same way traditional cash is used outside the banking system. But unlike traditional cash, individuals, rather than a central bank, would create these digital coins. Private parties rather than the government would thus accrue the seigniorage. The white paper that started bitcoin in 2008 outlined a way to create and oper- ate a decentralized electronic cash system (Nakamoto 2008). The payment system would not be under the control of a bank or a central authority. Rather, a large number of independent participants would operate it. The paper used existing cryptographic techniques of public and private keys to create anonymous and secure IDs. It used existing cryptographic time stamps, based on hash functions, to make past transactions irreversible. With those elements, electronic cash could become (pseudo)anonymous and counterfeit-proof.5 But the main contribution of the white paper was the method it proposed to keep track of past transactions without a trusted intermediary. It would be done through an automatic process Chapter 2: Cryptocurrencies and Blockchain: Hype or Transformational Technologies? ●  25 that would achieve consensus among most participants about the cumulative history of transactions, even if a minority of participants sent erroneous messages to the network. The solution to this so-called distributed consensus problem was to let partici- pants compete for permission to add a new batch of transactions to the decentral- ized database. Participants use their computer power to solve a difficult puzzle. The solution, which is considered proof of work, is impossible to find analyti- cally; it can be reached only through trial and error. The first person who solves the puzzle can add a block of new transactions to the chain of existing transac- tions—hence the term blockchain—and broadcast the new block to the network, so that all participants can update the blockchain in their own copy.6 Although the puzzle is difficult to solve, its solution is easy to verify. There- fore, the nodes in the bitcoin network can easily determine if a proposed block is valid and should be added to the chain. Even if a node goes offline for a period of time, the network is not jeopardized. When the node goes back online, it ac- cepts the longest valid chain as the correct one. If most of the computer power is owned by honest participants, the expectation is that they will create the longest chain, as the probability that they add new blocks is proportional to their com- puter power. As a result, the longest chain can be considered the consensus view. If a dishonest participant adds a block that is not accepted by others in the chain, that block will not become part of the longest chain, because the participant will not have enough computer power to add more blocks to the chain quickly enough. The difficulty of the puzzle is adjusted every two weeks, in order to cre- ate about one block per 10 minutes. Limiting the addition of a new block to the blockchain to one every 10 minutes (on average) prevents the network from be- ing overwhelmed and keeps the size of the blockchain manageable. Competition for the right to add a block to the blockchain also solved the problem of the creation of new electronic coins. People who solve the puzzle re- ceive a combination of newly minted coins and transaction fees.7 With every block, new coins are created. Every four years the number of new coins per block is cut in half, until the maximum number of 21 million bitcoins is reached. Most of the remaining bitcoins will be added over the next 15 years. The creation of new digital coins is like unearthing gold, which is why the puzzle solvers are called miners in the world of cryptocurrencies. Ten years after the publication of the white paper, the concepts underlying bitcoin have proven successful. The blockchain technology is working and se- cure. Seventeen million bitcoins have been created, with an aggregate value of $137 billion in 2018. Numerous alternative cryptocurrencies have emerged, and many companies and research groups are exploring additional blockchain ap- plications. Cryptocurrencies have unleashed a wave of financial innovations, putting competitive pressure on the financial sector, especially its facilitation of cross-border transfers. Bitcoin’s biggest success has also become its most worrisome weakness. The proof-of-work concept that ensured achievement of a decentralized consensus has become excessively costly and wasteful. Attracted by the reward of newly minted digital coins, investors have created massive computer power with spe- cialized chips to compete for permission to add a block to the blockchain. Over 26  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 the past few months, the reward for solving the puzzle ranged from $100,000 to $250,000, depending on the price of bitcoin, the fees per transaction, and the number of transactions in a block. As more computer power was added to the network, the puzzle automatically became more difficult (figure 2.1). As a result, more and more electricity was needed to solve the puzzle. The system currently consumes an estimated 53 TWh of electricity a year— almost as much as the entire country of Bangladesh consumes (Digiconomist n.d.). The cost of electricity used to process a single average transaction (about $20) can power about five households in a high-income country for a day. These electricity costs are likely to rise. Because miners’ profits of are still large, more computer power is being added to the network, increasing the diffi- culty of the puzzle. People who use the network to transfer bitcoins do not di- rectly experience these costs, because miners are paid mainly through seignior- age rather than fees. But the costs in terms of electricity use, and the resulting burden on the environment, are real. A paradoxical side-effect of the rapid increase in computing power is that computer power has become more concentrated. A few companies have installed huge computer capacity in large dedicated factories, using specialized chips. Their exploitation of economies of scale leads to concentration of market power. Participants with less computer power started working together in pools (fig- ure 2.2). With limited computing power, the probability of being the first to solve the puzzle is very small, and the income stream is irregular and thus unpredictable. By pooling forces, participants can generate a small but steady income stream. This concentration of computer power makes the network more vulnerable to malicious attacks. Even without attacks, if the market becomes an oligopoly, min- ers could manipulate transaction fees, refuse to process certain types of transac- tions, or deny service to users. FIGURE 2.1 As the price of bitcoin soared in 2017, 3.5E+12 so did competition 3E+12 among miners Mining Di culty Index 2.5E+12 2E+12 1.5E+12 1E+12 5E+11 0 -16 -16 -16 -16 -17 -17 -17 -17 -17 -18 -18 6 -17 -1 ar ay ep ov an ul an ar ay ep ov ar ul 1-J 1-J 1-M 1-M 1-M 1-M 1-N 1-J 1-M 1-N 1-S 1-J 1-S Source: blockchain.info. Note: The bitcoin difficulty index measures the difficulty of finding a new block on the blockchain. The greater the difficulty, the longer the time it takes on average for a miner to find a valid block. The difficulty in the first block of the bitcoin blockchain was 1. The difficulty is adjusted up or down every 2,016 blocks. If the previous 2,016 blocks take less than two weeks to generate, the difficulty is increased (and vice versa). Chapter 2: Cryptocurrencies and Blockchain: Hype or Transformational Technologies? ●  27 FIGURE 2.2 Three large Bitcoin.com mining pools provide GBMiners 1% 0% half of all network blocks BW.COM 1% KanoPool BitClub Network 1% 58COIN 3% 1% BitFury 3% BTC.com BTCC Pool 4% 24% F2Pool 7% Unknown 9% AntPool 13% BTC.TOP 10% ViaBTC SlushPool 12% 11% Source: blockchain.info. Note: Data are for March 2018. The danger of market concentration is likely to increase. As the number of newly minted bitcoins declines, the income of miners will increasingly depend on fees. Lower profits will discourage new investors from entering the market, and smaller, inefficient miners are likely to exit. The sustainability of a completely decentralized payment system will be tested if miners must forgo the large prof- its coming from seigniorage. An advantage of declining profits because of disappearing seigniorage is that electricity use will no longer increase and might even decline. Box 2.1 models the long-term mechanisms determining the degree of difficulty of the puzzle, energy use, user fees, and even the price of bitcoins. The model is simplistic, particularly as it ignores adjustment lags and speculative bubbles, which likely play a signifi- cant role in reality. But it sheds light on balancing mechanisms in the cryptocur- rency market and provides a framework for exploring the consequences of the disappearance of seigniorage. As of spring 2018, the total reward a miner received per transaction was just below $100 (figure 2.3). Most of it comes through seignorage (the bitcoin block reward) rather than fees. The impact on the demand for bitcoin if this reward shifts away from seignorage toward fees may not be dramatic. Large interna- tional bank transfers can involve similar levels of fees (through the SWIFT inter- national payment system). 28  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 BOX 2.1 Equilibrium mechanisms in the bitcoin market Over time, as fewer and fewer bitcoins are created, power should be expected, which will increase the the income of miners will shift from seigniorage difficulty of the puzzle. In equilibrium, the difficulty toward fees. This box models the consequences of of the puzzle is given by the shift for electricity use and other characteristics of the mining process. (2.1.5)      Assume that miners use the following produc- Demand for transactions by consumers is down- tion function to solve the puzzle that allows them ward sloping in the size of the transaction fees: to add transactions to the blockchain: (2.1.6) (2.1.1) where T D is the total desired number of transac- where T S is the total number of transactions miners tions miners supply, and B is a scaling factor. The supply, A is the level of technology, K is the capi- fees will be determined by the condition tal stock, E is the electricity consumption, and D (2.1.7) is the difficulty of the puzzle. There is substitution between capital and electricity: miners can install If consumers want more transactions than min- more advanced, more electricity-efficient equip - ers can facilitate, fees will go up and demand for ment to achieve the same solution power with less transactions will adjust. Miners are constrained by electricity. the rule that only one block with not many more Miners minimize costs under the restriction of than 2,000 transactions can be added to the block- the production function, where the cost per trans- chain. This restriction is represented by T. Conse- action is quently, fees are determined by consumer prefer- (2.1.2) ences and the maximum number of transactions allowed in the system: where c is the cost per transaction, r is the return to capital, δ is the depreciation rate of the equipment, (2.1.8) Ph is the price of the capital goods, and Pe is the price of electricity. The final price to endogenize is the price of a bit- This optimization leads to the following cost per coin. Currently, speculative behavior, which is very transaction c : difficult to model, is likely to be one of the deter- minants of that price. A standard money demand (2.1.3)      function can describe the main determinants: If there are profits, new miners will keep enter- (2.1.9) ing the market, which will cause the difficulty of the where p is the price of bitcoin, a is the aver- puzzle to adjust so that in equilibrium profits equal age size of transactions, and V is the velocity of zero: money. If people want to keep bitcoins in their (2.1.4) wallet because they expect the price to rise, then where n is the block reward in terms of the number the velocity of circulation will fall and the current of newly minted bitcoins, p is the price of bitcoin, price will rise. If people want to transfer larger val- and f are the fees. ues with bitcoins, pushing up the average value of The market is not yet in equilibrium. Miners’ transactions, the price will also rise. These factors profits are still large, as is the risk-adjusted return. may have been the two main drivers behind the As a result, still more investments in computing sharp increase in the bitcoin price in December (Continued next page) Chapter 2: Cryptocurrencies and Blockchain: Hype or Transformational Technologies? ●  29 BOX 2.1 (continued) 2017. Market participants bought bitcoins to trans- created. A decline in n reduces the energy use per fer large sums, and speculation pushed the price transaction. Increasing the price of energy can also farther up. In equilibrium the bitcoin price would reduce energy use. Such a price increase would be given by not increase the cost of transactions, it would merely reduce the difficulty of the puzzle, as some (2.1.10) miners are pushed out of the market. Increasing where M S is the exogenously given number of bit- the overall energy efficiency of mining (increasing coins in circulation. Substituting this result in the A in equation 2.1.1) does not reduce energy use. It difficulty expression yields merely makes the puzzle more difficult. The long-term equilibrium can be achieved at a (2.1.11)      lower electricity use, but this raises other concerns. It could lead to even more concentration of min- The reduced-form equation for energy use per ing power, as in the process many miners would transaction is exit the market, making it easier for highly special- ized mining facilities to capture larger shares of the (2.1.12) computational power. The concentration of mining power could erode trust in the network and thus This model suggests that the system could reduce incentives to hold bitcoins long, increasing achieve a long-term equilibrium in which electricity the velocity of money, which would cause a drop consumption is lower because fewer bitcoins are in the price and further instability in the network. FIGURE 2.3 Most mining revenue comes from the 180 seignorage (block reward) 160 of the network 140 Earnings of miners (dollars) 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 6 -16 -16 16 -16 -16 17 -17 -17 -17 -17 -17 -18 -18 -1 - p- eb pr un g ct ov an ar ar ay ul ov ec Au Se O -J -A -M -M -N -M -J -D N -F -J 4- 13 9- 7- 2- 19 14 24 22 21 23 29 28 18 Mining revenue per transaction Fees per transaction Source: blockchain.info. 30  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 The lack of scalability of the bitcoin payment system is another limitation. The proof-of-work concept prevents malicious participants from overwhelming the blockchain, ensuring its veracity. But it limits the addition of new blocks to one every 10 minutes and each block to a maximum size of 1 MB. The average num- ber of transactions that can be included in a block of this size is 2,000. In its cur- rent form, the bitcoin payment network can thus process only three transactions per second. By contrast, credit card companies process thousands of transactions per second. This constraint makes it impossible for bitcoin to substitute for large- scale digital payment systems. Many attempts have been made, through new cryptocurrencies or additions to the bitcoin network, to avoid the electricity-consuming puzzle and to increase scalability. A leading concept is proof of stake, which could replace proof of work.8 In this concept, participants are elected to add a new block to the block- chain on the basis of the amount of own coins they want to attach to the contract. This proof-of-stake concept is like putting coins in escrow to earn permission to intermediate and charge transaction fees. Selection would still be probabilistic, but richer participants would have a higher probability of being selected. Ethe- reum, which runs a popular cryptocurrency, may adopt this approach. It repre- sents a shift back in the direction of trusted intermediaries. The concept is not very different from existing financial institutions that are trusted because they have a stake in preserving their company. An even more radical departure from proof of work is to grant the authority to maintain the blockchain to a limited number of preselected, trusted partici- pants. Ripple has taken this approach, working with commercial banks. It rein- states trusted intermediaries into the blockchain network. Another experiment to reduce electricity costs is to design a simple, albeit less secure, system for small transactions and to put only the balances of many small transactions on the blockchain. Lightning Network is taking this approach, as an addition to the bitcoin blockchain (Poon and Dryja 2016). Most of the discussions in the cryptocurrency community are about mecha- nisms to make trusted intermediaries superfluous. But another important ques- tion is how well cryptocurrencies perform the traditional functions of money. Money is useful because it can serve as medium of exchange, a unit of account, and a store of value. Like other forms of electronic money, cryptocurrencies have advantages over physical commodities like gold or banknotes. They are easier to store and easier to transfer over large distances. However, some inherent draw- backs of cryptocurrencies make them less optimal than legal tender in most countries. The most important drawback is the volatility of the purchasing power of cryptocurrencies, as illustrated by their exchange rate vis-à-vis legal tender (fig- ure 2.4). That volatility in purchasing power makes them very risky to accept as a medium of exchange. It also makes them suboptimal as a store of value, as there is no guarantee that their value will not drop to zero. Advocates argue that cryp- tocurrencies cannot be inflationary, because their supply is fixed or at least lim- ited. In fact, cryptocurrencies can be extremely inflationary if demand for them Chapter 2: Cryptocurrencies and Blockchain: Hype or Transformational Technologies? ●  31 FIGURE 2.4 Daily price movements of bitcoin continue to be large 25,000 30 20 Bitcoin price (dollars per bitcoin) 20,000 10 Daily return (percent) 15,000 0 10 10,000 20 30 5,000 40 0 50 -A 3 -D 3 -A 3 -A 4 -D 4 -A 4 -A 5 -D 5 -A 5 -A 6 -D 6 28 c-16 -A 7 -D 7 -17 28 r-1 28 g-1 -1 28 -1 28 c-1 28 r-1 28 g-1 28 c-1 28 r-1 28 -1 28 c-1 28 r-1 28 g-1 ec pr ug ug p p p p e e e e u u u -A -A 28 28 Daily closing price (dollars, left-hand axis) Daily return (percent, right-hand axis) 90 80 70 Daily range (percent) 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 -13 28 -13 28 -13 28 -14 28 -14 28 -14 28 -15 28 -15 28 -15 28 -16 28 -16 28 -16 28 -17 28 -17 -17 pr ug ec pr ug ec pr ug ec pr ug ec pr ug ec -A -A -A -A -A -D -D -D -A -D -D -A -A -A -A 28 28 Source: coinmarketcap.com. Note: Panel a shows the percentage difference between the opening and closing price for the day. Panel b shows the percentage difference be- tween the highest and lowest price in a day. drops (because, for example, customers prefer alternative cryptocurrencies that are more user-friendly, are more scalable, or provide more privacy). The volatility of their purchasing power also reduces the value of cryptocurrencies as a unit of measurement. With large overall price swings, it becomes difficult to discern movements in relative prices.9 In fact, there may be a natural limit to how stable the price of bitcoin can be- come. Unlike other commodity-type assets, bitcoin does not have a feedback loop from the supply side. 32  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 Sustained volatility can be very inefficient for a bitcoin-based economy. Ex- tracting information about relative prices would be very costly. Entering into long-term contracts could become prohibitively expensive. The blockchain has proven to be very secure, but it is impossible to avoid se- curity concerns altogether. Cryptocurrencies have been stolen by hacks into ex- changes, where they are exchanged against legal tender or other cryptocurren- cies, and hacks into mining pools. Users can protect stored cryptocurrencies by keeping their wallets offline. These offline wallets are called cold wallets; wallets that are online are called hot wallets. Exchanges cannot be avoided; they remain a weak link. The problem is especially severe because once stolen there is little re- course to recover the funds. Many of these problems are already being addressed. The security breaches of exchange sites forced many exchanges to use hot and cold wallets. This practice involves storing most deposits in an offline wallet, whose private keys are secure and are never stored on a network-connected device. A small portion of the de- posits is transferred to the hot wallet, which is used for daily transactions and payments. If there is a security breach, potential losses are limited to the amount stored in the hot wallet; at least in theory, most deposits should be protected. The attractiveness of cryptocurrencies will be tested once governments extend their financial oversight to cryptocurrencies in their efforts to fight money laun- dering, tax evasion, and illicit transactions. Doing so will challenge the (pseudo) anonymity of the cryptocurrencies. This oversight will be easier if the concentra- tion of mining power continues to increase. To the extent that current use is mo- tivated partly by the desire to avoid oversight, increased surveillance will reduce demand for cryptocurrencies. However, it is also possible that oversight may make the use of cryptocurrencies more attractive, as it becomes easier to incorpo- rate them in the overall financial infrastructure. The innovative power of cryptocurrencies has been impressive. They have already put some competitive pressure on cross-border payment systems. The concept is promising, because it potentially improves financial access for people who live in remote areas that are not covered by financial institutions. It would be wrong to judge cryptocurrencies on the current state of affairs. As with many new technologies, childhood diseases will be outgrown. However, their real contribution may turn out to be very different from originally foreseen. The original designer of bitcoin and the blockchain technology wrote that “the main benefits are lost if a trusted third party is still required” (Nakamoto 2008). In fact, the future benefits may appear precisely because the networks shift back to trusted intermediaries. It is even conceivable that the most successful crypto- currencies will be linked to legal tender and issued by central banks. Creating digital markets without intermediaries The ability to achieve distributed consensus, and to store immutable information in a decentralized database, makes a wide variety of P2P contracts possible with- out a centralized authority. Enthusiasm about other possibilities is enormous. As one observer put it, “The paradox about bitcoin is that it may well turn out to be Chapter 2: Cryptocurrencies and Blockchain: Hype or Transformational Technologies? ●  33 a revolutionary breakthrough and at the same time a colossal failure as a cur- rency” (Johnson 2018). Smart, or self-executing, contracts are examples of blockchain applications that go well beyond instantaneous transfers of funds with cryptocurrencies. Such contracts could be used on a blockchain platform to engage in commitments over time, without the help of middlemen. Ethereum, which has been operational since the summer of 2015, enables the creation of P2P contracts that outline the conditions under which future payments occur. One example of such a smart contract is a parametric insurance contract, such as a contract that insures farmers against drought. The seller commits to pay a certain amount if rainfall remains below a certain threshold. The contract is pre- programmed to read the realized rainfall from a trusted weather data feed at a point in the future. The buyer purchases the contract with a one-time payment. The seller commits funds equal to the maximum payout in case of a drought. As the contract is fully collateralized, there is no counterparty risk. At the expiration date, either the buyer or the seller can execute the contract to check if the trigger condition has been met. The contract distributes the funds between the buyer and the seller and terminates itself. This type of contract could be handled without intermediation (although insurance companies could also provide such con- tracts). Storing these contracts on the blockchain makes them immutable and guarantees their enforcement. Smart contracts could also be used for financial instruments other than insur- ance. Entrepreneurs already sell tokens to fund new companies through ICOs and promise future dividend payments in a smart contract on a blockchain. The tokens are similar to shares issued in an initial public offering (IPO), but there are key differences. Shares are sold on stock markets and typically give the right via shareholder representation to participate in decision making. In contrast, tokens are traded on a P2P blockchain with no privileges outside what is written in the smart contract. Regulators across the world are working on directives that would extend oversight to ICOs. Doing so would increase the similarities between ICOs and IPOs, but the financial smart contract would provide a new, innovative, in- strument to fund start-ups. It creates relatively liquid new financial instruments that can be used to finance small-scale risky ventures. The potential advantages of such P2P contracts are obvious. They could be available to people who have no access to financial instruments (box 2.2). They could also increase access to financial services that is now limited because of distrust in financial institutions. Currently, enforcement of contracts is not straightforward in parts of ECA. Smart contracts are secure, even if the counter- parties do not know each other. Blockchain platforms could make these financial products more liquid if the new products could be traded outside specialized markets. There are potential disadvantages of smart contracts. Adjustments to the cur- rent blockchain platforms are likely required for them to work in a user-friendly, efficient, and scalable way. These drawbacks may be the reason why, outside ICOs, there have not yet been large-scale applications of smart contracts. The first disadvantage of existing platforms is the volatility of the value of cryptocurrencies, which is especially inconvenient with contracts that span many 34  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 BOX 2.2 Providing access to secure insurance In many countries, individuals, farmers, and Especially in the transition economies of ECA, small- to medium-size businesses have limited or financial markets are incomplete. Market-based no access to insurance or hedging instruments financial institutions were established only in the for commodity price risks, floods, hurricanes, early 1990s in these economies, and they are still exchange rate volatility, and the like. Markets are only partially developed. Insurance products are incomplete or not available. When they are avail- particularly underdeveloped. The insurance rate able, contracts are often not trusted to be enforced of farmers in ECA is well below the global aver- or are very costly, particularly for small transac- age (box figure 2.2.1). A recent report finds that tions. Lack of this key financial service is associated these incomplete financial sectors are associated with a high risk of falling into poverty, business fail- with lower growth of the bottom 40 percent of the ure, and the absence of entrepreneurship. income distribution (Gould and Melecky 2017). FIGURE B2.2.1 Farmers in Europe and Central Asia are underinsured 7 12 months (2011, percentage) Adults working in agriculture who purchased agricultural 6 insurance in the previous 5 4 3 2 1 0 Sub-Saharan Developing World South Asia Developing Africa East Asia Europe and and Pacific Central Asia Source: World Bank Findex Survey. Suppose that a small wheat farmer in a develop- ers are not likely to have access to international ing country is 30 days away from harvest. Although financial markets in which these contracts are well she may be happy with the current wheat price, she established and markets are deep, and the need knows that she can sustain at most a 20 percent for intermediaries can make the process prohibi- drop between now and the time she sells her har- tively expensive. vest. In order to hedge against a larger decline, the Government interventions to support such con- farmer can purchase a put option with a duration tracts have often been ineffective. Such policies of one month and a strike that is 20 percent lower are either too costly from the government fiscal than the current market price. Entering in such a standpoint or create moral hazard if noninsured contract will ensure that if the price falls below the risks are covered by government payouts in the strike price, the contract will pay the difference. event of widespread loss. The contract mitigates the risk by creating a price Blockchain technology and smart contracts floor. raise the potential for insurance/minimum price Despite the relative simplicity of these con- contracts that are flexible, low-cost, secure, and tracts, many frictions may prevent small farmers highly customizable to a multitude of risks and from entering into such agreements. Although payouts (large and small), with only marginal trans- bilateral over-the-counter agreements are pos- actions costs. This approach would provide easy sible, the legal framework may not be well adapted access to foreign insurers, and enforcement costs to accommodate them, and enforcement can be would be low if the payout were collateralized in difficult and costly. Small- and medium-size farm- the blockchain. Chapter 2: Cryptocurrencies and Blockchain: Hype or Transformational Technologies? ●  35 years. Parties to the contract likely want security in terms of the purchasing power of payments. That goal could possibly be met by linking the contracts to futures markets, but it seems more promising to use tokens that are linked to le- gal tender. Doing so would be a major step away from the original concept of cryptocurrencies, as it requires a trusted party that can guarantee the value of the token. Still, it could be a natural development of the smart contracts. Fizzy is a parametric insurance application by the insurance company AXA (https://fizzy.axa/), in which passengers purchase insurance by sending funds to the smart contract along with their flight information. If their flight is delayed for more than two hours according to a publicly accessible database, the smart contracts pays out compensation in euros. Fizzy could be developed into an Ethereum-based smart contract, but the volatility of the Ether token is likely to prove too much of a drawback for a large-scale application. If contracts shift to tokens that are linked to legal tender, the market can no longer operate without a trusted intermediary. Such an intermediary must sell additional tokens in exchange for legal tender if demand for tokens increases. The intermediary must hold part of the legal tender in reserve, so that tokens can be repurchased if demand declines. Such reserves are similar to the reserves fi- nancial institutions must hold when they create electronic accounts or mobile payment systems. In the case of tokens linked to legal tender, participants who maintain the blockchain would no longer be rewarded with the seigniorage of new coins; the reward would consist only of fees paid by the parties in the con- tract. These fees might not be enough to attract enough participants who want to compete with one another. It is plausible that such a system would naturally converge to a permissioned blockchain, in which several preselected servers up- date the blockchain, eliminating the need for costly competition among servers and making the maintenance of the platform more efficient. A second disadvantage of smart contracts is that they are collateralized by freezing potential payouts on the blockchain. The blockchain provides security, but it is also inefficient (like putting money in escrow, where it cannot be used productively). Insurance companies can pool risks and invest the cash flow. As a result, they should be able to provide cheaper services than offered in P2P con- tracts, in which investing the cash flow is not possible. Cutting out insurance companies could thus increase costs. There may be a trade-off between efficiency and independence from interme- diaries. Higher costs may be worth paying where the public does not trust that normal contracts will be enforced. Where trust exists, the public might prefer to deal with insurance companies rather than anonymous peers. If blockchain con- tracts are used, trusted intermediaries will likely offer contracts without freezing the assets in the contract, reintroducing trust into these transactions. A similar argument holds for standard financial intermediation by banks. Be- cause P2P contracts likely have a broader reach and can create innovative instru- ments, they could provide competitive additions to existing banking products. However, commercial banks have a big advantage in financial intermediation. By pooling risk, they can turn short-term liabilities into long-term assets. Because intermediation between savings and investments is much more difficult in inde- pendent P2P contracts without risk pooling, smart contracts are likely to be com- 36  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 bined with, or even integrated into, existing financial institutions, rather than replacing them. Risk pooling could also be explicitly programmed in smart con- tracts, implying that these contracts will not be completely risk free. A third potential disadvantage of following the original blockchain design for smart contracts is the public nature of the blockchain. Transparency is attractive because it makes it easy to audit the validity of contracts by virtually anyone with an Internet connection. But participants in transactions may want more privacy. Therefore, it is plausible that smart contract applications will develop in the di- rection of more encryption, more restricted-read access, or both.10 Many governments are experimenting with blockchain to digitize their ser- vices. Experiments with land and real estate registries are popular. One objective is to avoid the vulnerabilities of a centralized server. Decentralized storage of data means that several servers are always online, making it more difficult to alter data. Another objective is to prepare for a link with smart contracts, so that real es- tate could be sold online without the help of notaries, as ownership could be veri- fied on the blockchain. Governments would still take responsibility for the infor- mation, including information about zoning and restrictions on sales. The goal is thus not to purge governments from transactions but rather to make government services more efficient and more trustworthy. In these applications, the registry can be updated by a limited, selected num- ber of servers (a permissioned approach). There is no need to let an undeter- mined number of miners compete for the updates. There is, however, a need for full transparency. Not everyone should be able to write on the system, but every- one should be able to read the registry. The reading provides the actual service and is also a mechanism for double-checking the veracity of the information. Another government application could be public procurement. The central government could issue a token backed by the national currency. Each ministry or municipality could be issued an address and allocated tokens as part of the budget process. They would use the tokens to pay contractors for public pur- chases; contractors would redeem their tokens with the central government. This mechanism would make all purchases not only fully transparent but also in- stantly auditable by anyone, reducing graft. Social protection transfers could benefit from a similar set-up, although privacy concerns would have to be addressed. Large companies are also exploring blockchain applications. Companies need to be online all the time, for internal communications and communications with clients. One central server is not reliable in this respect; a system that provides a common view of information through communication between independent servers is superior to a central server. Decentralized information is also more dif- ficult to alter through hacks, because hackers would have to break into more than one server. Companies are experimenting with different versions of the blockchain proto- col to transition toward a more decentralized information strategy. Experiments are moving toward permissioned systems, with a preselected number of servers maintaining the decentralized database. Decentralizing reduces the probability that participating servers become malicious, makes it easier to secure them, and Chapter 2: Cryptocurrencies and Blockchain: Hype or Transformational Technologies? ●  37 prevents the costly competition that is needed in a permission-less system. The decentralized consensus problem is easier to solve than in the original bitcoin application. However, with a small number of servers, data systems other than blockchain could be used. The advantages of a permissioned system may be the reason why there are no large-scale blockchain applications yet in these compa- nies, despite the many experiments. Blockchain technology could also be used to manage vast and diverse data systems, such as health records, that are too complicated for a central server. They could benefit from decentralized servers that communicate with one another and always reflect the latest update of treatments and test results. The existence of secure, decentralized digital health records could significantly increase the effi- ciency of the health care industry. The main challenge for these kinds of data systems is privacy. Both reading and writing of health records should be limited. This requires adjustments to the original blockchain design, which is public, in the sense that everyone can read it. A health record application would be private, with secure encryption to protect confidentiality of medical information. These examples show the broad range of potential applications of blockchain. They also suggest that many of them could be very different from the original blockchain design. Instead of a public database, with an unlimited number of participants that maintain the blockchain and an independent cryptocurrency to be used in transactions, the most successful future applications could work with private information, a limited number of permissioned servers, and a token linked to legal tender for transactions. The most important components of those future applications could become the cryptography behind personal IDs, the time stamps that make data irrevers- ible, and the open source character of the platform. These applications would not eliminate trusted intermediaries, they would make more competition between intermediaries possible. Digital platforms like Facebook, Uber, Airbnb, and Ama- zon use proprietary software and organize their own user IDs; the veracity of their data is not protected through decentralized storage. All these platforms can gain natural monopoly power because of network effects, because the platforms become more useful and more powerful if more people participate. A standardize system of digital IDs and open-source networks could break that monopoly and increase entry opportunities. Experiments with P2P digital interactions are very important for this reason. Even if current applications do not stand the test of time, the ultimate result could well be transformational. Blockchain applications in Europe and Central Asia Many countries in ECA have provided fertile ground for cryptocurrencies and blockchain technologies, especially since late 2016. When cryptocurrencies emerged, almost 10 years ago, activities were small-scale. As everywhere else in the world, early transactions were used largely for gambling or for the purchase illegal products on the dark web (figure 2.5).11 38  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 FIGURE 2.5 Early use of bitcoin was clustered around gambling and the dark web Source: blockchain.info. Note: Each link (“edge”) in the figure represents a bitcoin transfer between nodes. The size of the nodes represents the total inflows of funds (one entity can have multiple addresses). The use of cryptocurrencies intensified at the end of 2016, especially for large cross-border transfers. When the prices of cryptocurrencies skyrocketed in 2017, investments in mining capacity increased sharply and people began investing in cryptocurrencies in the hope of benefitting from further price rises. Investments in blockchain technologies surged. Governments in many ECA countries began experimenting with blockchain to improve their services. Some central banks are studying the issuance of legal tender in the form of digital cur- rency, and financial institutions are piloting blockchain applications to incorpo- rate them in the existing financial architecture. ECA has become an important center for ICOs. In terms of the number of projects, the Russian Federation ranks third globally (with 8.8 percent of all proj- ects), Switzerland fifth (6.9 percent), Estonia seventh (3.0 percent), and Lithuania eighth (2.8 percent) (figure 2.5). This section examines the reasons for the strong interest in blockchain technologies in ECA, based on anecdotal evidence. Blockchain technologies, which place a heavy emphasis on making financial intermediaries redundant, are particularly attractive in countries where trust in Chapter 2: Cryptocurrencies and Blockchain: Hype or Transformational Technologies? ●  39 financial institutions is lacking, people want to avoid oversight, and/or financial sectors are underdeveloped (Aris 2017). Countries where corruption and political instability are higher, confidence in the rule of law is lower, and regulatory qual- ity is lower tend to adopt bitcoin more rapidly (all four correlations shown in figure 2.6 are statistically significant). A prime example is Republica Bolivariana de Venezuela, where people seek alternatives for the bolivar, the value of which been eroded by hyperinflation. Such extreme examples of hyperinflation no longer exist in ECA. Nevertheless, some anecdotal evidence suggests that weak institutions or vulnerable banks are one reason behind the interest in cryptocurrencies.12 Financial dollarization remains substantial in the eastern part of the region, reflecting lack of trust in FIGURE 2.6 Adoption of bitcoin is negatively correlated with the quality of institutions a. Rule of law b. Regulatory quality Weekly bitcoin volume growth (percent, dollars) 9 Weekly bitcoin volume growth (percent, dollars) 9 MAR MAR 8 8 NGA NGA VEN PAK TZA VEN TZA 7 7 PAK 6 6 5 RUS 5 RUS MYS MYS IDN KEN IDN KEN PER HKG HKG 4 CHN ZAF 4 CHN ZAF IRN THA IND IRN IND THA POL UKR POL UKR HRV JPN HRV ARE JPN 3 MEX SAU ROM SGP 3 SAU TURROM SGP ARG BRA USA ARG BRA USA DOM NZL DOM NZL PHL NOR NOR 2 COL CHE 2 PHL COL CHE HUN CHL CAN HUN CHL CAN CZE GBR CZE GBR 1 VNM 1 VNM 0 0 –3 –2 –1 0 1 2 3 –3 –2 –1 0 1 2 3 Index value Index value c. Political stability d. Control of corruption Weekly bitcoin volume growth (percent, dollars) Weekly bitcoin volume growth (percent, dollars) 9 9 MAR MAR 8 8 NGA NGA PAK VEN TZA VEN PAK TZA 7 7 6 6 5 RUS 5 RUS IDN MYS IDN MYS KEN PER HKG KEN PER HKG THA ZAF CHN ZAF 4 CHN 4 IRNTHA UKR IND POL UKR IND POL ARE HRV JPN HRV JPN SAU 3 TUR MEX SAU ROM SGP 3 MEX ROM SGP BRA ARG USA BRA ARGTUR USA PHL DOM SWE NZL DOMPHL NZL 2 NOR 2 NOR COL CHE COL HUN CHE CHLHUN CAN CHL CAN DNK GBR AUS AUS 1 VNM CZE 1 VNM CZE GBR 0 0 –3 –2 –1 0 1 2 –2 1 0 1 2 3 Index value Index value Source: World Development Indicators and localbitcoins.com. Note: As bitcoin is traded on a global network, it is difficult to determine the geographic origin and destination of transactions. This analysis uses the currency denomination on a popular P2P bitcoin exchange (localbitcoins.com). The vertical axis shows the speed of adoption of bitcoin, mea- sured by the average weekly growth of the volume of bitcoins exchanged on this exchange. The institutional variables are sourced from the World Bank’s Governance Indicators database. 40  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 existing legal tender. It has resulted in much lower savings at banks than in other parts of the world (Gould and Melecky 2017). Households are looking for alter- native saving options. Another reason for the use of blockchain technologies in ECA is the desire to develop alternative means of transferring large funds. Russia is the largest issuer (more than $956 million)—followed by the United States ($811 million) and Swit- zerland ($514 million)—because of the $850 million raised for the TON block- chain.13 One of the goals of that ambitious project is to provide an alternative to the SWIFT international interbank payment system (Aris 2017). Russia also has the largest number of users of the digital wallet on blockchain.com (UNDP 2018). Despite these examples, it is doubtful that ICOs will have a broader application as venture capital if security is not built in for investors. Established financial centers are striving to adjust to meet the competition from a disruptive technology like blockchain. Switzerland is leading in adjusting financial regulations to cover ICOs, ensuring that they are incorporated into the existing financial architecture rather than developed as an outside alternative (see Atkins 2018a, 2018b; Financial Times 2018). Its aims to become a cryptocur- rency and blockchain hub is reflected in its vibrant ICO activities. For example, Sirin Labs raised $157 million for the development of a blockchain-based smart- phone. In line with these developments, a Swiss foundation, advised by Jacob Frenkel, chairman of JPMorgan Chase International, and Nobel laureate Myron Scholes, raised $50 million to develop a cryptocurrency backed by Special Draw- ing Rights (SDRs). Saga would have a stable value and be integrated into the existing financial sector, including anti-money-laundering checks, with deposits in the International Monetary Fund’s SDR holdings. France is also planning a regulatory framework for ICOs (Aris 2017). Governments in ECA are accumulating in-house experience with blockchain pilots to improve government services. Estonia, Georgia, and Ukraine have ex- perimented with blockchain to set up land and real estate registries. They are still searching for more specialized and more efficient designs, but the experiments have given a boost to efforts to digitize government services. Some government banks in ECA are seeking to improve their services through the use of blockchain technologies. The Russian state-owned VEB bank is pilot- ing a new blockchain-based payment system with the regional government of Kaliningrad (Milano 2018). Another state-owned bank, Sberbank, is partnering with Russia’s federal anti-monopoly service to use blockchain technologies to store and transfer documents. Official bodies in ECA are investing in blockchain research to improve ser- vices. The European Commission has funded a blockchain observatory to en- courage blockchain technologies and help formulate policy recommendations, especially for smart contracts and the improvement of government services (Young 2017; Nicholson 2018). Lithuania has opened a blockchain center to incu- bate start-ups, partnering with similar centers in Melbourne and Shanghai (Med- iTelegraph 2017). Separately, the central bank of Lithuania offers a one-year sand- box environment for start-ups that develop new digital financial technologies. Estonia is exploring opportunities to use blockchain technologies in medicine Chapter 2: Cryptocurrencies and Blockchain: Hype or Transformational Technologies? ●  41 (https://e-estonia.com/).Georgia is investigating the possibility of supporting smart contracts. Serbia and Tajikistan are experimenting with remittances on blockchain, in cooperation with the United Nations Development Programme (UNDP 2018). Azerbaijan is experimenting with digital IDs for banking using blockchain (SputnikInternational 2018). The Swedish central bank is considering launching its own digital currency (Aris 2017). Small ECA countries with a supportive business climate and the absence of legacy financial instruments are well placed to introduce new financial instru- ments based on blockchain technologies. Tokenization and ICOs enable small start-ups, which lack easy access to finance, to raise funds in global markets. Dynamic start-ups in the Baltic countries and several other small countries, in- cluding Georgia, have issued ICOs (figure 2.7). These examples are instructive for other economies in the region that have long been dominated by state-owned enterprises and have grown primarily through the nontradable sectors. For many of those economies, the challenge is to unleash new growth potential in FIGURE 2.7 Europe and Central Asia is the site a. Estimated share of ICO projects of many initial coin Share o erings (ICOs) 18.07% .20% b. Estimated funds raised in ICOs Amount raised $956,174,361 $110,000 Source: Websites for ICO listings (icowatchlist.com, icobench.com, and tokenreport.com). 42  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 internationally competitive sectors. The new P2P technologies provide a gateway to these markets. More specifically, activities on and contributions to blockchain networks are automatically exposed to international competition. Seemingly more than in other parts of the world, governments in ECA are restraining natural monopolies of tech giants. People in the region show strong privacy concerns when data become proprietary and are captured by tech com- panies. The open character of the blockchain architecture could break the mo- nopoly on data. Several governments and the European Commission are looking at the possibility of using the new technologies to reduce the power of large digi- tal network companies. The anecdotal evidence presented here suggests that there may be multiple explanations for the blockchain activities in Europe and Central Asia: • In the eastern part of the region, market-based financial sectors are relatively new and have not fully matured. Insurance and capital markets are underde- veloped. Land registration and cadasters of real estate can still be improved. Blockchain technologies could help fill these gaps. • Vulnerabilities in the banking sectors after the transition in 1991, the global financial crisis in 2008, and the plunge in oil prices in 2014 have eroded trust in financial institutions. In the eastern part of the region, bank deposits are exceptionally low, and consumers are looking for alternative ways to invest their savings (Gould and Melecky 2017) • Throughout the region, banks dominate financial sectors. Venture capital that does not require collateral is scarce. New forms of fund raising could help tech start-ups that have a potential to grow quickly in competitive global markets. • Demand for new ways of making cross-border transfers is strong. Remittanc- es are large in the region; the high transactions costs associated with them is onerous. The region also has a large share of illicit financial flows, linked to money laundering, tax evasion, and the circumventing of capital controls or sanctions. • Governments in the region provide a broad range of services. They oversee elaborate social security systems, and most of them play an integrating role in health care, pensions, and education. There is continuous demand to make these services more efficient and more transparent. Many governments are experimenting with blockchain technologies to achieve those goals. • Governments in the region are looking for ways to break the power of large tech companies and increase privacy. It is unclear which experiments will have a lasting impact. The transforma- tional impact may come from applications that are very different from the origi- nal blockchain design. The blockchain experiment has already boosted innova- tion and competition, in both the private sector and government. For that reason alone, blockchain experiments deserve support. ECA is active in the mining of cryptocurrencies. Georgia is home to one of the largest mining companies of the world (Bitfury) as well as many smaller miners (box 2.3). Bitfury, which is building additional facilities in Canada, Iceland, and Norway, controls about 10–15 percent of global mining. Chapter 2: Cryptocurrencies and Blockchain: Hype or Transformational Technologies? ●  43 BOX 2.3 Cryptocurrency mining and the demand for electricity in Georgia Mining of cryptocurrencies is surprisingly wide- FIGURE B2.3.1 Georgia had the fastest-growing spread in Georgia, thanks to tax exemptions and electricity consumption in Europe and Central Asia in 2010–14 low electricity prices. Indeed, Georgia has had the Tajikistan fastest-growing electricity consumption per capita Cyprus in all of ECA since 2009 (box figure 2.3.1). Moldova This process was jumpstarted when Bitfury, one Greece United Kingdom of the world’s largest bitcoin miners, built a 20MW Electricity consumption Montenegro data center in Gori and a 40MW mining facility in annual growth 2000–09 Italy Switzerland Tbilisi, with funding from the Georgian Co-Invest- Electricity consumption Denmark ment Fund. The Tbilisi facility, located in a free annual growth 2010–14 France industrial zone, has daily revenue of $250,000– Spain Sweden $400,000. Bitfury recently sold this facility to its Ireland Chinese partner, Asian Chong Sing Holdings. It Portugal is now building mobile data centers to be sold to Norway Luxembourg other investors. Other companies have built mining Belgium facilities in free industrial zones in Kutaisi. Netherlands Finland Many households have joined mining pools. Croatia Surveys indicate that up to 5 percent of house- Uzbekistan holds in Georgia are engaged in cryptocurrency Serbia Czech Republic mining or investments. Macedonia, FYR These mining activities have had a striking Germany impact on electricity consumption, turning Geor- Slovak Republic Iceland gia from a net exporter to a net importer of elec- Bulgaria tricity. Estimates of the share of Georgia’s elec- Hungary Austria tricity demand devoted to cryptocurrency mining Lithuania range from 10 to 15 percent—and the figure could Ukraine be even higher, because it is difficult to observe Romania Russian Federation small-scale mining activities. Per capita electricity Slovenia consumption in Georgia was 3,343 KWh in 2016, Poland Belarus almost three times higher than in countries with Estonia similar levels of per capita income. Even after cor- Malta recting for historically high electricity consump- Turkmenistan Latvia tion in Georgia (likely because of the availability Bosnia and Herzegovina of inexpensive hydropower), energy use in recent Armenia years is remarkable. Between 2014 and 2016, per Turkey Albania capita energy consumption increased by 655 Kazakhstan KWh, of which only 65 KWh can be explained by Azerbaijan Kyrgyz Republic rises in income. Some 590 KWh, or 18 percent of Georgia total demand, remains unexplained. Even before 10 8 6 4 2 0 –2 –4 –6 –8 2015—actually, since the start of bitcoin, in 2009— Growth per capita (percent) the unexplained part of electricity demand was ris- ing (box figure 2.3.2). Source: World Development Indicators and the International Energy Agency. (Continued next page) 44  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 BOX 2.3 (continued) FIGURE B2.3.2 Unexplained electricity demand in Georgia has risen rapidly since 2009 2,500 2,000 Kwh per capita 1,500 1,000 500 0 00 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 Annual residual consumption of electricity Average residual consumption 2000–09 Source: Data for 2000–14 are from World Development Indicators and the International Energy Agency. Data for 2015 and 2016 are from Georgia’s energy services company. Of course, the mining of cryptocurrencies also It would be interesting to see how the financing raises incomes. Mining revenues in Georgia could of these activities shows up in the balance of pay- well contribute several percentage points to GDP, ments. Revenues in cryptocurrencies are likely even if these revenues are not registered as part exchanged into legal tender at exchanges abroad, after which part of the legal tender is transferred of GDP (if they were registered, they would prob- back to Georgia. ably be classified as exports). What is observable is Investment opportunities in mining cryptocur- the additional consumption and imports not only rencies likely attract foreign direct investment. It is of electricity and computer parts but also of more too early to draw conclusions about the spillovers general consumption financed by the mining reve- to other sectors of the economy. It may trigger nues. This increase is similar to the increase in con- other innovative activities, or it could crowd out sumption as a result of large inflows of remittances. investments in other activities. Cryptocurrency mining is also booming in Iceland (Perper 2018), which is on track to use more electricity for mining than it uses to power all of its residences. Armenia is set to be home to a 50MW mining farm (Murphy and Stafford 2018). Slush Pool, a bitcoin mining pool with a market share of about 7 percent and many participants from all over the world, is run by Satoshi Labs, a mining com- pany based in the Czech Republic. KnCMiner is a mining pool in Sweden. An- other mining pool is in Russia. Cryptocurrency mining thrives in a cold climate (avoiding the need for cool- ing) and in areas where electricity costs are low. En+ Group, a Russian energy company, is preparing to offer electricity to cryptocurrency miners at five plants in Siberia (Marson 2017; Helms 2018). The electricity capacity available for min- ers could well dwarf the capacity of existing mining facilities in ECA. EN+ could attract Chinese miners, who are currently dominant players in the global market but find a less and less hospitable environment in China. Chapter 2: Cryptocurrencies and Blockchain: Hype or Transformational Technologies? ●  45 These mining activities illustrate the dynamic response to new opportunities by entrepreneurs in the region. They bode well for the development of other ap- plications of these technologies. But the heavy electricity use by companies that compete for the right to mine cryptocurrencies is a growing problem. How to accommodate and mitigate growing electricity demand from cryptocurrency miners and prepare for future declines in demand if mining activities relocate or mining stops altogether in its current form are the most urgent challenges as these markets develop. There are multiple approaches to meeting these challenges. The cryptocur- rency community is looking for more efficient ways to update the blockchain. Governments are reconsidering their tariff policies; in order to curtail energy use, they need to raise electricity tariffs for miners or create more market-based mech- anisms to determine tariffs. If unchecked, electricity use could rise before alterna- tives are found, possibly resulting in long-term damage to the environment. In addition, the fiscal costs of investments in power plants (or contingent liabilities, where new power plants are developed in partnership with the private sector) could threaten public finances if demand for electricity driven by cryptocurren- cies collapses. Policy challenges Cryptocurrencies and blockchain technologies pose difficult challenges for pol- icy makers. There is no regulatory framework for transfers made with cryptocur- rencies or smart contracts. Transfers occur outside anti-money-laundering com- pliance programs, and smart contracts are not subject to consumer protection laws or financial oversight. Tax codes do not fully cover the new markets if cryptocurrencies are not rec- ognized in the law as payment systems but are instead viewed as commodities. It is difficult to determine the geographic location of the value added created by cryptocurrency mining. Tax legislation therefore has to be adjusted to incorporate these new activities into direct and indirect tax systems. Another ambiguity for policy makers is whether these new activities should be supported or constrained. Should they be encouraged because of positive ex- ternalities and first-mover benefits? Or should they be constrained, because they crowd out investments with greater social return? Another pertinent question for policy makers is whether and how they can use these technologies to improve their own services. It is too early to offer specific advice, because there is still great uncertainty about the future of cryptocurrencies and blockchain technologies. But experi- ences with other digital technologies—such as e-commerce, digital platforms, and the sharing economy—suggest that the following general guidelines should be followed. • Give the new technologies space, and avoid imposing restrictive legislation before initial ambiguities are resolved. Even if these technologies are ultimately unsuc- cessful, the experiments can help develop entrepreneurial skills, put competi- tive pressure on more traditional activities, and trigger innovations in other 46  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 sectors. A dynamic business climate should encourage innovations, experi- ments, and risk taking. • Make implicit subsidies explicit, and be clear about risks. If activities are not yet covered by the tax code or are undertaken in special economic zones, the im- plicit subsidy and its temporary nature should be calculated and made public. Consumers should be warned about risks, such as the risks associated with volatile cryptocurrencies. • Start planning for leveling the playing field. If these technologies become success- ful, they should be integrated into the formal economy. Tax codes and regula- tions should be adjusted, so that both old and new technologies operate on a level playing field.14 • Innovate as government. The corporate motto “think big, start small, quit soon, and scale fast” is relevant for governments, too. Blockchain technologies pro- vide a stimulus to further digitize government services. Most successful gov- ernments are bold in their ideas, know when to terminate experiments that are not successful, and have the professionalism to quickly scale small experi- ments that are promising. An undesirable side effect of the cryptocurrencies is the outsized use of elec- tricity in mining. If mining companies pay a lower electricity price than the mar- ginal cost of supplying more electricity, governments should consider raising tariffs or at least calculating the implicit subsidy. The sharp increase in electricity demand might be an opportunity to develop an electricity market with intra-day price fluctuations, so that price differentiation reflects actual costs. Uncertainty about future electricity demand for cryptocurrency mining warrants a rethinking of contingent liabilities of governments where additional power plants are built by public-private partnerships. Guarantees related to future demand for electric- ity used in cryptocurrency mining are riskier than for other electricity demand. At some point, electricity tariffs for mining could be used as indirect taxation of the value added created by miners. Although it is difficult to determine the geo- graphic location of the output of these activities, it is easy to locate the inputs. Ultimately, financial oversight will cover cryptocurrencies and smart con- tracts. This process will be a gradual one of trial and error, and it will depend on the direction in which blockchain applications develop. First steps have already been taken, in the United States (where bitcoin can be traded on futures markets), in Switzerland (where regulation of ICOs was proposed), and in the Netherlands (where guidance was provided about the tax treatment of cryptocurrency hold- ings). Oversight to prevent money laundering, tax evasion, pump-and-dump schemes, and illicit cross-border transfers focuses on transactions in which cryp- tocurrencies are exchanged for legal tender.15 At some point, this oversight could extend to miners and other companies that update the blockchain. The ultimate goal of all these efforts is to create a level playing field, so that blockchain applica- tion can be integrated into existing markets. The long-term outcome could be that supervision becomes much more effective, because the transparency of the block- chain could provide supervisors and courts with access to real-time information. This access would also make it easier to develop valuable early-warning systems. Chapter 2: Cryptocurrencies and Blockchain: Hype or Transformational Technologies? ●  47 The many experiments and brainstorms by governments and central banks throughout the region are inspiring. Just as blockchain opportunities put com- petitive pressure on private financial sectors, they also trigger creative thinking in governments. It is important that these experiments not consider current blockchain designs as the full universe of possibilities. Even if decentralized maintenance of digital government data can have major advantages, a permis- sioned system seems much more appropriate and efficient for governments than the original system that maintains the blockchain for cryptocurrencies. The ulti- mate conclusion might even be that other data systems are better suited for spe- cific applications than blockchain technologies, including in the creation of digi- tal currencies by central banks (box 2.4). The flurry of experiments shows the success of the blockchain revolution, but it also illustrates that progress may come from innovations that are quite different from the original design and objec- tive of the blockchain protocol. BOX 2.4 Will central banks issue digital currencies? Central banks are exploring the possibility of issu- The Swedish central bank is exploring the pos- ing digital money, for several reasons. First, the sibility of making electronic accounts and value use of traditional cash is steadily declining (Rogoff cards directly available to the public. The idea is to 2014). Second, cryptocurrencies have provided a administer this digital money in a central register at working digital alternative to cash, replicating the the central bank. This proposal to replicate instru- original characteristics of cash in digital format. ments that already exist in the private sector stems Like cash, cryptocurrencies allow anonymous P2P from the understanding that the government has transactions without involvement of middlemen. the legal obligation to provide means of payment Third, demand for tokens that are linked to legal to the public. It could, however, undercut the tra- tender is increasing. These tokens could be used in ditional financial intermediation role of commercial the same way as cryptocurrencies but without the banks, which transform liquid liabilities into long- drawback of high volatility in their value. It seems a term assets. A central bank cannot take over the natural development to transform actual coins and role of pooling liquidity to finance investments. banknotes into digital tokens with the same legal If a central bank chose blockchain technolo- protection and subject to the same price stabili- gies to administer digital transactions in a decen- zation as all money issued by central banks.a The tralized way, it would compete more directly with transparency of transactions with central bank digi- cryptocurrencies, with the advantage of providing tal currencies could facilitate the systematic con- a token with a more stable value. Still, the system duct of monetary policy (Bordo and Levin 2017). would differ fundamentally from the early crypto- There are serious concerns about the issuance currency protocols. Supply of central bank coins of digital money by central banks. Digital tokens would be endogenous—in order to link their value issued by central banks could potentially replace to legal tender—and seigniorage would accrue to not only cash but also electronic payment systems the central bank. Such a system would undoubt- operated by commercial banks, which already offer edly become a permissioned blockchain, with only electronic accounts, mobile money, and value cards. preselected servers participating (Danezis and These systems can be uploaded and used offline. Meiklejohn 2016). a. Bech and Garratt (2017) provides a comprehensive overview of the differences between central bank digital currencies and cryptocurrencies. 48  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 Notes 1. Electronic accounts are much more popular than cash. Central banks do provide elec- tronic accounts to banks; they do not yet provide digital cash or electronic accounts di- rectly to the public. 2. The public key functions as a pseudonym in communications. The private key is used to prove one’s identity. If this digital ID becomes a standard on open-source platforms, it could make IDs and passwords on proprietary platforms like Facebook or Google redun- dant. 3. See, for example, the Georgian start-up Golden Fleece (https://goldenfleece.co/). 4. Clark (2017) describes the early history of digital payment systems. 5. A bitcoin address is an identifier of 26–35 alphanumeric characters that are equivalent to unique IDs. Every transaction is recorded on the public blockchain, so anyone can view each address involved in each transaction. However, it is difficult to know the real iden- tity of the people involved in the transactions. For this reason, the bitcoin network is of- ten described as being pseudo-anonymous rather than completely anonymous. 6. In the bitcoin protocol, a block can contain about 2,000 new transactions. 7. The block rewards are hard-coded, but there is no guidance on what the fee should be. As miners have discretion over which transactions to include, they select the transactions with the highest fees. As the size of each block on the blockchain is limited to 1 MB (roughly 2,000 transactions), if a user wants her transaction to be included in the next block, she has to offer a high enough fee so that her transaction is among the approxi- mately 2,000 that are selected. 8. Other new concepts, often variations of the proof of stake, are proof of activity, proof of burn, proof of capacity, and proof of elapsed time (Rooney 2018). 9. The Austrian school and Keynesian economists have long debated the pros and cons of private, decentralized money versus government-sanctioned legal tender. What is an attraction for one group of economists (no reliance on governments, which are inclined to impose an inflation tax) is a nightmare for the other (financial instability, lack of mon- etary instruments). 10. ZeroCash (http://zerocash-project.org/) is a good example of a platform that provides more encryption. 11. Silk Road, an online market for illegal drugs that used bitcoins, started in 2011. The FBI took it down in 2014. 12. The vulnerability of banks in oil-exporting countries after the fall in oil prices was one of the reasons for the formation of the Blockchain and Cryptocurrency Association (Dyussembekova 2017). 13. This project is spearheaded by Pavel Durov, one of the founders of the Russian social media platform Vkontakte, and the encrypted messaging app Telegram (Khrennikov and Voitova 2018). 14. Carstens (2018) strongly advocates this point. 15. Levin, O’Brien, and Zuberi (2015) discusses the regulation of cryptocurrencies. Bal (2015) discusses tax issues. He and others (2016) provide a comprehensive overview of all oversight measures. Chapter 2: Cryptocurrencies and Blockchain: Hype or Transformational Technologies? ●  49 References Aris, Ben. 2017. “Russia’s Blockchain Revolution.” Moscow Times, October 6. https:// themoscowtimes.com/articles/eastern-europes-blockchain-revolution-59179. Atkins, Ralph. 2018a. “Swiss Authorities Tread Wary Path through CryptoValley.” Financial Times, March 20. https://www.ft.com/content/bea458ba-25fc-11e8-b27e-cc62a39d57a0. ———. 2018b. “Switzerland’s Stock Exchange Chairman Calls for ‘e-Franc.’” Financial Times. February 25. https://www.ft.com/content/fcc7d27a-186e-11e8-9376-4a6390addb44. Bal, Aleksandra. 2015. “How to Tax Bitcoin.” In Handbook of Digital Currency: Bitcoin, Innovation, Financial Instruments, and Big Data, ed. David Lee Kuo Chuen. Cambridge, MA: Academic Press. Bech, Morten Linnemann, and Rodney Garratt. 2017. “Central Bank Cryptocurrencies.” September 17. Bank for International Settlements, Basel. https://www.bis.org/publ/ qtrpdf/r_qt1709f.htm. Bordo, Michael D., and Andrew T. Levin. 2017. “Central Bank Digital Currency and the Future of Monetary Policy.” NBER Working Paper 23711. National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA. http://www.nber.org/papers/w23711. Carstens, Agustin. 2018. “Money in the Digital Age: What Role for Central Banks?” Lecture by the general manager of the Bank for International Settlements, House of Finance, Goethe University, Frankfurt, February 6. https://www.bis.org/speeches/sp180206.htm. Castor, Amy. 2017. “A (Short) Guide to Blockchain Consensus Protocols.” CoinDesk. May 17. https://www.coindesk.com/short-guide-blockchain-consensus-protocols/. Clark, Jeremy. 2017. “The Long Road to Bitcoin.” Foreword to “Distributed Ledger Technology (DLT) and Blockchain,” Harish Natarajan, Solvej Karla Krause, and Helen Luskin Gradstein, World Bank, FinTech Note No. 1, Washington, DC. http://documents.worldbank.org/ curated/en/177911513714062215/Distributed-Ledger-Technology-DLT-and-blockchain. Danezis, George, and Sarah Meiklejohn. 2016. “Centrally Banked Cryptocurrencies.” https://arxiv.org/pdf/1505.06895.pdf. Digiconomist. n.d. Bitcoin Energy Consumption Index. https://digiconomist.net/bitcoin- energy-consumption. Dyussembekova, Zhazira. 2017. “Kazakh Organizations form Blockchain and Cryptocurrency Association.” Astana Times, November 23. https://astanatimes.com/2017/11/kazakh- organisations-form-blockchain-and-cryptocurrency-association/. Financial Times. 2018. “Bringing Swiss Order to Initial Coin Offerings.” February 19. https://www.ft.com/content/36ef310c-1566-11e8-9e9c-25c814761640. Gould, David Michael, and Martin Melecky. 2017. “Risks and Returns: Managing Financial Trade-Offs for Inclusive Growth in Europe and Central Asia.” World Bank, Washington, DC. https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/25494. He, Dong, Karl Habermeier, Ross Leckow, Vikram Haksar, Yasmina, Almeida, Mikari Kashima, Nadim Kyriakos-Saad, Hiroko Oura, Tahsin Saadi Sedik, Natalia Stetsenko, and Concepcion Verdugo-Yepes. 2016. “Virtual Currencies and Beyond: Initial Considerations.” IMF Staff Discussion Note SDN/16/03, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC. https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/sdn/2016/sdn1603.pdf. Helms, Kevin. 2018. “Five Siberian Power Plants Attracting Crypto Miners with Surplus Electricity.” February 15. https://news.bitcoin.com/five-siberian-power-plants-attracting- cryptocurrency-miners-surplus-electricity/. Levin, Richard B., Aaron A. O’Brien, and Madina M. Zuberi. 2015. “Real Regulation of Virtual Currencies.” In Handbook of Digital Currency: Bitcoin, Innovation, Financial Instruments, and Big Data, ed. David Lee Kuo Chuen. Cambridge, MA: Academic Press. 50  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 Johnson, S. 2018. “Beyond the Bitcoin Bubble.” New York Times, January 16. https://www. nytimes.com/2018/01/16/magazine/beyond-the-bitcoin-bubble.html. Khrennikov, Ilya, and Olga Voitova, 2018. “Telegram Triples Price in Largest Initial Coin Offering.” Bloomberg Technology, February 28. https://www.bloomberg.com/news/ articles/2018-02-28/telegram-said-to-triple-price-in-largest-initial-coin-offering. Krugman, Paul. 2013. “Bitcoin Is Evil.” New York Times, December 28. https://krugman. blogs.nytimes.com/2013/12/28/bitcoin-is-evil/. Marson, James. 2017. “Frigid, Industrial Siberia: Primed for the Digital Era.” September 3. https://www.wsj.com/articles/frigid-industrial-siberia-primed-for-the-digital- era-1504436400. MediTelegraph. 2017. “Lithuania Emerges as Blockchain Gateway to Europe.” December 5. http://www.themeditelegraph.com/en/green-and-tech/technology/2017/12/05/ lithuania-emerges-blockchain-gateway-europe-YVX3gnWsH60lH36eLrU3qL/index. html. Milano, Annaliese. 2018. “Regional Government in Russia to Test Blockchain Payments.” Coindesk, February 20. https://www.coindesk.com/regional-government-russia-test- blockchain-payments/. Murphy, Hannah, and Philip Stafford. 2018. “Blockchain Explainer: A Revolution Only in Its Infancy.” Financial Times, February 1. https://www.ft.com/content/6c707162-ffb1- 11e7-9650-9c0ad2d7c5b5. Nakamoto, Satoshi. 2008. “Bitcoin: A Peer-to-Peer Electronic Cash System.” https://bitcoin. org/bitcoin.pdf. Nicholson, Sibel. 2018. “EU Opens Blockchain Observatory, Looking to Invest up to €340 Million.” Interesting Engineering, February 2. https://interestingengineering.com/eu- opens-blockchain-observatory-looking-to-invest-up-to-340-million. Perper, Rosie. 2018. “Iceland May Use More Electricity Mining Bitcoin than Powering Homes This Year.” BusinessInsider, February 12. http://www.businessinsider.com/ iceland-bitcoin-mines-are-booming-2018-2. Poon, Joseph, and Thaddeus Dryja. 2016 “The Bitcoin Lightning Network: Scalable Off- Chain Instant Payments.” Lightning Network, January 14. https://lightning.network/ lightning-network-paper.pdf. Popper, Nathaniel. 2018. “As Bitcoin Bubble Loses Air, Frauds and Flaws Rise to Surface.” New York Times, February 5. https://www.nytimes.com/2018/02/05/technology/virtual- currency-regulation.html. Rogoff, Kenneth. 2014. “Costs and Benefits to Phasing Out Paper Currency.” NBER Macroeconomics Annual, vol. 29. http://www.nber.org/chapters/c13431. Rooney, Kate. 2018. “Peter Thiel Is Betting on Bitcoin Because One Cryptocurrency Will Become the ‘Online Equivalent to Gold.’” CNBC, March 15. https://www.cnbc.com/2018/03/15/ peter-thiel-is-betting-on-bitcoin-to-be-the-online-equivalent-to-gold.html. SputnikInternational. 2018. “Cryptocurrency Boom: Armenia Set to Be Home to 50 MW Mining Farm.” February 7. https://sputniknews.com/business/201802071061451274- cryptocurrency-boom-armenia-mining-farm/. Truman, Edwin M. 2013. “Asian and European Financial Crises Compared.” WP13-9, Peterson Institute for International Economics, Washington, DC. https://piie.com/ publications/wp/wp13-9.pdf. UNDP (United Nations Development Programme). 2018. The Future Is Decentralised: Block Chains, Distributed Ledgers, & The Future of Sustainable Development. New York. https:// www.blockchain.com/assets/pdf/TheFutureisDecentralised.pdf. Young, Joseph. 2017. “Why the EU Is Investing $540,000 in Blockchain Development and Pilot Test.” BTCmanager.com, May 1. https://btcmanager.com/why-eu-is-investing- 540000-in-blockchain-development-and-pilot-test/. PART II Selected Country Pages Selected Country Pages ●  53 pick up. The poverty rate (measured as ALBANIA Recent developments US$ 5.5/day, 2011 PPP) is estimated to have decreased in 2017 to 32.8 percent, compared to 33.9 percent in 2016. Labor Albania’s real GDP grew by 3.8 percent force participation of women, particularly in 2017, up from 3.4 percent in 2016. Key young women, has started to decline Table 1 2017 drivers were private investment and con- throughout 2017, a trend that needs to be P o pulatio n, millio n 2.9 sumption. Investment dynamics reflected closely monitored to avoid reversing pre- GDP , current US$ billio n 12.5 two large energy projects financed by vious gains. GDP per capita, current US$ 4297 FDI (the Trans -Adriatic Pipeline and a Fiscal policy supported a reduction of Internatio nal po verty rate ($ 1.9) a 0.9 hydropower plant). Private consumption public debt, but the pace of fiscal consoli- Lo wer middle-inco me po verty rate ($ 3.2) a 6.6 was supported by a recovery in employ- dation slowed in 2017. The 2017 fiscal defi- a 34.7 ment, wages and credit. Public consump- cit is estimated at 2 percent of GDP, slight- Upper middle-inco me po verty rate ($ 5.5) a tion made a small contribution to ly above the deficit of 1.8 percent in 2016. Gini co efficient 32.1 b growth, reflecting growth of the public - Revenue gains, from increased economic Scho o l enro llment, primary (% gro ss) 113.7 b sector wages. High tourism exports and activity and the recovery of commodity Life expectancy at birth, years 78.2 recovering commodity exports more than prices, were estimated at an additional 0.9 Source: WDI, M acro Poverty Outlook, and official data. compensated for the high investment - percent of GDP in comparison to 2016. On Notes: (a) M ost recent value (2012), 2011 PPPs. related imports of machineries and the expenditure side, under-execution of (b) M ost recent WDI value (2015). equipment as well as for the drought - public investments and lower interest related energy imports. expenditures partially compensated Growth stimulated job creation. Employ- drought-related emergency support to the ment grew by 2.9 percent in the first three electricity sector and higher local govern- Growth is estimated to have strengthened quarters of 2017, following a strong ex- ments spending. Prudent fiscal policy at 3.8 percent in 2017 supported by in- pansion of 6.5 percent in 2016. Labor force supported the public debt decline to 71 vestments and is projected to moderate to participation increased to 58 percent, up percent of GDP in 2017, compared to 72.4 by 0.4 percentage points year-on-year. percent in 2016. 3.6 percent in 2018 as large FDI-financed Besides improved employment prospects, The Bank of Albania’s (BoA) policy stance energy projects wind down; growth will the increase in labor force participation continues to be accommodative and credit be driven by household consumption, and may reflect the Government’s anti- growth recovers. Average inflation picked a pickup in exports. Growth created jobs, informality campaign – including in- up to 2 percent in 2017, but remained be- creased audits and higher penalties for low the BoA’s 3 percent target, prompting contributing to poverty reduction. Public non-compliance. The unemployment rate no changes in the policy rate, which re- debt declined in 2017, but the pace of declined by 1.7 pp to an average of 13.9 mains at 1.25 percent since May 2016. Un- fiscal consolidation slowed. Fiscal consol- percent in the first three quarters of 2017. derlying price pressures have remained idation, improvement in spending effi- Real wages in the formal employment subdued, helped by an appreciation of the ciency, and implementation of structural have started to pick up in 2017 in con- national currency relative to the euro by 1.7 struction, energy, and tourism. percent in 2017. The restructuring of NPLs reforms remain critical to fostering confi- Poverty is estimated to have declined as from large borrowers and mandatory write dence and growth. growth and employment continued to -offs led to a decline in the NPL ratio to 13.2 FIGURE 1 Albania / Real GDP growth and contributions to FIGURE 2 Albania / Actual and projected poverty rates and real GDP growth real private consumption per capita Percent, percentage points Poverty rate (%) Private consumption per capita (constant LCU) 7 60 250000 6 5 50 4 200000 3 2 40 1 150000 0 30 -1 100000 -2 20 -3 -4 50000 -5 10 Q1 -10 Q1 -11 Q1 -12 Q1 -13 Q1 -14 Q1 -15 Q1 -16 Q1 - 17 Net taxes Other services 0 0 Information and communication Trade autorepair and transport 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020 Construction Manifacturing Extractives Agriculture International poverty rate Lower middle-income pov. rate GDP Upper middle-income pov. rate Consumption pc Sources: Instat, Bank staff calculations. Sources: World Bank. Notes: See Table 2. MPO 40 Apr 18 54  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 percent of total loans as of December 2017. energy FDI projects winds down and eco- over the medium term, it has also an- Low interest rates, progress in dealing with nomic activity increases to close to poten- nounced sizable investments financed NPLs and economic growth stimulated an tial, growth will moderate. Growth will be through public private partnerships increase of private sector credit issuance by increasingly relying on private consump- (PPPs) to be contracted starting from 2018. 13.5 percent in 2017. tion, supported by improved labor market The current account deficit widened in conditions, and net exports supported by 2017. The current account deficit is esti- mated to have widened, reaching 8 per- improved foreign demand. Investment will continue to support growth, reflecting Risks and challenges cent of GDP in 2017. FDI-related invest- a public investment drive to reduce infra- ments in the energy sector and drought- structure gaps and private investment, Economic prospects are vulnerable to related electricity imports increased im- reflecting structural reforms and improve- downside risks. Given high public debt, ports. Tourism and commodity prices ments in the business climate. Labor mar- the government needs to implement fiscal increased the value of exports. The result- ket improvements will support private consolidation and strengthen tax compli- ing financing needs were covered by sig- consumption. Poverty is expected to de- ance to preserve the macro-fiscal stability nificant FDI inflows. With much of the cline from 31.3 percent in 2018 to 29.5 per- as a foundation for growth. The Govern- financing coming through FDIs, external cent in 2019. ment needs to strengthen its PPP manage- debt declined by 2 percentage points Sustained fiscal consolidation and struc- ment framework to contain fiscal risks reaching 70.4 percent of GDP in 2017. For- tural reforms are expected to gradually from PPPs and to ensure that investment eign exchange reserves have remained reduce the fiscal deficit to 1.5 percent of is cost-effective. Harnessing growth will stable, covering 6 ½ months of imports of GDP by 2020, and the debt-to-GDP ratio require progress on structural reforms goods and services. to 60 percent of GDP by 2022. Under the improving the business climate - includ- Government medium term fiscal frame- ing judiciary, financial and energy reform work, fiscal consolidation will continue -, strengthening the skills of its labor force Outlook until 2021 – lowering expenditures on personnel, operational and maintenance, - and removing barriers to jobs for the population. Lower than expected growth social outlays and local governments. On in trading partners and higher global in- Growth is projected to moderate to 3.6 the revenue side, the introduction of a terest rates are also key risks for Albania ’s percent in 2018, as two large FDI projects newly valued property tax in 2018 is ex- growth and public finances. Reforms in the energy sector wind down, and then pected to yield additional revenues. While should be informed by equity considera- average 3.5 percent in the period 2019-20. the government is planning sustained tions to ensure continued poverty reduc- As the demand stimulus from the large capital expenditures at 5 percent of GDP tion and inclusion. TABLE 2 Albania / Macro poverty outlook indicators (annual percent change unless indicated otherwise) 2015 2016 2017 e 2018 f 2019 f 2020 f Real GDP growth, at constant market prices 2.2 3.4 3.8 3.6 3.5 3.5 Private Consumption 1.1 2.9 1.7 2.7 2.7 3.5 Government Consumption -1.1 3.8 2.3 1.2 0.4 0.6 Gross Fixed Capital Investment 4.0 6.0 6.8 3.5 3.1 1.9 Exports, Goods and Services 1.0 13.0 7.5 6.5 6.5 6.3 Imports, Goods and Services -2.9 7.4 5.7 4.8 4.8 4.9 Real GDP growth, at constant factor prices 3.1 3.4 3.7 3.6 3.5 3.5 Agriculture 0.8 0.7 0.8 1.5 1.8 1.8 Industry 5.1 3.2 3.5 3.6 4.2 4.2 Services 3.4 5.1 5.5 4.9 4.0 4.1 Inflation (Consumer Price Index) 1.9 0.9 2.0 2.1 2.3 2.8 Current Account Balance (% of GDP) -7.8 -6.8 -8.0 -7.1 -6.9 -6.7 Financial and Capital Account (% of GDP) 6.4 5.6 6.8 5.9 5.7 5.5 Net Foreign Direct Investment (% of GDP) 8.0 8.7 9.4 8.5 7.0 6.5 Fiscal Balance (% of GDP) -4.9 -1.8 -2.0 -2.0 -1.6 -1.4 Debt (% of GDP) 73.1 72.4 71.0 69.0 66.6 64.3 Primary Balance (% of GDP) -2.2 0.7 0.2 0.1 0.9 1.1 International poverty rate ($1.9 in 2011 PPP) a,b 0.8 0.8 0.7 0.7 0.6 0.5 Lower middle-income poverty rate ($3.2 in 2011 PPP) a,b 6.5 5.8 5.6 5.1 4.7 4.2 Upper middle-income poverty rate ($5.5 in 2011 PPP) a,b 35.4 33.9 32.8 31.3 29.5 27.2 So urce: Wo rld B ank, P o verty & Equity and M acro eco no mics, Trade & Investment Glo bal P ractices. No tes: e = estimate, f = fo recast. (a) Calculatio ns based o n ECA P OV harmo nizatio n, using 201 2-LSM S. No wcast: 201 5 - 2017. Fo recast are fro m 2018 to 2020. (b) P ro jectio n using neutral distributio n (2012) with pass-thro ugh = 0.87 based o n private co nsumptio n per capita in co nstant LCU. MPO 41 Apr 18 Selected Country Pages ●  55 The fiscal deficit narrowed slightly in ARMENIA Recent developments 2017, to 4.7 percent of GDP (down from 5.5 percent in 2016), but remained wider than the budgeted deficit of 2.8 percent of Armenia's economic performance outper- GDP. While tax revenue increased by 7.3 formed expectations in 2017, recording the percent year on year in 2017—driven by Table 1 2017 highest rate of growth since 2007. Follow- higher collections of excise taxes, customs P o pulatio n, millio n 3.0 ing a flat economic performance in 2016, duties and environmental taxes—as a per- GDP , current US$ billio n 11.6 real GDP expanded by 7.5 percent, mainly centage of GDP revenue declined by 0.8 GDP per capita, current US$ 3813 driven by a recovery in the external envi- percentage points compared with 2016. Internatio nal po verty rate ($ 1.9) a 1.8 ronment. Growth was also supported by Capital expenditure rose by 36 percent Lo wer middle-inco me po verty rate ($ 3.2) a 14.1 a strong rebound in domestic demand. year on year in nominal terms, but tight a 43.5 Consumption benefited from higher in- control over current spending resulted in Upper middle-inco me po verty rate ($ 5.5) a comes—buoyed by a boost to remittance a decline of 1.6 percentage points in over- Gini co efficient 32.5 b inflows of about 12 percent year on year all expenditure as a share of GDP. At the Scho o l enro llment, primary (% gro ss) 98.5 b and nominal average wage growth of 3 end of 2017, public debt (including CBA Life expectancy at birth, years 74.2 percent—which also benefited poor and debt) totaled almost 59 percent of GDP. Source: WDI, M acro Poverty Outlook, and official data. vulnerable households. The current account deficit continued to Notes: (a) M ost recent value (2016), 2011 PPPs. On the production side, growth was driv- narrow for a third consecutive year and is (b) M ost recent WDI value (2015). en by a significant expansion in trade (16 estimated to have fallen to under 2 per- percent), industry (10 percent) and ser- cent of GDP in 2017. The improvement in vices (9 percent). Also the construction the current account was driven by a sector showed modest growth (3 percent), strong increase in export earnings (up 25 but output remains below its pre-crisis percent year on year)—particularly from Firming international metal prices, eco- level of 2008. The agriculture sector minerals and processed food products— nomic recovery in Russia, and stronger shrunk (by 4 percent), due to unfavorable robust growth in tourist arrivals and ex- domestic demand supported a real GDP weather conditions. ports of other services (such as ICT), and A period of deflation came to an end in improvement in the income account. The growth rate of 7.5 percent in 2017, the 2017 and inflation began rising, reaching strong inflows were partially offset by a largest annual expansion in a decade. an annual rate of 2.6 percent by year-end, significant increase in import spending Growth in the medium term is projected within the central bank's inflation target of (28 percent year on year), a large share of to converge towards its potential of 4 percent (+/- 1.5 percentage points). Re- which comprised capital imports linked around 4 percent, accompanied by a con- covering domestic demand, gradually to investment. rising commodity prices and excise tax Banking sector performance remained tinued (albeit gradual) decline in the pov- hikes resulted in higher prices for food, solid, with a capital adequacy ratio of just erty rate. However, external vulnerabili- beverages, cigarettes, and transport, under 20 percent on average at end-2017, ties and delayed structural reforms could affecting the purchasing power of poor well above the minimum requirement of undermine economic growth. and vulnerable groups, which traditional- 12 percent. At the end of 2017, the non- ly spend a higher share of their budget on performing loan ratio stood at 5.5 percent, these items. its lowest level since the 2014 Russian FIGURE 1 Armenia / GDP growth, fiscal, and current FIGURE 2 Armenia / Actual and projected poverty rates and account balance real private consumption per capita Percent, percentage points Poverty rate (%) Private consumption per capita (constant LCU) 8 100 2000000 4 80 1500000 60 0 1000000 40 -4 500000 20 Real GDP growth, % change -8 CAB, % of GDP 0 0 Fiscal balance, % of GDP 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017 2019 -12 International poverty rate Lower middle-income pov. rate 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 Upper middle-income pov. rate Consumption pc Sources: National Statistics Service of Armenia, Central Bank of Armenia and Source: World Bank (see notes to Table 2). World Bank staff projections. MPO 42 Apr 18 56  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 crisis. Dollarization ratios for bank depos- communication technology (ICT), and partners—as well as its low level of ex- its and loans declined slightly but re- tourism sectors are expected to deliver port diversification —will remain high. mained high at around 60 percent. Total solid growth as efforts to boost competi- Adverse shocks linked to the Russian lending grew by 10 percent, while the tiveness and connectivity start to deliver recovery or metal export prices would Dram lending rate fell by 260 basis points results. As the economy continues to grow have a negative impact on economic over the course of 2017. and incomes rise—and remittance inflows growth rates over the near to medium The economic recovery in 2017 is expected continue to support livelihoods thanks to term. Fiscal slippage could trigger the to have supported a further reduction in a benign external environment—the abso- need for sharper adjustments in public poverty rates, which have been on a de- lute poverty rate is forecast to decline to spending, undermining domestic demand clining trend since the global economic 8.1 percent in 2020. and real economic activity. Fiscal policy crisis. The absolute poverty rate Although price pressures are forecast to should remain prudent to contain public (measured at the 2011 PPP-adjusted increase in the short term, mainly due to debt levels. Avoiding fiscal procyclicality US$3.2/day poverty line) is estimated to higher customs duties and excise taxes on will help prevent macroeconomic imbal- have fallen from 14.1 percent in 2016 to fuels starting in 2018, inflation is projected ances and reduce the risks associated 11.6 percent in 2017. to remain within the official target range. with overheating (including potential The new Tax Code, which becomes fully competitiveness losses) during periods of effective in 2018, lays the foundation for strong economic growth. Continuing co- Outlook better tax administration and higher tax revenues. Implementation of the upgrad- ordination with the monetary authorities and the maintenance of a flexible ex- ed fiscal rule (approved in December change rate will be vital to avoid episodes Armenia's economic outlook remains pos- 2017) will result in stronger discipline for of real exchange rate appreciation that itive. The strong performance in 2017 sug- current spending and will provide some can lead to losses in competitiveness. gests the opening of a window of oppor- room to increase growth-friendly capital Sustaining robust economic growth will tunity to undertake the reforms needed to expenditures while also stabilizing and require bold structural reforms—such as make growth inclusive and sustainable. eventually reducing the public debt. providing a fair and competitive business On the assumption of sustained favorable and investment environment—to address external economic conditions and robust fundamental problems in Armenia's econ- structural reforms, medium-term growth is forecast to be around the potential Risks and challenges omy. Increasing country-wide access to economic opportunities will help to boost growth rate (4 percent), supported by pri- household incomes and drive a further vate-sector, export-led activity. In particu- Armenia’s vulnerability to economic con- reduction in poverty, particularly in sec- lar, the agribusiness, information and ditions in Russia and its other trading ondary cities where poverty is highest. TABLE 2 Armenia / Macro poverty outlook indicators (annual percent change unless indicated otherwise) 2015 2016 2017 e 2018 f 2019 f 2020 f Real GDP growth, at constant market prices 3.2 0.2 7.5 4.1 4.0 4.0 Private Consumption -7.8 -1.3 8.8 5.0 4.7 4.5 Government Consumption 4.7 4.1 9.8 4.3 3.7 3.5 Gross Fixed Capital Investment 2.5 -11.4 7.3 4.5 4.2 4.1 Exports, Goods and Services 4.9 19.1 23.2 10.1 9.8 9.5 Imports, Goods and Services -15.1 7.6 24.0 10.3 9.5 8.9 Real GDP growth, at constant factor prices 4.3 0.7 7.2 4.1 4.0 4.0 Agriculture 13.2 -5.8 -4.0 2.5 2.7 2.4 Industry 2.8 -0.9 8.0 5.4 5.2 5.1 Services 2.1 4.0 10.5 3.9 3.8 3.9 Inflation (Consumer Price Index) 3.7 -1.4 1.0 3.5 3.8 4.0 Current Account Balance (% of GDP) -2.6 -2.3 -1.7 -2.9 -3.5 -3.8 Financial and Capital Account (% of GDP) 4.0 4.5 1.4 2.9 3.5 3.8 Net Foreign Direct Investment (% of GDP) 1.5 2.6 4.1 4.4 4.5 4.7 Fiscal Balance (% of GDP) -4.8 -5.5 -4.7 -2.6 -2.5 -2.3 Debt (% of GDP) 48.7 56.6 58.8 58.6 58.3 57.5 Primary Balance (% of GDP) -3.0 -3.6 -2.7 -0.5 -0.3 0.0 International poverty rate ($1.9 in 2011 PPP) a,b 1.9 1.8 1.4 1.3 1.0 0.8 Lower middle-income poverty rate ($3.2 in 2011 PPP) a,b 13.5 14.1 11.6 10.1 9.1 8.1 Upper middle-income poverty rate ($5.5 in 2011 PPP) a,b 48.3 43.5 39.9 38.2 36.8 35.2 So urce: Wo rld B ank, P o verty & Equity and M acro eco no mics, Trade & Investment Glo bal P ractices. No tes: e = estimate, f = fo recast. (a) Calculatio ns based o n ECA P OV harmo nizatio n, using 201 6-ILCS. A ctual data: 2015, 2016. No wcast: 2017. Fo recast are fro m 2018 to 2020. (b) P ro jectio n using neutral distributio n (2016) with pass-thro ugh = 0.7 based o n private co nsumptio n per capita in co nstant LCU. MPO 43 Apr 18 Selected Country Pages ●  57 y/y, led by a rise in oil exports, as oil pric- AZERBAIJAN Recent developments es recovered (oil exports accounted for 90 percent of total exports), while imports rebounded by 3 percent y/y (compared to The Azerbaijani economy had a very mod- a drop in 2016). Non-oil exports increased est recovery in 2017, as a rebound in the by 22 percent y/y, supported by stronger Table 1 2017 non-oil economy was offset by a contrac- external demand, mainly from Russia. The P o pulatio n, millio n 9.9 tion in the oil sector due to substantial current account recorded an estimated GDP , current US$ billio n 40.7 OPEC-led cuts in oil production and ca- surplus of 4.3 percent of GDP in 2017. GDP per capita, current US$ 4128 pacity constraints. In particular, the non- The tightening monetary policy, improved Scho o l enro llment, primary (% gro ss) a 106.6 oil sector rebounded by 2.7 percent year- external environment, and transfers from Life expectancy at birth, years a 71.8 on-year (y/y), supported by benign public the Oil Fund to the central bank helped to financing, stronger external demand, and maintain a broadly stable exchange rate at Source: WDI, M acro Poverty Outlook, and official data. Notes: improved confidence in response to recov- 1.7 AZN per USD in 2017. As a result, the ering oil prices. With the exception of the central bank’s reserves increased by 34 (a) M ost recent WDI value (2015). construction sector, output increased in all percent y/y in 2017 and totaled US$5.3 non-oil sectors with strong y/y growth billion by end-2017. The Oil Fund’s assets recorded in transport (8.5 percent), infor- rose by 8.02 percent y/y and totaled US$ mation and communication technologies 35.8 billion (about 87% of GDP) in January (6.6 percent), tourism (5.9 percent) and 2018, mainly due to higher oil prices and a agriculture (4.2 percent). On the down- portfolio revaluation. Azerbaijan’s economy had a very modest side, and despite higher oil prices, oil GDP In June 2017, the Government of Azerbai- recovery in 2017. Benign public financ- contracted by 5 percent y/y. jan (GoA) relaxed its fiscal consolidation ing, improved confidence, and a favorable Annual end-year inflation declined from program, and public spending was re- external environment supported non-oil 15.6 percent in 2016 to 7.9 percent in 2017, vised up to primarily inject capital equiva- as the effect of the exchange rate pass- lent to 0.7 percent of GDP in the Azerbai- economic growth, but this was offset by through and the impact of administrative jan Deposit Insurance Fund1. Higher an OPEC-led decline in oil production. tariffs dissipated. The high inflation rate budget spending is estimated to have wid- Going forward, growth is expected to recorded for food items (9.4 percent y/y) ened the consolidated fiscal deficit strengthen, driven mainly by a fiscal was due to a strong external demand for (comprising State Budget, the Oil Fund, agricultural products. To curb inflation, the Social Protection Fund and the Na- stimulus, a rise in hydrocarbon prices, the central bank continued to tighten the khchivan Government) from a nearly bal- and an increase in gas exports. Social monetary policy stance by actively absorb- anced position in 2016 to a deficit of 1.5 conditions remain a major source of con- ing manat liquidity through the use of percent of GDP in 2017. cern, as real wages and spending on social deposit auction operations and the issu- There were signs of recovery in Azerbai- ance of notes. jan’s financial sector in 2017, supported by protection programs declined in 2017. Higher oil prices, sluggish import growth, the stabilization of the manat exchange and expanded non-oil exports helped to rate and growth across the non-oil sectors. improve Azerbaijan’s balance of payments The level of non-performing loans is re- in 2017. Exports expanded by 50 percent ported to have dropped from 33 percent FIGURE 1 Azerbaijan / Non-oil sectors influenced by FIGURE 2 Azerbaijan / Official poverty rate oil price Percent Percent Percent 12 40 49.0 50 46.7 44.7 10 30 45 40.2 8 20 40 10 Poverty headcount ratio at national line 6 35 0 29.3 4 30 -10 2 25 -20 20.8 0 20 -30 15.8 -2 13.2 -40 15 10.9 9.1 -4 -50 10 7.6 6.0 5.3 5.0 4.9 5.9 -6 -60 5 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 0 Non-oil GDP growth, y/y % Oil price, y/y % (RHS) Source: State Statistical Committee. Source: State Statistical Committee. Notes: The official national poverty rates for 2013 -16 have not been reviewed by the World Bank. MPO 44 Apr 18 58  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 in 1Q2016 to 19 percent in 4Q2017, thanks the Shah-Deniz II field will be operational and enhanced government support to to the restructuring (largely at fiscal cost). by end-2018. Since the OPEC-deal is ex- exporters of non-oil products. However, The restructuring of the largest bank — tended until the end of 2018, Azerbaijan’s spending cuts on social protection, as well the state-owned International Bank of crude oil output is not expected to decline as a moderate economic recovery, are not Azerbaijan (IBA)—was completed. IBA’s much further. Moreover, average oil pric- conducive to poverty reduction. external liabilities worth US$3.3 billion es will firm up somewhat in 2018 relative were converted into longer-term liabilities to 2017 and are projected to stabilize at and the sovereign debt. High inflation adversely affected house- robust levels in the medium term. Non-oil GDP growth is expected to accelerate in Risks and challenges hold incomes and reduced the real pur- 2018, fueled by an 83-percent y/y increase chasing power. In 2017, the increase in the in budgeted public investment. Neverthe- Following the recovery in oil prices after minimal cost of living and nominal aver- less, growth in the non-oil economy is the 2014-16 shock, the likelihood of a pro- age wages by 11.6 percent y/y and 6 per- expected to remain moderate due to a cyclical economic policy rather than eco- cent y/y, respectively, was not sufficient to protracted recovery of the banking sector nomic reforms to stimulate growth is ris- compensate for higher prices. As a result, and a weak business environment. ing. The main challenge is to preserve the poverty likely increased in 2017 and was The GoA plans a fiscal stimulus in 2018 reform momentum induced by the shock probably worsened by the 50-percent cut through boosting capital spending, which and strengthen institutions to ensure the in the coverage of the country’s most im- will be primarily financed by an increase resilience of the economy to future exter- portant social assistance program. in budget transfers from the sovereign nal shocks. Moreover, progress on the wealth fund. The consolidated fiscal bal- structural reform agenda to stimulate pri- ance is likely to be slightly positive in 2018 vate-sector participation and jobs creation Outlook and is estimated to average 1.3 percent of GDP in the medium term, as oil prices remains limited. An adaptive and effective social protection system and programs remain firm and gas exports rise. aimed at productive inclusion of poor and Azerbaijan’s economy is projected to ex- To contain inflation, the central bank vulnerable households are needed to re- pand by 1.8 percent y/y in 2018, support- needs to continue tightening monetary duce poverty. ed mainly by the fiscal stimulus. The policy. Azerbaijan’s external sector is ex- growth is expected to accelerate in the pected to continue to improve due to an medium term, driven by an expansion of increase in hydrocarbon production and a natural gas production, as the main pipe- continuation of non-oil export growth, 1/ ADIF was established in 2007 to protect individual line that will deliver gas to Europe from supported by a rise in external demand deposits when banks are closed. TABLE 2 Azerbaijan / Macro poverty outlook indicators (annual percent change unless indicated otherwise) 2015 2016 2017 e 2018 f 2019 f 2020 f Real GDP growth, at constant market prices 1.1 -3.1 0.1 1.8 3.8 3.2 Private Consumption 5.4 -2.8 2.7 3.2 3.3 3.4 Government Consumption -7.1 -8.1 1.8 3.0 0.3 -0.7 Gross Fixed Capital Investment -8.7 -20.0 -5.0 2.5 4.5 4.4 Exports, Goods and Services -1.0 -2.0 -1.1 0.3 4.0 3.5 Imports, Goods and Services -5.0 -10.0 0.2 2.2 2.4 2.8 Real GDP growth, at constant factor prices 1.0 -3.1 0.1 1.8 3.8 3.2 Agriculture 6.6 2.6 4.2 4.0 4.1 4.2 Industry -2.0 -4.9 -2.8 -0.1 3.2 2.7 Services 6.9 -0.3 5.4 5.0 4.8 4.0 Inflation (Consumer Price Index) 7.7 15.6 7.9 6.4 4.2 3.9 Current Account Balance (% of GDP) -0.4 -3.6 4.3 5.9 7.2 7.9 Financial and Capital Account (% of GDP) -16.8 -7.2 -4.3 -5.9 -7.2 -7.9 Net Foreign Direct Investment (% of GDP) 3.2 3.2 2.8 2.6 2.3 2.1 Fiscal Balance (% of GDP) -6.2 0.3 -1.5 0.4 1.4 2.1 Primary Balance (% of GDP) -5.5 1.0 -0.4 1.7 2.3 2.7 So urce: Wo rld B ank, P o verty & Equity and M acro eco no mics, Trade & Investment Glo bal P ractices. No tes: e = estimate, f = fo recast. Fiscal acco unts are calculated using Glo bal Eco no mic P ro spects o il pro jectio ns. MPO 45 Apr 18 Selected Country Pages ●  59 budget surplus has been spent on repay- BELARUS Recent developments ment and servicing public debt in foreign currency, which amounted to US$3.26 billion, or 6.9 percent of GDP. The modest cyclical expansion continues, Pressures were partially eased by the dis- supported by improving external condi- bursement of the two tranches of the Table 1 2017 tions and recovery in industry. In 2017, EFSD loan (totaling US$600 million), dis- P o pulatio n, millio n 9.4 the economy grew at 2.4 percent y/y, a bursement of a bilateral loan from Russia GDP , current US$ billio n 57.0 rebound from the contraction of (US$700 million), and the issuance of Eu- GDP per capita, current US$ 6039 2.5 percent y/y in 2016. Modest economic robonds—US$1.4 billion in 2017, and Upper middle-inco me po verty rate ($ 5.5) a 0.7 growth in Russia and a gradual increase US$0.6 billion in February 2018. Exports Gini co efficient a 27.0 in commodity prices boosted merchandize recovered, helping to bring down the cur- Scho o l enro llment, primary (% gro ss) b 101.3 exports and supported an increase in do- rent account deficit to 1.1 percent of GDP b 73.6 mestic business activity. On the demand in January-November 2017 (vs 3.2 percent Life expectancy at birth, years side, real wage increases helped to in- a year ago), yet driven by the primary Source: WDI, M acro Poverty Outlook, and official data. Notes: crease household consumption by almost income deficit of 4 percent of GDP. (a) M ost recent value (2016), 2011 PPPs. 6 percent in 3Q 2017 (vs. 6.5 percent fall in Real wage increases have stopped the (b) M ost recent WDI value (2015). 3Q 2016). In the same period, growth of deterioration of household incomes. In gross fixed capital formation recovered to 2017, real wages and disposable incomes 1.8 percent – mainly due to rebound of grew by 6.2 and 2.4 percent respectively, public investment – versus the dramatic benefiting from lower inflation. Disposa- fall by 18.9 percent in 3Q 2016. ble incomes growth was the highest in Improving external conditions, stronger In 2017, annual average inflation slowed Minsk, but also in regions with higher to 4.6 percent helped by better anchored absolute poverty rates, such as Brest and domestic demand, and prudent macroeco- inflation expectations, moderation in ad- Gomel. The hires-to-terminations ratio nomic policies supported a cyclical recov- ministrative price adjustments, and im- throughout 2017 exceeded that of 2016 by ery in 2017 and early 2018. Real incomes ported disinflation. Moderating inflation an average of 12 percent. The share of started to pick up, but accelerated wage has allowed the National Bank to cut its households below the official poverty benchmark rate from 17 to 10.5 percent threshold remained stable throughout the growth, along with other fiscal stimulus, during 2017, leading to an almost twofold first three quarters of 2017. could pose risks to macro stability. Rising reduction in nominal lending rates in na- public debt levels and continued depend- tional currency. As a result, supply of new ence on external financing make the econ- credit in nominal terms went up by almost 30 percent y/y. However, NPL levels re- Outlook omy vulnerable to macroeconomic shocks. main at around 13 percent and a compre- The revival of economic growth requires hensive NPL resolution mechanism is still While the recovery is underway, annual addressing structural bottlenecks imped- not put in place. economic growth rates are unlikely to ex- ing productivity improvements. Quasi-fiscal expenditures continue to put ceed 3 percent. Improved household con- pressures on public debt levels and exter- sumption and investment activity, along nal financing needs. Recorded primary with gradual increase in exports, will help FIGURE 1 Belarus / Real GDP growth and contributions to FIGURE 2 Belarus / Actual and projected poverty rates and real GDP growth real GDP per capita Percentage points Poverty rate (%) GDP per capita (constant LCU) 15 60 2500000 10 50 2000000 5 0 40 1500000 -5 30 -10 1000000 20 -15 Q1/14 Q3/14 Q1/15 Q3/15 Q1/16 Q3/16 Q1/17 Q3/17 500000 10 Total consumption of goods and services Gross capital formation Exports of goods and services 0 0 Imports of goods and services 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017 2019 Statistical discrepancy GDP growth Upper middle-income pov. rate GDP pc Sources: World Bank Staff Calculations based on Belstat data. Sources: World Bank. Notes: see Table 2. MPO 46 Apr 18 60  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 the economy to grow. At the same time, is likely to remain close to a half of GDP in public debt repayments and service (or persisting domestic structural bottlenecks the medium term. Majority of gross exter- about 5.4 percent of forecasted GDP), related to unaddressed legacy issues of nal debt pertains to the public sector and is while domestic obligations of the Govern- misallocation of capital and low export characterized by a heavy and uneven debt ment denominated in foreign currency diversification will continue to constrain service profile with repayment peaks every add another US$0.7 billion (or about 1.2 the growth potential. Weak foundations few years. As the public debt is largely percent of GDP). for a sustainable growth recovery imply denominated in foreign currency, there is a Downside risks from domestic factors that income per capita gaps between Bela- risk of disorderly adjustment in external relate to a possibility of a disorderly un- rus and its neighbors may widen as the imbalance due to tightening of global fi- winding of financial sector imbalances if economies of the Baltic States and Poland nancial conditions. Second, Belarus re- mechanisms for addressing insolvent are projected to grow on average above mains vulnerable to changes in global com- SOEs and NPL resolution are not put in 3 percent per annum. At the same time, modity prices and in terms of its energy place. In addition, there are risks to fiscal modest growth would ease balance-of- trade policy with Russia. sustainability arising from existing quasi- payment pressures, allowing to maintain a Either of these developments would make fiscal deficits related to the excesses of the current account deficit between 2 and it harder for the government to generate expansionary policies of the past. Reintro- 3percent of GDP over the next three years. the foreign currency needed to service its duction of short-term demand stimulus is debt. Belarus’s experience with the 2017 risky, leaving little prospects for improv- Eurobond issuance indicates that access to ing enterprise performance and strength- Risks and challenges external market financing – in contrast to loans from Russia and China – comes at a ening of financing sector. The effects of lower interest rates are limited, as highly high cost. A ten-year, US$0.6 billion indebted enterprises are unable to invest Downside risks from external factors are tranche was priced at 7.625 percent, high- more. Boosting productivity of available coming from two sources. First, although er rates than the ones obtained by emerg- capital and labor remains a sustainable the headline current account deficits have ing economies. In 2018, the Government way to overcome prolonged stagnation of narrowed down, a public debt to GDP ratio will allocate US$3.1 billion for external growth and incomes. TABLE 2 Belarus / Macro poverty outlook indicators (annual percent change unless indicated otherwise) 2015 2016 2017 e 2018 f 2019 f 2020 f Real GDP growth, at constant market prices -3.8 -2.5 2.4 2.9 2.7 2.5 Private Consumption -2.3 -3.9 2.5 3.0 3.1 3.1 Government Consumption -0.5 -0.6 1.3 0.8 1.3 1.3 Gross Fixed Capital Investment -15.5 -16.1 9.9 6.5 5.6 5.2 Exports, Goods and Services 2.1 2.8 7.5 7.2 8.3 8.9 Imports, Goods and Services -10.6 -2.1 9.2 8.0 8.7 9.1 Real GDP growth, at constant factor prices -4.6 -2.9 2.9 2.9 2.7 2.5 Agriculture -2.8 3.8 4.1 4.5 3.9 3.8 Industry -6.8 -4.6 6.1 7.2 8.3 7.7 Services -2.3 -2.8 -1.1 -2.8 -5.1 -5.9 Inflation (Consumer Price Index) 13.5 11.8 4.6 6.0 6.5 6.5 Current Account Balance (% of GDP) -3.3 -3.6 -2.7 -2.9 -3.0 -2.8 Financial and Capital Account (% of GDP) -2.3 -1.7 1.7 2.6 1.4 1.2 Net Foreign Direct Investment (% of GDP) 2.9 2.6 2.4 2.6 2.6 2.3 Fiscal Balance (% of GDP) 2.5 0.1 3.7 2.1 2.1 2.1 Debt (% of GDP) 26.5 43.3 45.9 46.1 46.4 46.8 Primary Balance (% of GDP) 3.7 1.6 6.1 4.7 4.3 3.9 Upper middle-income poverty rate ($5.5 in 2011 PPP) a,b 0.7 0.7 0.6 0.6 0.6 0.5 So urce: Wo rld B ank, P o verty & Equity and M acro eco no mics, Trade & Investment Glo bal P ractices. No tes: e = estimate, f = fo recast. (a) Calculatio ns based o n ECA P OV harmo nizatio n, using 201 6-HHS. A ctual data: 2015, 2016. No wcast: 2017. Fo recast are fro m 2018 to 2020. (b) P ro jectio n using neutral distributio n (2016) with pass-thro ugh = 0.7 based o n GDP per capita in co nstant LCU. MPO 47 Apr 18 Selected Country Pages ●  61 2016. In 2017, revenues rose mainly due BOSNIA AND Recent developments to stronger collection of indirect taxes while expenditure declined mainly be- cause of continued restraint on current HERZEGOVINA Growth reached an estimated 3 percent in 2017. Domestic demand remains the dom- government spending. At the same time, sluggish capital spending reflected imple- inant driver of growth with consumption mentation delays. adding 3pp, investment 0.8 pp and im- Current expenditures are expected to re- Table 1 2017 ports 5.1pp. Improved external demand main on a downward, driven by the com- P o pulatio n, millio n 3.8 has supported exports growth, but a mitment of the authorities to reduce the strong rise in imports is offsetting this wage bill. Total public debt in 2017 re- GDP , current US$ billio n 17.2 momentum. With negative overall net mained at 37 percent of GDP (external GDP per capita, current US$ 4544 a exports, they are estimated to have sub- public debt was 27 percent of GDP) and Scho o l enro llment, primary (% gro ss) n.a. tracted from growth (-0.8 pp). Unem- consisted largely of concessional debt to a Life expectancy at birth, years 76.6 ployment remains high, although some international financial institutions. Source: WDI, M acro Poverty Outlook, and official data. improvements are observed in the labor The latest available poverty data using the Notes: market. The unemployment rate fell from national poverty line is for 2015 and was (a) M ost recent WDI value (2015). 25.4 percent in 2016 to 20.5 in 2017, driven estimated at 16 percent, very close to the by a fall in activity rate and a slight rise in 15 percent poverty rate estimated for 2011. employment. The decrease in unemploy- Rural poverty (19 percent) was higher ment was more pronounced among work- than urban poverty (12 percent). Behind ers with primary education (from 26 per- the minimal movement in poverty in 2011 cent in 2016 to 18 percent in 2017), which -2015 there was a small positive effect of should have made poverty recede in 2017. pensions on household incomes, coun- Economic growth in Bosnia and Herze- After almost two years of deflation, infla- tered mainly by a decrease in employment govina (BiH), which reached an estimated tion started to pick up in 2017, owing rate and a decline in self-employment 3 percent in 2017, is expected to pick-up mainly to the recovery of global oil price. earnings. The implementation of new la- The consumer price index increased by bor laws in both BiH entities, and continu- starting in 2018 with the implementation 1.2 percent year-on-year (y-o-y) in De- ation of support schemes for first-time job of structural reforms and heavy infra- cember 2017. The biggest driver of the seekers are expected to improve labor structure investment. Translating this increase was transport, tobacco and rental markets outcomes in the coming years, growth into improvements in labor mar- housing. In contrast, prices decreased hence also supporting poverty reduction. kets will be critical to observe declines in notably on alcohol, clothing, and telecom- munication services. Given similar poverty. As BiH enters general elections year, political turmoil may be a risk for growth in nominal salaries, the effect on real incomes was neutral. Outlook economic growth. In 2017, the fiscal balance is expected to remain in surplus. The latest consolidated Supported primarily by consumption and data project a 2.0 percent of GDP surplus to some extent by public investment, eco- in 2017, up from a deficit of 0.3 percent in nomic growth is projected to strengthen to FIGURE 1 Bosnia and Herzegovina / Real GDP growth and FIGURE 2 Bosnia and Herzegovina / Labor market contributions to real GDP growth indicators, 2014-2017 Percent, percentage points Percent 5.0 50 43.7 2014 2015 45 42.7 4.0 2016 2017 40 3.0 33.9 35 31.7 2.0 30 27.5 1.0 25 23.5 20.5 0.0 20 16.8 -1.0 15 -2.0 10 5 -3.0 2013 2014 2015 2016f 2017f 2018f 2019f 2020f 0 Activity rate Employment rate Unemployment Unemployment Private_consumption Government_consumption rate rate over 1 year Gross_fixed_investment Net exports duration GDP Sources: BiH Agency for Statistics (BHAS), World Bank staff estimate. Sources: LFS 2014 -2017 report, World Bank staff calculations. MPO 48 Apr 18 62  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 about 4 percent by 2020. As the BiH’s re- poverty is projected to decline only slow- poorly-targeted benefits. Fiscal consolida- form agenda advances, a moderate rise in ly over the next couple of years. tion and provision of an effective safety exports is expected, but strong demand The current account deficit (CAD) is fore- net will not be effective if structural rigidi- for imports implies that net external de- cast to rise slightly in 2018 as both imports ties in spending are not addressed— mand will continue to be a drag on and exports started to pick up in 2017. In especially the high public wage bill. How- growth. Remittances are likely to remain the medium run, with improved progress ever, support from the international part- stable, and, together with progress on on ongoing structural reforms and higher ners can help the BiH authorities to deliv- reforms, will underpin a gradual pickup demand for foreign savings, CAD is ex- er on their challenging reform agenda. in consumption, which will remain a ma- pected to deteriorate from 5.8 percent of Without continued implementation of jor driver of growth. Investments in ener- GDP in 2017 to 6.8 percent of GDP by structural reforms, it would be difficult to gy, construction, and tourism will support 2020. Overall, in the medium term both address rigidities in public employment, investment growth generally, as well as fiscal and external deficits will persist un- pensions, and debt. job creation in those sectors. Because of til 2020. There are notable risks, both domestic and these dynamics, real GDP growth is pro- external. The main domestic risk is the jected to build up gradually from 3 per- challenging political environment, which cent in 2017 to 3.2 percent in 2018 and up to 4 percent in 2020. Risks and challenges makes structural reforms difficult in such areas as infrastructure, telecommunica- As poverty is strongly associated with tions, energy sector, and transport. It also unemployment and inactivity in BiH, for Achieving prudent, efficient, and effective raises risks to the economic outlook. De- economic growth to translate into pov- fiscal policy, addressing persistent unem- spite some delays, BiH has submitted a erty reduction, improvements in labor ployment and continuing to safeguard the detailed Questionnaire to the European market participation and employment banking sector, will remain central to the Commission, a major step towards becom- will remain key. However, with high BiH reform agenda. Although external ing a candidate country. Main external unemployment and the expectations of deficits continue to be moderate, on the risk for BiH remains slow growth in the flat real wages due to the substantial fiscal side the tax burden is high, and pub- EU and rising inflation in developed remaining slack in the labor market , lic spending is inefficient, as evidenced by countries and interest rates. TABLE 2 Bosnia and Herzegovina / Macro poverty outlook indicators (annual percent change unless indicated otherwise) 2015 2016 2017 e 2018 f 2019 f 2020 f Real GDP growth, at constant market prices 3.7 3.1 3.0 3.2 3.4 4.0 Private Consumption 0.4 1.8 3.2 3.4 3.7 3.5 Government Consumption 0.8 1.8 3.6 5.5 6.3 4.2 Gross Fixed Capital Investment 1.0 1.7 3.8 2.5 6.5 4.7 Exports, Goods and Services 6.3 4.1 12.5 9.2 4.7 3.6 Imports, Goods and Services 0.9 1.2 9.9 8.0 6.5 3.3 Real GDP growth, at constant factor prices 3.1 3.1 3.0 3.2 3.4 4.0 Agriculture 9.2 5.0 2.8 3.0 3.0 3.0 Industry 3.4 3.0 2.7 3.0 3.0 3.0 Services 2.3 2.9 3.1 3.4 3.6 4.5 Inflation (Private Consumption Deflator) 1.0 -0.8 1.2 1.4 1.4 1.4 Current Account Balance (% of GDP) -5.7 -4.5 -5.8 -6.2 -6.8 -6.8 Financial and Capital Account (% of GDP) -2.0 -1.4 7.0 7.4 8.1 6.9 Net Foreign Direct Investment (% of GDP) -1.4 -1.6 1.2 2.5 2.8 2.8 Fiscal Balance (% of GDP) 0.6 -0.3 2.0 1.3 0.2 0.0 Debt (% of GDP) 40.6 41.1 36.8 33.3 30.8 29.5 Primary Balance (% of GDP) 1.5 0.8 3.2 2.8 1.4 0.9 So urce: Wo rld B ank, P o verty & Equity and M acro eco no mics, Trade & Investment Glo bal P ractices. No tes: e = estimate, f = fo recast. MPO 49 Apr 18 Selected Country Pages ●  63 ing the deterioration of the trade bal- BULGARIA Recent developments ance and lower EU transfers. At 72.1 percent, the employment rate (20- 64) reached record high levels while unem- Economic growth remained strong in Bul- ployment was close to pre-crisis levels. garia at 3.6 percent in 2017, only slightly However, the working age population Table 1 2017 lower than 3.9 percent in 2016. Consump- continued to shrink constraining the ex- P o pulatio n, millio n 7.1 tion and investment were the main drivers pansion of potential growth. Labor and GDP , current US$ billio n 55.8 of growth while the contribution of net skill shortages as well as rising minimum GDP per capita, current US$ 7887 exports was negative in 2017. Consump- wages pushed overall salaries up about 9 Internatio nal po verty rate ($ 1.9) a 1.0 tion was supported by a dynamic labor percent compared with 2016. Lo wer middle-inco me po verty rate ($ 3.2) a 3.8 market, rising wages, and eased financial Strong labor market conditions supported a 7.5 credit conditions. Investment expanded at continued improvement in poverty reduc- Upper middle-inco me po verty rate ($ 5.5) a a solid rate, despite slow implementation tion. Poverty measured using the Upper Gini co efficient 37.4 b of public investment projects. On the pro- Middle-Income Class line of $5.5 per day Scho o l enro llment, primary (% gro ss) 97.2 b duction side, the greatest contributions to (in 2011 PPP terms) is estimated to have Life expectancy at birth, years 74.5 GDP growth came from manufacturing; declined from 8.5 percent in 2015 to 7.5 Source: WDI, M acro Poverty Outlook, and official data. construction; real estate; trade, transport, percent in 2017 (see Notes to Table 2). Notes: (a) See Notes to Table 2. and tourism. However, income inequality in Bulgaria is (b) M ost recent WDI value (2014). Strong domestic demand and higher ener- the highest in the EU and has been increas- gy and commodity prices pushed inflation ing over the last few years, with the in- up. After three years of deflation, inflation come of the richest 20 percent of the popu- turned positive to 2.1 percent in 2017. lation equal to almost eight times that of Economic growth remained strong in Fiscal performance remained positive on the poorest 20 percent in 2015. The cover- 2017, slightly lower compared with 2016. the back of improved revenue collection age and adequacy of the social transfer and lower than planned public investment system remains low. Unemployment has The employment rate peaked and wages spending. Tax revenues grew by 10 per- declined significantly but regional varia- were pushed up by labor and skill short- cent in 2017 compared with 2016 thanks to tions and long-term and youth unemploy- ages. Output and employment growth strong economic activity, better compli- ment remain high. Inactivity among cer- contributed to a reduction in poverty. ance, higher minimum wages and an in- tain groups of the population persists and Further gains in growth, poverty reduc- crease in the pension contribution rate. many citizens – including the elderly, peo- Like 2016, capital investment was well ple living in rural areas, and the Roma – tion and shared prosperity hinge on the below expectations as implementation of are excluded from economic opportunities. implementation of policies to boost EU funded projects remained slow. In- productivity. Policy areas that require stead of planned deficit of 0.6 percent of attention include strengthening institu- GDP, fiscal accounts were balanced for the second year in a row. Outlook tions, enhancing the skills of the labor The current account surplus narrowed force, and improving the effectiveness to 3.9 percent of GDP in 2017 com- GDP growth is expected to remain robust, and efficiency of public spending. pared with 5.3 percent in 2016 follow- reaching 3.8 percent in 2018. Domestic FIGURE 1 Bulgaria / Real GDP growth and contributions to FIGURE 2 Bulgaria / Actual and projected poverty rates and real GDP growth real GDP per capita Percent, percentage points Poverty rate (%) GDP per capita (constant LCU) 6 25 16000 5 14000 4 20 12000 3 2 15 10000 1 8000 0 10 6000 -1 4000 -2 5 2000 -3 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017e 2018f 2019f 2020f 0 0 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020 Consumption Gross capital formation Change in inventories Net Exports International poverty rate Lower middle-income pov. rate GDP Upper middle-income pov. rate GDP pc Sources: NSI; MFMod, World Bank. Sources: World Bank (see notes to Table 2). MPO 50 Apr 18 64  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 demand will continue to support growth health, public order, and infrastructure labor costs and therefore undermine com- as the expected intensified absorption of could undermine fiscal consolidation and petitiveness. Further acceleration of real EU funds will boost investment, likely limit the potential of public spending to estate prices in large cities could negative- outweighing the negative contribution of enhance growth. ly affect the quality of bank portfolios. net exports. Private consumption is ex- Poverty reduction is expected to continue Upside factors likely to lead to higher- pected to continue expanding thanks to at a modest pace in the near term. Sus- than expected growth are an enhanced tight labor markets and rising real estate tained improvements in employment and economic sentiment in Europe and strong- prices in large cities. Going forward, wages, as well as recent increases in the er global economic activity. GDP growth is projected to moderate to minimum pension, should support real The key challenges for Bulgaria are to 3.6 percent in 2019 and 2020. Domestic incomes and therefore further reductions accelerate convergence with the rest of the demand should remain the driver of in poverty. Poverty is projected to fall EU and to build a more inclusive society. growth with an increasing contribution from 7.5 percent in 2017, as measured at Accelerating convergence requires im- of investment. $5.5 a day in 2011 PPP, to 7.0 percent in provements in productivity and labor The current account balance is likely to 2018, and to 6.3 percent by 2020. force participation as the demographic remain in surplus, but narrow net ex- transition is weighing on the size of the ports will continue to deteriorate and an working age population. Enhancing expected slowdown in EU growth due to higher oil and commodity prices. Risks and challenges productivity growth requires addressing governance challenges (public administra- The fiscal position is likely to weaken tion, judiciary, business environment, slightly in 2018 and 2019, reflecting plans Risks to the projected growth path are governance of SOEs) that have under- for expansion of public investment and broadly balanced. Lower than expected mined Bulgaria’s structural transfor- increasing wages and social assistance European growth could undermine export mation. Enhancing the skills and employ- payments. Strong revenue collection, driv- growth, while tightening global financial ability of all Bulgarians, more effective en by further improvements in compli- market conditions could increase the cost and efficient public spending on health, ance and an increased pension contribu- of lending to the private sector with nega- pensions and long-term care are also tion rate in 2018, is likely to support fiscal tive implications for investment. Continued needed to ensure inclusiveness and sus- consolidation in the medium term. Lack of wage growth at a faster pace than produc- tainability of growth in the face of demo- improvement in spending efficiency in tivity could translate into increasing unit graphic changes. TABLE 2 Bulgaria / Macro poverty outlook indicators (annual percent change unless indicated otherwise) 2015 2016 2017 e 2018 f 2019 f 2020 f Real GDP growth, at constant market prices 3.6 3.9 3.6 3.8 3.6 3.6 Private Consumption 4.5 3.6 4.8 5.2 4.7 4.5 Government Consumption 1.4 2.2 3.2 3.2 1.7 0.8 Gross Fixed Capital Investment 2.7 -6.6 3.8 7.3 6.7 7.2 Exports, Goods and Services 5.7 8.1 4.0 3.9 4.0 4.0 Imports, Goods and Services 5.4 4.5 7.2 5.9 5.4 5.2 Real GDP growth, at constant factor prices 3.0 3.2 3.7 3.8 3.6 3.6 Agriculture -6.8 5.3 -0.1 2.1 1.9 1.9 Industry 3.6 3.2 3.4 3.2 3.5 3.8 Services 3.3 3.1 4.1 4.2 3.7 3.6 Inflation (Consumer Price Index) -0.1 -0.8 2.1 2.1 2.1 2.2 Current Account Balance (% of GDP) 0.0 5.3 3.9 2.3 1.4 0.7 Financial and Capital Account (% of GDP) 4.6 0.5 -3.8 -2.3 -1.3 -0.6 Net Foreign Direct Investment (% of GDP) 5.5 1.4 1.8 2.3 2.3 2.4 Fiscal Balance (% of GDP) -1.6 0.0 0.0 -0.2 -0.2 0.2 Debt (% of GDP) 26.0 29.0 25.6 24.3 23.0 21.4 Primary Balance (% of GDP) -0.7 0.9 1.0 0.7 0.7 1.1 International poverty rate ($1.9 in 2011 PPP) a,b 1.2 1.2 1.0 0.7 0.6 0.6 Lower middle-income poverty rate ($3.2 in 2011 PPP) a,b 3.6 3.6 3.3 3.1 2.9 2.7 Upper middle-income poverty rate ($5.5 in 2011 PPP) a,b 8.5 7.9 7.5 7.0 6.7 6.3 Wo rld So urce:NSI; B ank, B NB Po ; Euro verty stat; Wo & Equity and rld B ank, MM acro acro eco eco no mics no and mics, Trade Fiscal & Investment M anagementGlo balbal Glo P ractice, and P o verty Glo bal P ractice. P ractices. No tes: e = estimate, f = fo recast. (a) Calculatio ns based o n EU-SILC harmo nizatio n, using 201 4-EU-SILC. No wcast: 201 5 - 2017. Fo recast are fro m 201 8 to 2020. (b) P ro jectio n using neutral distributio n (2014) with pass-thro ugh = 0.87 based o n GDP per capita in co nstant LCU. MPO 51 Apr 18 Selected Country Pages ●  65 stronger than expected fall in the govern- CROATIA Recent developments ment’s debt ratio to 80 percent of GDP in 2017, down from 82.7 in 2016. External imbalances narrowed further as GDP growth slowed from 3.2 percent in the current account surplus increased to 2016 to 2.8 percent in 2017. Exports of 3.7 percent of GDP in September 2017 (on Table 1 2017 goods and services was the main driver of a four-quarter basis). This rise is expected P o pulatio n, millio n 4.1 growth in 2017. Tourism recorded excep- to be only temporary, as it reflects a fall in GDP , current US$ billio n 54.9 tional performance with foreign tourist banks’ profits resulting from their expo- GDP per capita, current US$ 13297 nights rising by over 11 percent, and sures to Agrokor Group. External debt (of Lo wer middle-inco me po verty rate ($ 3.2) a 1.3 strong growth of merchandise export con- the public and private sectors) declined to Upper middle-inco me po verty rate ($ 5.5) a 5.8 tinued. Private consumption also made a 84.2 percent of GDP in November 2017, Gini co efficient a 30.8 positive contribution to growth, supported 5.6 percent lower than 2016, as banks and b 98.0 by favorable labor market developments the private corporate sector continued to Scho o l enro llment, primary (% gro ss) b and personal income tax rate cuts. Howev- deleverage. Life expectancy at birth, years 77.3 er, the share of imported durable goods in Employment rose across the board, with Source: WDI, M acro Poverty Outlook, and official data. consumption increased. On balance, the manufacturing, tourism and construction Notes: (a) M ost recent value (2015), 2011 PPPs. effect of net exports on growth turned neg- accounting for more than a half of the (b) M ost recent WDI value (2015). ative. In addition, growth slowed down increase. Together with negative migra- because investment growth decelerated tion flows, this led to a marked decline of markedly. This was mainly due to a weak- the survey-based unemployment rate to er absorption of EU funds, which led to a an estimated 11 percent in 2017, down sharp fall in government investments. from 13.1 percent in 2016. Real net wages Economic growth decelerated to 2.8 per- Following deflationary pressures in 2016, increased by 4.2 percent y-o-y in Decem- cent in 2017 due to a slowdown in gov- prices increased by 1.1 percent y-o-y in ber. The positive wage trends are due the ernment investment and a rebound in 2017 on the back of the recovery of inter- recovery of firms' profitability, labor imports. The poverty rate is projected to national oil and food prices. With inflation shortages in some sectors, a 6-percent rise still subdued, the Croatian National Bank in public sector wages and cuts in the per- have declined to 5.1 percent as disposable (CNB) continued to pursue an expansion- sonal income tax rate. incomes have increased. Strong fiscal con- ary monetary policy throughout 2017. Economic recovery and labor market solidation continued in 2017, leading to a Fiscal consolidation also continued in improvements are now starting to re- further fall in the debt ratio. However, the 2017, with the budget surplus estimated at duce absolute poverty, after increasing 0.1 percent of GDP, down from a deficit of during six subsequent years of economic reform momentum has faltered and, with- 0.9 percent in 2016. The surplus was recession. The poverty rate measured at out addressing substantial economic and achieved by buoyant tax collection and the upper middle -income class poverty institutional weaknesses, prospects for constrained growth in expenditures in line line of $5.5 at 2011 PPP per capita fell reinitiating real convergence and promot- with the November 2017 budget revision. from 7.3 percent in 2013 to 5.8 percent in The combination of a significant primary 2015, which is still higher than the pre - ing inclusive growth are weak. surplus and a small debt reducing interest crisis rate. The poverty rate for 2017 is -rate growth differential resulted in a projected at 5.1 percent, suggesting that FIGURE 1 Croatia / Real GDP growth and contributions to FIGURE 2 Croatia / Actual and projected poverty rates and real GDP growth real GDP per capita Percent, percentage points Poverty rate (%) GDP per capita (constant LCU) 4 8 100000 3 7 2 80000 6 1 5 60000 0 4 -1 40000 3 -2 2 -3 20000 1 -4 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018f 2019f 2020f 0 0 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017 2019 Final consumption Gross fixed capital formation Change in inventories Net exports Lower middle-income pov. rate Upper middle-income pov. rate Residual item GDP growth GDP pc Sources: CROSTAT, World Bank. Sources: World Bank (see notes to Table 2). MPO 52 Apr 18 66  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 the reduction in poverty is slowing down. 2020, leading to a further decline in public goods to GDP growth is expected to stay While real per capita income has returned debt to below 70 percent of GDP. Howev- high, it is exposed to the risk of a slow- to its 2008 level, output is still about 4 er, the overall fiscal stance will become down in external demand from the EU. percent lower than in 2008. Therefore, the moderately pro-cyclical, as the structural Furthermore, the still high level of public rebound in per capita income reflects the budget balance is expected to worsen. debt makes Croatia vulnerable to interest impact of demographic trends. Positive labor market developments are rate shocks and worsening external fi- expected to support the growth of dispos- nancing conditions. Finally, the cyclical able income for all segments of the wel- upturn and the sounder fiscal position Outlook fare distribution. The continued decline in the share of long-term unemployed and may foster continued complacency. The lack of reforms would have an adverse NEETs will reduce the absolute poverty effect on growth over the medium term. Growth is expected to slow further to 2.6 rate further to 4.0 percent in 2020. Croatia’s prospects for improving higher percent in 2018, due to a slowdown in and more inclusive growth remain weak. private consumption as the favorable Currently low potential growth calls for a effects of the tax reform on real wages start to fade. Furthermore, exports of tour- Risks and challenges strong structural reform agenda. Substan- tial economic, social and institutional ist services are expected to slow in 2018, weaknesses should be addressed to boost due to capacity constraints. On the other Risks are slightly skewed to the downside. private sector productivity and competi- hand, better absorption of EU funds will As the operational restructuring of Agro- tiveness, raise the quality of human and give a boost to investment spending. kor Group unfolds in 2018, the negative physical capital and modernize public These trends suggest an average economic effects on investment activity and private services. This would lead to increasing growth of 2.8 percent for 2019 and 2020. consumption might be greater than cur- economic activity and employment, The government balance is expected to rently envisaged. In addition, although which are crucial for a further reduction stay in surplus and may reach 1 percent by the positive contribution of exports of in poverty. TABLE 2 Croatia / Macro poverty outlook indicators (annual percent change unless indicated otherwise) 2015 2016 2017 e 2018 f 2019 f 2020 f Real GDP growth, at constant market prices 2.3 3.2 2.8 2.6 2.7 2.8 Private Consumption 1.1 3.5 3.6 3.0 2.8 2.6 Government Consumption -0.9 1.9 2.0 1.5 1.5 1.6 Gross Fixed Capital Investment 3.8 5.3 3.4 6.4 6.9 7.4 Exports, Goods and Services 9.4 5.6 6.1 5.8 5.0 5.0 Imports, Goods and Services 9.2 6.2 8.1 7.4 6.3 6.4 Real GDP growth, at constant factor prices 2.3 2.8 2.8 2.6 2.7 2.8 Agriculture 1.3 0.6 -2.2 2.2 2.2 2.2 Industry 2.6 4.4 1.3 3.6 2.8 2.8 Services 2.3 2.3 3.6 2.3 2.7 2.8 Inflation (Consumer Price Index) -0.5 -1.0 1.5 1.4 1.4 1.5 Current Account Balance (% of GDP) 4.5 2.6 3.6 2.6 1.7 1.0 Financial and Capital Account (% of GDP) -3.5 -1.7 -3.2 -1.5 -0.6 0.0 Net Foreign Direct Investment (% of GDP) 0.5 4.0 1.3 2.6 2.6 2.8 Fiscal Balance (% of GDP) -3.3 -0.9 0.1 0.5 0.6 1.0 Debt (% of GDP) 85.4 82.7 80.1 76.0 72.1 67.7 Primary Balance (% of GDP) 0.2 2.3 3.1 3.2 3.2 3.5 Lower middle-income poverty rate ($3.2 in 2011 PPP) a,b 1.3 1.3 1.3 1.1 1.0 1.0 Upper middle-income poverty rate ($5.5 in 2011 PPP) a,b 5.8 5.4 5.1 5.0 4.4 4.0 So urce: Wo rld B ank, P o verty & Equity and M acro eco no mics, Trade & Investment Glo bal P ractices. No tes: e = estimate, f = fo recast. (a) Calculatio ns based o n EU-SILC harmo nizatio n, using 201 5-EU-SILC. A ctual data: 2015. No wcast: 2016 - 2017. Fo recast are fro m 2018 to 2020. (b) P ro jectio n using neutral distributio n (2015) with pass-thro ugh = 0.87 based o n GDP per capita in co nstant LCU. MPO 53 Apr 18 Selected Country Pages ●  67 0.8 percentage points of GDP from re- GEORGIA Recent developments duced administrative costs in 2017. This helped to scale up public investments to 8.3 percent of GDP and slightly narrow The economy performed well in 2017. fiscal deficit to 3.8 percent of GDP from GDP growth improved markedly to 5 the 3.9 percent observed in 2016. Georgia ’s Table 1 2017 percent—from 2.8 percent in 2016—led by public debt remained sustainable at 44 P o pulatio n, millio n 3.7 an improved external environment. Pru- percent of GDP as of end-2017. GDP , current US$ billio n 15.5 dent macro-fiscal policies helped preserve The banking sector is well capitalized, GDP per capita, current US$ 4194 fiscal space and supported price stability. profitable and with low non-performing Internatio nal po verty rate ($ 1.9) a 4.2 Inflation spiked to 6.7 percent (eop) in loans (NPLs), although structural vulnera- Lo wer middle-inco me po verty rate ($ 3.2) a 17.1 2017 in response to higher excise taxes on bilities persist. The sector yielded a return Upper middle-inco me po verty rate ($ 5.5) a 45.5 tobacco and fuel, but dropped to below 3 on assets of 2.8 percent and a return on a percent in February 2018. With inflation equity of over 20 percent as of end-2017. Gini co efficient 36.5 b above the ceiling of its target range in 2017 Also by December 2017, NPLs represented Scho o l enro llment, primary (% gro ss) 116.8 b and rapid credit growth, the NBG in- only 2.4 percent of gross loans, down from Life expectancy at birth, years 73.0 creased the policy rate by 0.75 bps to 7.25 3.6 percent as of end-2016. At the same Source: WDI, M acro Poverty Outlook, and official data. percent over 2017. time, systemic vulnerabilities persist, in- Notes: (a) M ost recent value (2016), 2011 PPPs. Georgia’s external position improved cluding the large market concentration by (b) M ost recent WDI value (2015). considerably. Export of goods expanded the top two banks, the high retail loan by 24 percent on the back of strong de- growth (including by non-bank financial mand from Russia, Azerbaijan, Ukraine, institutions), and elevated dollarization, China, and the US; tourism proceeds rose against the backdrop of deficient financial by 27 percent; and worker’s remittances safety nets. NBG plans to address the Georgia’s growth accelerated to 5.0 per- increased by 21 percent in 2017. Import latter issues with the support from the WB cent in 2017, on the back of an improved growth was relatively lower, reflecting and IMF. gradually the firming oil prices. Gross Poverty is estimated to have fallen in 2017, external environment. In 2018 growth is FDI inflows increased in 2017 to 12.3 per- driven by an increase of employment op- projected at 4.5 percent, led by invest- cent of GDP, helping strengthen the inter- portunities related to the expansion of the ment. The fiscal deficit declined to 3.8 national reserve position, which stood at construction and services sectors, resum- percent of GDP in 2017, slightly improv- 4 months of imports of goods and ser- ing the decreasing trend started in 2010 ing from 2016; while fiscal consolidation vices. Total external debt remained high (and which stalled in 2016). The spike in at 112 percent of GDP at the end Septem- inflation in 2017 may have offset—albeit will continue in 2018, public investment ber 2017. to a minor extent—the positive effect of is expected to remain robust. Poverty is Fiscal policy was prudent. Despite elimi- employment on poverty by reducing expected to return to its declining trend nating the income tax on reinvested households’ purchasing power. The most as economic growth recovers and trans- profits starting in 2017, revenues in- recent poverty figures available for the creased by 11 percent. To prioritize so- country are for the year 2016, when pov- lates into higher income. cial and infrastructure spending, the erty was estimated at 17 percent using the authorities generated savings of about lower-middle income. FIGURE 1 Georgia / Real GDP growth and contributions to FIGURE 2 Georgia / Actual and projected poverty rates and real GDP growth real GDP per capita Percent, percentage points Poverty rate (%) GDP per capita (constant LCU) 15 100 4000 3500 10 80 3000 5 60 2500 2000 0 40 1500 -5 1000 20 500 -10 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017p 2018p 2019p 2020p 0 0 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017 2019 Gov. consumption Net Exports Investments Prv. Consumption International poverty rate Lower middle-income pov. rate GDP growth Upper middle-income pov. rate GDP pc Sources: Geostat and World Bank staff estimates. Sources: World Bank. Notes: see Table 2. MPO 54 Apr 18 68  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 programs. The fiscal deficit of the general of GDP. Additional risks stem from con- Outlook government will be gradually reduced to 3.0 percent of GDP by 2020 keeping public tingent liabilities generated by the gov- ernment’s Power Purchasing Agreements debt stable. Still, fiscal slippages, or accu- (PPAs). At the end-2017 there were 72 Georgia’s growth outlook over the medi- mulation of new liabilities or materializa- signed PPAs, in which the state issues um term is positive. The more benign ex- tion of contingent liabilities may compro- guarantees to purchase excess electricity ternal environment should facilitate the mise the expected consolidation and result from operators on a seasonal basis. While development of private sector-led export in higher debt burden. the fiscal risks of PPAs exist, the needs for sectors, encourage FDI, and support con- Continuous expansion of the economy in additional power capacity are also evi- sumption from still robust remittances. A upcoming years should lead to more em- dent from the consumption growth trend. steady implementation of the reform pro- ployment opportunities and further pov- The Government is committed to review gram will result in a further acceleration erty reduction. Employment opportunities carefully its decisions going forward, of growth over the medium term to 5 per- outside agriculture in rural areas (in par- ensuring compliance of new PPAs with cent by 2020, particularly by enhancing ticular) will play a critical role in leading the draft Law on Public Private Partner- productivity. Inflation is envisaged to to significant reductions in lagging re- ships that is expected to be approved and remain well contained, converging to the gions. Pensions and social assistance are enacted in 2018. NBG’s target of 3 percent by year-end expected to play a much smaller role for As a very open economy, Georgia is vul- 2018, while the current account deficit poverty reduction in upcoming years, in nerable to regional developments given its would narrow to below 9 percent of GDP contrast to the 2010-2015 period, given the historically high current account deficit, by 2020. more limited fiscal space. and the risks of export demand and re- Considerable consolidation of administra- mittances shock. The downside risks to tive spending, streamlining of subsidies the baseline scenario are associated with and a more efficient social safety net will help to achieve medium-term fiscal con- Risks and challenges further tightening of US monetary policy and Lari depreciation; deterioration in the solidation while providing space for capi- external environment (including due to a tal spending. Current spending is project- Georgia’s quasi-fiscal risks emanating weaker EU outlook) and regional geopo- ed to decline from 24.5 percent of GDP in from the contingent liabilities of the State - litical tensions. 2017 to 23 percent in 2020, primarily by Owned Enterprises (SOEs) are substantial Rural poverty and high poverty rates in containing the wage bill and administra- and a source of vulnerability. The Fiscal lagging regions also remain a challenge. tive expenses—which rose steadily and Risks Annex to the 2018 Budget Law sug- Providing employment opportunities and steeply for at least 4 years—and better gests that the liabilities of the 76 high and raising agricultural productivity will be targeting of subsidies and social assistance medium risk SOEs are around 20 percent critical to address them. TABLE 2 Georgia / Macro poverty outlook indicators (annual percent change unless indicated otherwise) 2015 2016 2017 e 2018 f 2019 f 2020 f Real GDP growth, at constant market prices 2.9 2.8 5.0 4.5 4.8 5.0 Private Consumption 0.1 -0.3 4.2 5.0 4.0 3.0 Government Consumption 22.1 2.8 1.3 0.8 0.0 2.8 Gross Fixed Capital Investment 11.7 8.8 -2.4 14.5 16.1 11.1 Exports, Goods and Services 6.0 -0.7 21.0 9.0 4.0 5.0 Imports, Goods and Services 10.4 -0.2 10.0 10.0 6.0 5.0 Real GDP growth, at constant factor prices 3.2 2.6 5.0 4.5 4.9 5.1 Agriculture 1.5 0.0 2.0 2.5 3.0 3.0 Industry 4.1 5.5 4.0 5.0 4.8 4.8 Services 3.1 2.1 5.6 4.5 5.1 5.3 Inflation (Consumer Price Index) 4.0 2.1 6.5 3.0 3.0 3.0 Current Account Balance (% of GDP) -11.9 -12.8 -8.7 -9.4 -9.1 -8.9 Financial and Capital Account (% of GDP) 11.9 12.8 8.7 9.4 9.1 9.9 Net Foreign Direct Investment (% of GDP) 9.0 9.8 10.5 8.9 8.9 9.0 Fiscal Balance (% of GDP) -3.8 -3.9 -3.8 -3.7 -3.3 -3.0 Debt (% of GDP) 41.4 38.2 36.0 36.8 37.7 38.8 Primary Balance (% of GDP) -2.8 -2.7 -3.1 -2.9 -2.5 -2.2 International poverty rate ($1.9 in 2011 PPP) a,b 4.0 4.2 3.7 3.4 3.0 2.7 Lower middle-income poverty rate ($3.2 in 2011 PPP) a,b 16.7 17.1 15.5 14.0 12.7 11.1 Upper middle-income poverty rate ($5.5 in 2011 PPP) a,b 46.7 45.5 42.6 40.2 37.6 34.9 So urce: Wo rld B ank, P o verty & Equity and M acro eco no mics, Trade & Investment Glo bal P ractices. No tes: e = estimate, f = fo recast. (a) Calculatio ns based o n ECA P OV harmo nizatio n, using 201 6-HIS. A ctual data: 2015, 2016. No wcast: 2017. Fo recast are fro m 2018 to 2020. (b) P ro jectio n using neutral distributio n (2016) with pass-thro ugh = 0.87 based o n GDP per capita in co nstant LCU. MPO 55 Apr 18 Selected Country Pages ●  69 fund) declined by nearly US$5 billion (3 KAZAKHSTAN Recent developments percent of GDP). The government continued to consolidate its core fiscal accounts, but the overall fiscal Following two years of weak growth, Ka- deficit widened to 7 percent of GDP in 2017 zakhstan’s economy recovered in 2017. as a result of the banking sector bailout. Table 1 2017 Real GDP growth accelerated to 4 percent The government recapitalized the Problem P o pulatio n, millio n 18.0 in 2017, up from 1.1 percent in 2016. Oil Loans Fund with an injection of US$6.5 GDP , current US$ billio n 158.2 production, which rose by 10.5 percent billion (about 4 percent of GDP) in 2017 to GDP per capita, current US$ 8792 year on year in 2017, was the primary support the recovery of banks’ balance Lo wer middle-inco me po verty rate ($ 3.2) a 0.4 driver of this improvement. The increase sheets; the central bank provided another Upper middle-inco me po verty rate ($ 5.5) a 7.8 in oil output was observed in the oil fields US$2 billion to support ailing banks. Gini co efficient a 26.9 that were not covered by the OPEC-led The central bank continued to implement b 110.6 cuts in 2017. Together with more favora- its inflation targeting policy. As the im- Scho o l enro llment, primary (% gro ss) b ble terms of trade, it generated positive pact of the 2015 currency depreciation Life expectancy at birth, years 72.0 spillover effects to the manufacturing and eased, consumer price inflation halved Source: WDI, M acro Poverty Outlook, and official data. services sectors. While the agriculture from an average of 14.6 percent in 2016 to Notes: (a) M ost recent value (2015), 2011 PPPs. sector contributed modestly to overall 7.4 percent in 2017. With inflation easing, (b) M ost recent WDI value (2015). growth in 2017, growth of the construction the central bank cut its policy interest rate sector slowed, largely reflecting the com- three times in 2017 and two times in early pletion of oil transportation projects. 2018. The latest rate cut, in March 2018, On the demand side, growth was driven lowered the policy rate to 9.5 percent. by an improvement of net exports, high- The poverty rate (using the $5.5/day inter- More favorable terms of trade and in- lighting oil sector expansion and the re- national poverty line) rose from 5.6 per- creased oil production supported the eco- covery of global oil prices. cent in 2013 to a peak of 7.9 percent in nomic recovery and an improvement in The current account deficit narrowed 2016; it is estimated to have fallen to 6.9 substantially in 2017, to 3 percent of percent in 2017. The incidence of poverty poverty indicators in Kazakhstan in 2017. GDP (from 6.5 percent in 2016), buoyed increased in all regions of Kazakhstan Over the medium term, the real GDP by more favorable terms of trade. The between 2014 and 2015, the last year for growth rate is expected to hover around improvement in the current account bal- which data are available. Poverty rates in 3 percent, as the oil sector’s contribution ance helped the tenge to strengthen by the most vulnerable southern regions about 10 percent in real terms against more than doubled during this period, to economic growth declines relative to the U.S. dollar in 2017. On the financing jumping from 5.2 percent to 13.9 percent 2017 (when a structural shift in oil out- side, FDI inflows and foreign borrowing in Kyzylorda oblast and from 5 percent to put occurred). Risks to the outlook in- by state -owned enterprises were offset 12.5 percent in Jambyl oblast. clude a potential weakening of the exter- by short-term capital outflows. The cen- Despite the economic recovery and im- nal environment, a worsening of problems tral bank reported an increase of assets proved consumer confidence, household held by residents abroad. As a result, income remained under pressure in 2017, in the banking sector, and a missed oppor- gross international reserves of the cen- as the labor market struggled to recover. tunity to deepen structural reforms. tral bank and the government (in the oil Real wages and salaries declined by 2.1 FIGURE 1 Kazakhstan / Real GDP growth and contributions FIGURE 2 Kazakhstan / Actual and projected poverty rates to real GDP growth and real GDP per capita Percent, percentage points Poverty rate, percent Thousand, tenge 7 9 820 6 8 800 5 7 780 4 6 760 3 5 740 2 4 720 1 3 0 2 700 -1 1 680 -2 0 660 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 e 2013 2014 2015 2016 e 2017 e 2018 f 2019 f 2020 f Consumption Investment $5.5/day, 2011 PPP $3.2/day, 2011 PPP Net exports Real GDP growth Real GDP per capita (RHS) Sources: Statistical Office of Kazakhstan; World Bank staff estimates. Sources: World Bank staff estimates. MPO 56 Apr 18 70  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 percent year on year. Although wages current account balance and fiscal oil reve- and price stability and encourage invest- rose by 2.5 percent year on year in Asta- nue are also expected to level off. The fis- ment in the non-oil economy. Higher in- na, the capital—and by 1.6 percent and cal position will improve gradually in the comes will also have positive spillover 1.9 percent in Pavlodar and Kostanay wake of fiscal consolidation efforts. The effects on poverty reduction. oblasts, respectively—these gains were government is planning to cut the non-oil . more than offset by falling real wages in fiscal deficit from over 13 percent of GDP the rest of the country. The official unem- ployment rate remained unchanged in in 2017 to 7 percent by 2020. As the economy continues to grow, labor Risks and challenges 2017 at 4.9 percent. income—the primary driver of poverty reduction in Kazakhstan—is forecast to Both external and domestic factors present return to positive real growth. As a result, risks to Kazakhstan’s medium-term eco- Outlook the poverty rate is projected to decline to 5 percent by 2020. nomic outlook. The economy’s vulnerabil- ity to external shocks remains the main The successful implementation of struc- challenge to achieving stable and sustaina- As oil output growth stabilizes from 2018 tural reforms will be required to deliver ble development. External demand from onward, real GDP growth is expected to more sustainable and inclusive economic China and the Russian Federation, Ka- moderate to an average annual rate of 3 growth. The ongoing structural and insti- zakhstan’s main trading partners, as well percent through 2020. Growth in the non- tutional reforms (including those under as global oil demand and prices will re- tradable services sector will be supported the 100 Concrete Steps program and the main the key external factors impacting by stronger domestic demand as real in- Strategic Plan for Development of Ka- Kazakhstan’s economic performance. Do- comes of households are expected to start zakhstan to 2025, as adopted in early 2018) mestic factors include the pace of imple- recovering. Moreover, the planned addi- should aim to reduce the role of the state mentation of structural and institutional tional investment in oil output expansion in the economy and facilitate the develop- reforms, especially in anticipation of a projects will drive an increase in construc- ment of a vibrant, modern and innovative political transition over the medium term. tion activity. tradable non-oil sector. In this context, A potential escalation of problems in the Assuming that there are no external efforts to restructure and privatize state- banking sector is also a concern. To miti- shocks and that the authorities continue owned enterprises would be expected to gate these risks and facilitate a sizeable their inflation targeting regime, consumer focus on improving the efficiency of pub- expansion of the tradable non-oil sector’s price inflation will stabilize at between 4.3 lic administration, reducing fiscal risks, role in the economy, the government must -5.3 percent in the medium term. and open contestable spaces for the pri- demonstrate significant improvements to As oil prices are projected to stabilize vate sector to act. Prudent fiscal and mon- the rule of law, the investment climate, around US$60 per barrel in 2018-20, the etary policies would support economic and the quality of human capital. TABLE 2 Kazakhstan / Macro poverty outlook indicators (annual percent change unless indicated otherwise) 2015 2016 2017 e 2018 f 2019 f 2020 f Real GDP growth, at constant market prices 1.2 1.1 4.0 2.8 3.0 3.2 Private Consumption 1.8 1.2 1.5 1.7 2.0 2.2 Government Consumption 2.4 2.4 -2.5 -3.4 1.7 1.5 Gross Fixed Capital Investment 4.2 3.0 6.2 7.6 4.5 4.6 Exports, Goods and Services -4.1 -4.4 1.5 1.7 1.9 3.1 Imports, Goods and Services -0.1 -2.2 -6.0 1.0 2.1 2.5 Real GDP growth, at constant factor prices 1.9 1.2 3.9 2.8 3.0 3.2 Agriculture 3.5 5.4 2.9 3.0 3.0 3.0 Industry -0.4 1.1 6.1 2.1 2.3 3.1 Services 3.2 0.9 2.7 3.2 3.4 3.3 Inflation (Consumer Price Index) 6.6 14.6 7.4 5.3 4.3 4.5 Current Account Balance (% of GDP) -2.8 -6.5 -3.0 -0.6 -0.5 -0.3 Financial and Capital Account (% of GDP) 5.2 6.9 6.1 2.6 1.8 1.7 Net Foreign Direct Investment (% of GDP) 1.7 10.5 6.0 5.2 4.6 4.2 Fiscal Balance (% of GDP) -7.9 -6.4 -7.0 -2.6 -2.4 -2.0 Debt (% of GDP) 21.9 19.6 20.7 20.9 22.4 24.6 Primary Balance (% of GDP) -7.1 -5.3 -6.1 -1.8 -1.5 -1.2 Lower middle-income poverty rate ($3.2 in 2011 PPP) a,b 0.4 0.4 0.3 0.3 0.3 0.3 Upper middle-income poverty rate ($5.5 in 2011 PPP) a,b 7.8 7.9 6.9 6.2 5.6 5.0 So urce: Wo rld B ank, P o verty & Equity and M acro eco no mics, Trade & Investment Glo bal P ractices. No tes: e = estimate, f = fo recast. (a) Calculatio ns based o n ECA P OV harmo nizatio n, using 201 5-HB S. A ctual data: 2015. No wcast: 2016 - 2017. Fo recast are fro m 2018 to 2020. (b) P ro jectio n using neutral distributio n (2015) with pass-thro ugh = 0.87 based o n GDP per capita in co nstant LCU. MPO 57 Apr 18 Selected Country Pages ●  71 due to a decline in CIT collections by 7 KOSOVO Recent developments percent. Spending increased by 5.7 per- cent, due to a 11.9 percent increase in so- cial transfers and 5.4 percent increase in Growth reached 4.4 percent in 2017, up capital spending. Higher actual costs than from 4.1 percent in 2016. The upturn is planned costs for spending on veterans Table 1 2017 driven by rise in investment, and recovery in benefits exceeded plans due to the delay P o pulatio n, millio n 1.8 exports. Higher private investment was driv- in the implementation of the cap on the GDP , current US$ billio n 7.1 en by FDI inflows, thanks to higher growth scheme. In addition, goods and services GDP per capita, current US$ 3902 in Europe, low interest rates, and a better spending rose by 10.7 percent due to early Scho o l enro llment, primary (% gro ss) a n.a. business environment as Kosovo improved elections and creation of two additional Life expectancy at birth, years a 71.3 its rank from 60 to 40 in Doing Business. ministries. Public and publicly guaranteed Investment contributed 3pp to economic debt remains on a rising trajectory, reach- Source: WDI, M acro Poverty Outlook, and official data. Notes: growth, with public investment increasing ing 15.8 percent of GDP at end-2017. by 5 percent y-o-y. The recovery in goods The current account deficit (CAD) improved (a) M ost recent WDI value (2015). exports was led by a rebound in commodity to 5.1 percent of GDP in 2017, from 8.2 per- prices with a broad-based increase in vol- cent in 2016, thanks to better external condi- umes of goods exports, albeit from a low tions and increase in export volumes. Ex- base, and a surge in the export of services. ports of goods jumped up by 23.1 percent y-o Net exports contributed a 1.1pp while the -y in 2017 due to higher growth of the trad- contribution of consumption was only 0.4pp. ing partners, and higher global prices of base The economy grew at 4.4 percent in In terms of economic sectors, construction, metals. Exports of services grew by 17.7 per- 2017, up from 4.1 in 2016. The accelera- trade, financial and transport were the main cent in 2017, mainly due to higher travel tion was due to a pickup in investment engine of growth in 2017 with a contribution expenditures by the diaspora. and a recovery in exports. Stronger of 2.6 pp. Agriculture remained stagnant, Higher growth continued to foster job crea- whereas industry contributed 0.7pp. tion in 2017. Employment grew by 1.2pp y-o- growth fostered job creation in 2017, Consumer price inflation was 1.5 percent y in the third quarter of 2017, however, as supporting poverty reduction; but labor in 2017 y-o-y, up from 0.3 percent in 2016, labor force participation expanded further, force participation remains low. The as prices for fuel, food, tobacco, alcohol, unemployment increased by 2.7 pp. Despite outlook is positive, with 4.8 percent and other household items increased add- the recent improvements, employment is still ing to the cost of living. low at 29.7 percent on average as a share of annual growth projected between 2018 - Higher revenues (up 5.3 percent y-o-y) total population. The share of self-employed 2020, driven by investment and con- and under-execution of public invest- and unpaid family workers, i.e. those in vul- sumption. Risks to the outlook include ments narrowed the fiscal deficit to 1.4 nerable employment and measures job quali- the ability to execute the public invest- percent of GDP in 2017, lower than the ty, remains high at 23 percent; the youth ment program, metal price dynamics earlier projected 2 percent of GDP. Indi- unemployment rate slightly increased reach- rect tax revenues grew by 6.1 percent ing 53.3 percent in Q3 2017. The duration of and the fragile political situation. (VAT by 8.1 percent), while non -tax reve- unemployment is worrying with over 70 nues grew by 5.6 percent y-o-y. Direct tax percent of the unemployed seeking a job for revenues added only 2.5 percent growth, over a year. FIGURE 1 Kosovo / Real GDP growth and contributions to FIGURE 2 Kosovo / Actual and projected poverty rates and real GDP growth real private consumption per capita Percent, percentage points Poverty rate (%) Private consumption per capita (constant LCU) 8.0% 30 3000 6.0% 25 2500 4.0% 20 2000 2.0% 15 1500 0.0% -2.0% 10 1000 -4.0% 5 500 -6.0% 0 0 2014 2015 2016 2017 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020 Consumption Investments International poverty rate Lower middle-income pov. rate Net exports Real GDP growth Upper middle-income pov. rate Consumption pc Sources: Statistics Agency of Kosovo and WB Staff. Sources: World Bank. Notes: see Table 2. MPO 58 Apr 18 72  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 The CAD is expected to reach 6 percent of growth in Europe and other trading part- Outlook GDP in 2018. Increased demand for in- vestment goods is expected to widen the ners pose risks to the outlook. Perceived fragility of the government, CAD in 2018, despite higher exports pro- with only 61 out of 120 votes in the parlia- Economic growth is projected at 4.8 per- jected. Net FDI and remittances, are ex- ment, can slow down the implementation cent in 2018-2020, propelled by higher pected to finance larger shares of the CAD of public projects through the investment capital spending. Growth in public invest- as growth in Europe firms up and larger clause. In addition, the delay in fiscal re- ment is expected to be driven by several implementation of the Stabilization and forms such as the implementation of the projects under preparation, including the Association Agreement. cap on the war veteran’s benefits, further railway project and regional roads fi- Poverty, measured at the lower middle- increases in untargeted categorical social nanced by IFIs. Private investment is ex- income poverty line (US$ 3.2/day, 2011 benefits, and unfunded early retirement pected to increase reflecting improve- PPP), is expected to decline slightly to 2.55 schemes increase fiscal pressures. ments in the business environment, and in 2018, from 2.6 percent in 2017 driven by Reform priorities should include shifting increase in credit due to the partial credit stronger growth. High unemployment sources of growth towards tradable sec- guarantee fund for SMEs established in and inactivity rates remain the key imped- tors and increasing productivity to ad- 2017. Higher wages and social spending, iments to sustainable poverty reduction. dress high unemployment, low participa- growth in remittances and credit to house- tion rates, and poverty. holds are expected to promote household consumption adding an additional 2.3 pp to growth. Exports are likely to benefit Risks and challenges from robust growth in Europe and higher base metal prices. However, net exports Kosovo’s outlook is positive, but the risks are projected to subtract 0.9 pp from are tilted to the downside. Lower than growth in 2018 because of higher imports projected absorption of public investment, linked to public investment projects. lower base metal prices and slower TABLE 2 Kosovo / Macro poverty outlook indicators (annual percent change unless indicated otherwise) 2015 2016 2017 e 2018 f 2019 f 2020 f Real GDP growth, at constant market prices 4.1 4.1 4.4 4.8 4.8 4.8 Private Consumption 4.3 5.7 0.3 2.0 2.5 2.2 Government Consumption -6.5 -6.3 1.0 4.5 1.5 3.3 Gross Fixed Capital Investment 12.1 7.3 11.3 12.1 11.8 10.5 Exports, Goods and Services 1.9 7.5 15.6 8.3 7.9 7.7 Imports, Goods and Services 3.8 7.0 5.1 5.9 5.9 5.3 Real GDP growth, at constant factor prices 3.0 2.4 4.5 3.6 5.1 5.0 Agriculture -4.1 3.1 3.7 6.6 8.4 6.2 Industry 5.9 1.8 3.8 -0.5 5.8 4.5 Services 3.0 2.6 5.1 5.4 3.9 4.9 Inflation (Consumer Price Index) -0.5 0.3 1.5 1.7 1.7 1.7 Current Account Balance (% of GDP) -8.6 -8.2 -5.1 -6.0 -7.0 -7.5 Fiscal Balance (% of GDP) -1.8 -1.3 -1.4 -2.2 -3.0 -3.3 Debt (% of GDP) 12.7 14.1 15.8 16.6 18.6 20.9 Primary Balance (% of GDP) -1.5 -1.0 -1.1 -1.9 -2.6 -2.9 So urce: Wo rld B ank, P o verty & Equity and M acro eco no mics, Trade & Investment Glo bal P ractices. No tes: e = estimate, f = fo recast. MPO 59 Apr 18 Selected Country Pages ●  73 exports, which benefited from the recov- KYRGYZ Recent developments ery in regional demand as well as im- proved compliance by Kyrgyz producers with Eurasian Economic Union (EEU) REPUBLIC The Kyrgyz economy has recovered from the external shocks of 2014-15 as growth quality standards. Imports are estimated to have risen by 12% (in US dollar terms), accelerated to 4.5% in 2017, from 3.8% a a slower increase than might have been year earlier. Growth was driven by the envisaged given the improvement in re- Table 1 2017 non-gold industry (22%) while it deceler- mittances and high levels of public invest- P o pulatio n, millio n 6.2 ated in other main sectors: gold, construc- ment. The current account deficit was fi- tion, agriculture and services. On the de- nanced by FDI and government borrow- GDP , current US$ billio n 7.2 mand side, growth was supported by ing. International reserves increased GDP per capita, current US$ 1160 a public investment, net exports and private slightly to US$2.1 billion, covering about 4 Internatio nal po verty rate ($ 1.9) 1.4 consumption fueled by a steady rebound months of imports. a Lo wer middle-inco me po verty rate ($ 3.2) 19.1 in remittances inflows. The stronger balance of payments (and a Upper middle-inco me po verty rate ($ 5.5) 67.1 An expansionary fiscal stance was main- corresponding foreign exchange liquidity Gini co efficient a 26.8 tained, even as external tailwinds strength- in the economy) led to a further apprecia- Scho o l enro llment, primary (% gro ss) b 107.4 ened. The estimated overall fiscal deficit tion of the Kyrgyz som by 0.6% in 2017 Life expectancy at birth, years b 70.7 was 5% of GDP in 2017, down from 6.6% (8.8% in 2016). In real effective terms, in 2016 and lower than the budgeted defi- however, the som depreciated by 0.5%, Source: WDI, M acro Poverty Outlook, and official data. Notes: cit of 7.5%, but still above the levels of pre- largely reflecting relative inflation dynam- (a) M ost recent value (2016), 2011 PPPs. vious years. Both tax and non-tax revenues ics with key trading partners. (b) M ost recent WDI value (2015). increased as a share of GDP. In addition, Inflation rose slightly in 2017 reaching the budget received rising grant support 3.7%, given buoyant domestic demand. from international donors. At the same With inflation still below the National time, expenditures increased, driven large- Bank (NBKR) target of 5-7%, monetary ly by capital outlays. Substantial overruns policy remained accommodative. Econom- In 2017, growth was stronger than ex- in current spending in the first part of the ic activity was supported by a recovery in pected, supported by external tailwinds, year were partially mitigated by expendi- credit to the economy (14% growth), fol- the expansionary macroeconomic policy ture restraint in the last quarter of 2017. lowing a decline early in the year. stance, which buoyed domestic demand, The deficit was mainly financed by foreign The poverty rate (measured at below borrowing, which increased total public US$3.2 per day, 2011 PPP terms) is esti- and a better-than-expected (albeit weak- debt to 63.2% of GDP from 61.4% in 2016. mated to have fallen to 19% in 2016. Low ening) performance in the gold sector. The current account deficit is estimated to consumer price growth and higher re- Going forward, growth is projected to have narrowed to 9.4% of GDP in 2017 mittance inflows supported household decline slightly in 2018, before picking - from 12.1% a year before, as exports consumption. At the same time, moderate picked-up (+14.5% in US dollar terms) and growth in services and agriculture, where up to 5% over the medium term, allow- remittances continued to grow (by 24.2% about 50% of the bottom 40 are employed, ing for continued moderate declines in in US dollar terms). The export perfor- constrained real labor income growth for the poverty rate. mance was driven mainly by non-gold the poor. FIGURE 1 Kyrgyz Republic / Real GDP growth and FIGURE 2 Kyrgyz Republic / Actual and projected poverty contributions to real GDP growth rates and real GDP growth per capita Percentage points Percent Percent of population Percent 6 6 40 12 5 5 35 10 4 30 4 8 3 25 3 6 2 20 2 4 1 15 1 2 0 10 -1 0 5 0 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 0 -2 Agriculture Industry w/out Kumtor 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017 2019 Kumtor Construction Services GDP (RHS) GDP growth, RHS $3.2/day PPP, LHS Sources: Kyrgyz authorities and WB staff calculations. Sources: Kyrgyz authorities and WB staff calculations. MPO 60 Apr 18 74  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 The fiscal deficit is projected to decline to Outlook 2.9% of GDP by 2020. This will be achieved through measures to increase tax revenues Risks and challenges and curtail current spending, while capital Real GDP growth is projected to deceler- expenditures would remain robust at about The outlook is subject to downside risks. ate slightly to 4.2% in 2018 -as industrial 7.6% of GDP on average (although falling to Growth will continue to be highly de- output growth moderates- and then pick 6.1% in 2020 as externally financed projects pendent on exogenous regional develop- up to reach 5% by 2020. This scenario as- decline). Over 2018-20, tax revenues should ments. Specifically, a slowdown in Russia sumes that recovery takes hold in Russia increase as a share of GDP, with measures and Kazakhstan could affect negatively and Kazakhstan, benefiting the Kyrgyz to: (i) expand the tax base by encouraging the baseline scenario via remittances and economy via the traditional remittance businesses to formalize, (ii) improve the trade. Adverse exchange rate develop- and trade channels. An additional boost is administration of taxes, (iii) reduce tax ex- ments could heighten competition in the expected to come from exports, thanks to emptions, and (iv) increase some tax rates. domestic and EEU markets. a number of developments, which in- Over the same period, expenses are target- A core challenge continues to be to accel- clude: (i) enhanced access to the EEU mar- ed to decline by over 5 percentage points erate the process of convergence of local ket; and (ii) improved bilateral relations (from 38.7% in 2018) as a result of efforts to production to EEU standards. This would with Uzbekistan, which should lead to (i) streamline non-priority purchases of help Kyrgyz producers to boost exports of higher trade between the two countries. goods and services, (ii) reduce the wage bill agricultural and textile products in the These effects should mitigate the antici- as a share of GDP, and (iii) strengthen pub- short and medium run. pated moderation of public expenditure. lic procurement. Another challenge will be to bring fis- Inflation is envisaged to remain in line Modest increases in growth in agriculture cal policy back to a sustainable path, with the NBKR target, assuming no sig- and construction, and a solid performance of while continuing to provide adequate nificant global food price increases and remittances, are likely to support rural pov- support to the economy. Several policy relative exchange rate stability. erty reduction. Social transfers will continue decisions taken in the run -up to the While remittance inflows are expected to to play an important role in driving poverty Presidential elections in October 2017 grow further, the current account deficit reduction in both urban and rural areas. A are expected to add structural pressure is projected to remain elevated at around scheduled increase in pensions should also on spending, including a universal ex- 10% of GDP, reflecting structural fea- benefit poor households given that pensions tension of the previously income - tures of the economy and continued represent close to 15% of income among the targeted benefit for low income families high, albeit gradually moderating, levels poor. The poverty rate is projected to decline with children, which will complicate of public investment. to 18.5% in 2018 and 16.7% in 2020. the task of fiscal consolidation. TABLE 2 Kyrgyz Republic / Macro poverty outlook indicators (annual percent change unless indicated otherwise) 2015 2016 2017 e 2018 f 2019 f 2020 f Real GDP growth, at constant market prices 3.9 3.8 4.5 4.2 4.8 5.0 Private Consumption -0.9 1.8 1.9 2.8 3.6 4.0 Government Consumption 0.9 2.7 0.6 0.6 0.7 0.5 Gross Fixed Capital Investment 3.9 3.7 4.0 4.9 5.7 6.0 Exports, Goods and Services -5.6 2.2 5.6 8.4 8.5 8.9 Imports, Goods and Services -13.2 -4.0 0.0 2.7 3.3 4.4 Real GDP growth, at constant factor prices 3.9 3.8 4.5 4.2 4.8 5.0 Agriculture 6.2 3.0 2.2 2.7 2.2 2.2 Industry 2.9 5.9 10.3 6.8 8.9 9.8 Services 2.6 3.7 4.2 4.3 5.2 5.1 Inflation (Consumer Price Index) 6.5 0.4 3.6 4.0 4.0 4.0 Current Account Balance (% of GDP) -15.8 -12.1 -9.4 -11.0 -10.7 -9.8 Financial and Capital Account (% of GDP) 17.4 9.7 7.2 11.0 10.7 9.8 Net Foreign Direct Investment (% of GDP) 15.1 8.1 6.9 7.0 7.0 6.5 Fiscal Balance (% of GDP) -3.0 -6.6 -5.0 -4.1 -4.4 -2.9 Debt (% of GDP) 67.3 61.4 63.2 63.5 63.7 63.4 Primary Balance (% of GDP) -2.0 -5.6 -4.1 -2.5 -3.3 -2.2 International poverty rate ($1.9 in 2011 PPP) a,b 2.5 1.4 1.0 0.8 0.5 0.4 Lower middle-income poverty rate ($3.2 in 2011 PPP) a,b 23.2 19.1 18.5 18.0 17.4 16.7 Upper middle-income poverty rate ($5.5 in 2011 PPP) a,b 69.9 67.1 66.1 65.1 63.9 62.6 So urce: Wo rld B ank, P o verty & Equity and M acro eco no mics, Trade & Investment Glo bal P ractices. No tes: e = estimate, f = fo recast. (a) Calculatio ns based o n ECA P OV harmo nizatio n, using 2009-KIHS, 201 5-KIHS, and 2016-KIHS. A ctual data: 2015, 2016. No wcast: 2017. Fo recast are fro m 2018 to 2020. (b) P ro jectio n using average elasticity (2009-2015) with pass-thro ugh = 0.7 based o n GDP per capita in co nstant LCU. MPO 61 Apr 18 Selected Country Pages ●  75 grew by 2.4 percent y-o-y in 2017, helped MACEDONIA Recent developments in part by employment subsidies in the first part of the year, through which al- most third of the net new jobs were creat- The political turmoil of 2015-2017 slowed ed. The employment rate has been con- real GDP growth in 2017 from 2.9 percent stantly improving, but remains low at 44 Table 1 2017 in 2016 to zero percent in 2017, driven by a percent, meaning that more than half of P o pulatio n, millio n 2.1 fall in investments. The inauguration of the working age population is either un- GDP , current US$ billio n 11.3 the new government in June 2017 resolved employed or outside of the labor force. GDP per capita, current US$ 5440 the stalemate as evidenced by the compa- Most of the jobs created were in wholesale Internatio nal po verty rate ($ 1.9) a 5.3 nies’ improved expectations on future and retail trade, accommodation and food Lo wer middle-inco me po verty rate ($ 3.2) a 9.8 production. Investment fell by 4.5 percent services and manufacturing—the latter Upper middle-inco me po verty rate ($ 5.5) a 23.2 y-o-y in 2017, but it started recovering by sectors with links to the FDI-economy, a year-end with recovering investor confi- which benefit from tax exemptions and Gini co efficient 35.6 b dence. Private consumption was the only other government support. As a result, the Scho o l enro llment, primary (% gro ss) 93.2 b contributor to growth in 2017, supported unemployment rate fell to a historical low, Life expectancy at birth, years 75.5 by higher employment and wages. Net- at 22.4 percent in 2017, close to 80 percent Source: WDI, M acro Poverty Outlook, and official data. exports contributed negatively to growth of which is long-term. Notes: (a) M ost recent value (2015), 2011 PPPs. (-0.7 pp). Solid exports growth was pro- Poverty is estimated to have continued (b) M ost recent WDI value (2015). pelled by the recovery in the Euro area but declining in 2017. Poverty (at US$5.5/day was not enough to compensate for rising at 2011 PPP) is projected to have fallen to imports for energy, FDI-related imports, 21 percent in 2017, continuing a decreas- and iron and steel. At the sector level, ing trend present since 2009. Employment As investment contracted after a pro- construction and manufacturing stalled in growth and increases in salaries, especial- longed political crisis, economic growth 2017, with construction falling by almost ly in the labor-intensive sectors, are ex- 14 percent y-o-y in real terms as both pri- pected to have driven most of the poverty slowed to zero percent in 2017. Growth is vate and public construction activities reduction in 2017. Pensions, which played projected to rise to 2.3 percent in 2018, stalled. Mining, wholesale and retail trade a role in the 2009-2014 decrease, are un- driven by consumption and recovering and agriculture were the only sectors that likely to have played a relevant role in investment. Despite the slowdown, labor contributed positively to growth, support- recent poverty dynamics. market improved thanks to public subsi- ed by rising metal prices, growth in dis- Revenue gains in 2017 were offset by in- posable income and a favorable harvest creases in spending, resulting in un- dies; but employment and labor force season, respectively. changed fiscal deficit—at 2.7 percent of participation rates remain low compared Inflation remained low in 2017 at 1.4 per- GDP. Revenues increased on the back of to the EU. The fiscal deficit remained cent, although it increased from a 2016 de- solid VAT and collection of the social se- unchanged in 2017, with higher spend- flation, driven by rising prices of food and curity contributions, while expenditures beverages, energy (including oil), clothing increased due to higher spending for ing offsetting improved tax collection. and footwear and communications. health, pensions, and subsidies. Capital Poverty continued to decline in 2017, Despite slower growth, there were improve- spending once again remained under- propelled by job creation. ments in the labor market. Employment executed reflecting a slowdown in project FIGURE 1 Macedonia / Real GDP growth and contributions FIGURE 2 Macedonia / Annual and projected poverty rates to real GDP growth and real GDP per capita Percent, percentage points Poverty headcount GDP per capita (USD 2011 PPP) 6 50 35.1 16,000 32.5 32.2 45 14,000 4 29.7 40 28.9 12,000 2 35 24.8 23.2 30 21.7 21.4 10,000 20.5 19.3 0 25 8,000 -2 20 6,000 15 9.7 10.4 9.9 -4 7.5 4,000 10 6.2 4.9 5.3 5.2 5.0 4.9 4.8 5 2,000 -6 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017 f 2019 f 0 0 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 Final consumption Gross capital formation Net exports Real growth $1.9/day $5.5/day GDP per capita Sources: FYR Macedonia State Statistics Office and World Bank staff calculations. Sources: WDI and own calculations based on SILC 2010 -2015. MPO 62 Apr 18 76  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 implementation. Public and publicly guar- imports and were further replenished in Fiscal deficit is planned to remain un- anteed debt declined to 47.5 percent in January 2018 as the Government issued a changed in 2018 leading to rise in public 2017, from 48.4 percent in 2016, but due to 7-year EUR 500 million Eurobond at 2.75 debt to 50 percent of GDP. a drawdown on accumulated deposits to percent which fully covers government reduce new borrowing. borrowing requirements for 2018. Credit growth increased in 2017. House- hold credit grew by 9.2 percent, while Risks and challenges corporate lending remained subdued throughout 2017 (2.6 percent). The loan-to Outlook With the political crisis now resolved, the -deposit ratio stood at 88 percent, which main risk comes from fiscal vulnerabilities should allow banks to expand lending The economic outlook is positive, with and low potential growth. A low revenue activities. Non-performing loans (NPLs) growth expected to average 2.7 percent to GDP ratio, a growing deficit in the pen- stood at 6.3 percent, similar to 6.4 percent during 2018-2020. Construction activity is sion system, higher interest payments, at end-2016, but corporate NPLs increased expected to recover, as the construction of and accumulated arrears are risks to fiscal slightly to 9.9 percent. two highways is resumed. The manufac- sustainability. Discussions about raising The current account deficit narrowed to turing sector is also expected to recover, a untargeted social transfers compound the 1.1 percent of GDP in 2017. Solid export process that began in late 2017, propelled sustainability concerns. performance of FDIs, iron and steel, furni- by improved foreign demand from the Credible fiscal consolidation program ture and tobacco helped to reduce the EU. Private consumption is projected to focused on strengthening efficiency of goods and services deficit to 13.9 percent rise supported by higher employment and public spending and broadening of the tax of GDP (from 15 percent in 2016). Net as the new authorities indicated rise in base would help to stabilize public debt, private transfer inflows increased slightly social transfers. rebuild fiscal buffers against future shocks to 15.8 percent of GDP, while primary Poverty is likely to continue its down- and increase investor confidence. income deficit widened further to 4.2 per- ward trend in 2018 -2020 with improved Ensuring the backward linkages of the cent of GDP as foreign investors kept re- economic outlook. Public investment in FDIs, unlocking potentials in the energy, patriating profits amidst the political tur- infrastructure should sustain employ- tourism and agriculture sectors, as well moil. Foreign direct investments declined ment creation. Increases in social transfers as reducing the overregulation in pro- in 2017 to only 2.3 percent of GDP, com- should also translate into further poverty fessional and infrastructure network pared to 3.2 percent in 2016. At end-2017, reductions, if properly designed and services could help increasing the poten- foreign reserves stood at 4.4 months of means-tested. tial growth. TABLE 2 Macedonia / Macro poverty outlook indicators (annual percent change unless indicated otherwise) 2015 2016 2017 2018 f 2019 f 2020 f Real GDP growth, at constant market prices 3.9 2.9 0.0 2.3 2.7 3.0 Private Consumption 4.4 3.1 2.9 2.2 1.9 1.9 Government Consumption 3.9 1.9 -1.5 2.1 1.5 1.5 Gross Fixed Capital Investment 2.1 -3.9 -4.5 0.9 3.3 4.7 Exports, Goods and Services 8.5 8.1 9.2 5.4 6.3 6.3 Imports, Goods and Services 9.9 11.6 7.3 3.6 4.2 4.2 Real GDP growth, at constant factor prices 5.0 3.7 -0.8 4.1 2.6 2.9 Agriculture 1.9 2.8 4.1 0.9 1.2 1.2 Industry 6.2 6.1 -7.8 16.4 5.1 5.1 Services 4.9 2.7 1.7 -0.5 1.6 2.1 Inflation (Consumer Price Index) -0.3 -0.2 1.4 1.6 2.0 2.0 Current Account Balance (% of GDP) -1.9 -2.8 -1.1 -2.5 -2.5 -2.6 Financial and Capital Account (% of GDP) 1.8 2.6 1.0 6.7 2.2 2.4 Net Foreign Direct Investment (% of GDP) 2.3 3.3 2.2 2.6 2.9 3.1 Fiscal Balance (% of GDP) -3.6 -2.7 -2.7 -2.7 -2.5 -2.3 Debt (% of GDP) 38.1 39.6 39.3 43.3 44.4 45.5 Primary Balance (% of GDP) -2.4 -1.5 -1.4 -1.2 -0.9 -0.5 International poverty rate ($1.9 in 2011 PPP) a,b 5.3 5.2 5.0 5.0 4.8 4.8 Lower middle-income poverty rate ($3.2 in 2011 PPP) a,b 9.8 9.7 9.6 9.3 9.2 9.2 Upper middle-income poverty rate ($5.5 in 2011 PPP) a,b 23.2 21.9 21.0 20.6 20.5 20.2 So urce: Wo rld B ank, P o verty & Equity and M acro eco no mics, Trade & Investment Glo bal P ractices. No tes: e = estimate, f = fo recast. (a) Calculatio ns based o n SILC harmo nizatio n, using 201 5-SILC gro uped data (survey year). A ctual data: 2015. No wcast: 201 6 - 2017. Fo recast are fro m 2018 to 2020. (b) P ro jectio n using neutral distributio n (2015) with pass-thro ugh = 0.7 based o n P rivate co nsumptio n per capita in co nstant LCU. MPO 63 Apr 18 Selected Country Pages ●  77 The increasing real wages and a recover- MOLDOVA Recent developments ing flow of remittances, as well as the favorable 2016 harvest have been associ- ated with a downward trend in the pov- Growth reached 4.5 percent in 2017 on ac- erty headcount, which, measured at the count of strong consumption led by the international moderate poverty thresh- Table 1 2017 ongoing recovery in remittances and in- old of US$ 5.5/day in 2011 PPP, de- P o pulatio n, millio n 3.5 creases in real wages. A double-digit in- creased to 16.3 percent in 2015 from 18.4 GDP , current US$ billio n 8.2 crease in public investments stimulated in 2014, and continued decreasing in GDP per capita, current US$ 2307 gross fixed capital formation (+5.1 percent). 2016. The unemployment rate fell form Internatio nal po verty rate ($ 1.9) a 0.2 Despite robust exports supported by the 4.9 percent in 2015 to 4.2 percent in 2016, Lo wer middle-inco me po verty rate ($ 3.2) a 1.3 good harvest of the past two years, imports the decline being particularly pro- Upper middle-inco me po verty rate ($ 5.5) a 16.5 increased rapidly resulting in a negative nounced in rural areas (0.9 percentage a contribution of net exports to growth (-2.7 points), where the incidence of poverty Gini co efficient 26.3 b percentage points). On the production side, is higher. Salaries increased by a further Scho o l enro llment, primary (% gro ss) 92.4 b growth has been mainly driven by the re- 5.2 percent in real terms in 2017, sup- Life expectancy at birth, years 71.4 tail and wholesale trade (+1.3 percentage porting household welfare. Source: WDI, M acro Poverty Outlook, and official data. points), followed by growth in agriculture The external position remains stable, de- Notes: (a) M ost recent value (2016), 2011 PPPs. (+1 percentage points) and industry (+0.4 spite a recent increase in current account (b) M ost recent WDI value (2015). percentage points). deficit. In the first nine months of 2017, After a sharp deceleration in 2016, the in- exports increased in nominal terms by flation rate averaged 6.6 percent in 2017, 25.2 percent, remittances increased by 12.1 just above the target corridor of 5 percent percent, while net direct investments in- In 2017, Moldova registered robust growth +/- 1.5 percent. Increases in regulated pric- creased 1.2 percentage points of GDP supported by favorable conditions in agri- es, unfavorable climatic conditions in compared to end-2016, on account of rein- Spring which affected seasonal agricultur- vested profits, reaching 2.5 percent of culture and strong private consumption. al outputs, and stronger internal demand GDP. Yet, supported by a stronger Leu Higher wages and the recovery of re- accelerated the inflation rate, which has and imports of electricity, imports in- mittances brought poverty rate down. been out of the target corridor since April creased (+22.5 percent y/y), determining Growth momentum is expected to be pre- 2017. To stimulate credit activity and ab- the widening of the current account deficit sorb the existing liquidity after the bank- by 3.4 percentage points y/y reaching 9.2 served during 2018 and 2019 supported by ing crisis, throughout 2017, the NBM grad- percent of GDP. The current account defi- growing consumption and investments, ually reduced the base interest rate (from 9 cit continues to be financed predominant- particularly public. While Moldova rebuilt percent to 6.5 percent), while increasing ly through external debt. As of end - its macroeconomic buffers, major policy the reserve requirement ratio to a record September 2017, total external debt grew challenges related to upcoming elections, high of 40 percent. Strong foreign inflows by 8.1 percent totaling 83 percent of GDP. pushed the appreciation of the Moldovan Against this background, by end-January governance, particularly in the financial Leu, tempering the cost-push inflation 2018 foreign reserves reached an all-time sector, to the efficiency of public spending, pressures. By end-January 2018, the infla- record of 2.9 billion USD, covering more and to revenue mobilization remain. tion rate registered 6.5 percent y/y. than 5 months of imports. FIGURE 1 Moldova / Actual and projected GDP growth and FIGURE 2 Moldova / Actual and projected poverty rates and current account balance real private consumption per capita Percent Poverty rate (%) Private consumption per capita (constant LCU) 9.4 10 100 12000 7.1 6.8 4.8 4.5 4.5 10000 5 3.8 3.7 3.5 80 8000 60 0 6000 -0.7 -0.4 40 -5 4000 -6.0 20 2000 -10 Real GDP, % change 0 0 Current Account Balance, % GDP 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017 2019 -15 International poverty rate Lower middle-income pov. rate 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017 2019 Upper middle-income pov. rate Consumption pc Sources: National authorities and World Bank estimates. Sources: World Bank. Notes: see Table 2. MPO 64 Apr 18 78  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 Following two years of tight fiscal poli- plans to increase public investments, with poverty headcount, measured at the inter- cies, a lower than expected deficit was a focus on the road sector. Still, structural national moderate poverty threshold of registered in 2017, as fiscal revenues out- weaknesses will contain growth at around $5.5/day is projected to decline from 16.3 paced the double-digit increase in expend- 3.5 percent. As consumption and imports percent in 2015 to 12.7 percent in 2018 and itures. Following the under execution in strengthen, the current account deficit is 11.7 percent in 2019. 2016, public spending increased 12.5 per- expected to gradually increase, but to re- cent y/y. Supported by a strong increase in main below its historical average thanks fiscal revenues and better compliance, public revenues increased 16.2 percent y/ to revitalization of foreign inflows. The inflation rate is expected to reach the low- Risks and challenges y. Buoyant foreign trade was also reflected er bound of the target corridor in 2018 due in strong collections of VAT (+15.8 per- to base effects and lower regulated prices After two years of good climatic condi- cent, y/y) and excises (+30.9 percent, y/y). and to gradually increasing to the target tions, extreme weather may affect agricul- As a result, the fiscal deficit was 2.2 per- of 5 percent in medium term. In the base- tural output with consequences for overall centage points higher, totaling -0.8 percent line scenario, fiscal deficits are projected to growth. The banking sector has stabilized, of GDP. remain under control. Due to mandated yet it is important to continue reforms and indexation and valorization of pensions, strengthen the transparency in the sector. wage increases and additional public capi- Moreover, the increased demand (+30 per- Outlook tal investments, expenditures will increase reaching about 3 percent of GDP in 2018. cent in the first half of 2017) observed for the unregulated and poorly monitored non The factors underlying a favorable growth -banking financial intermediation sector Growth is expected to be robust and reach forecast similarly suggest a further decline raises concerns. Weaker growth of key 3.8% in 2018 and 3.7% in 2019 but remain in the poverty headcount during the pro- trade partners and potential changes in below the historical averages (of 4.6%). In jection period, following the trend from international trade and migration relations the medium-term the recovery in re- recent years. Increases in real wages and could undermine exports and remittance mittances together with private wage remittances, as well as a good harvest year flows. While the authorities have made growth will sustain private consumption, should support household welfare, inclu- efforts to reduce macroeconomic risks, fast- which will remain a key driver of growth. sively in rural areas, where the incidence er growth is necessary to converge with EU Import growth will outpace export of poverty remains higher. The rate of countries. For this to happen, Moldova growth, leading to a negative contribution wage increases according to latest data needs deep transformational reforms that of net trade to GDP growth. With parlia- from Q3 of 2017 suggests that on an annu- will create new and better jobs in the pri- mentary elections in November 2018, after al basis wages in agriculture increased vate sector and consequently will create a prolonged contraction, the Government faster than in the economy overall. The space for public investment needs. TABLE 2 Moldova / Macro poverty outlook indicators (annual percent change unless indicated otherwise) 2015 2016 2017 e 2018 f 2019 f 2020 f Real GDP growth, at constant market prices -0.4 4.5 4.5 3.8 3.7 3.5 Private Consumption -2.3 4.0 4.9 3.8 3.6 3.5 Government Consumption 0.2 -0.1 0.2 0.7 -0.1 0.2 Gross Fixed Capital Investment -3.3 -2.1 5.2 6.1 5.3 5.8 Exports, Goods and Services 2.9 8.7 12.7 2.2 3.9 5.1 Imports, Goods and Services -4.7 5.2 11.4 2.9 4.1 5.3 Real GDP growth, at constant factor prices -0.3 5.3 4.0 2.4 3.1 3.1 Agriculture -13.4 18.0 7.9 1.1 2.3 3.5 Industry 3.5 2.6 3.0 3.8 4.6 5.4 Services 3.8 1.8 2.7 2.5 2.9 2.2 Inflation (Consumer Price Index) 9.7 6.4 6.6 3.5 4.5 5.0 Current Account Balance (% of GDP) -7.2 -4.2 -8.0 -4.8 -5.2 -5.6 Financial and Capital Account (% of GDP) 8.0 2.9 4.7 4.2 4.7 5.1 Net Foreign Direct Investment (% of GDP) 3.5 1.3 2.6 2.7 3.3 3.4 Fiscal Balance (% of GDP) -2.2 -1.8 -0.8 -3.0 -2.5 -2.2 Debt (% of GDP) 46.4 43.8 38.9 39.2 38.7 38.1 Primary Balance (% of GDP) -1.5 -0.7 0.3 -2.1 -1.6 -1.3 International poverty rate ($1.9 in 2011 PPP) a,b 0.0 0.2 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 Lower middle-income poverty rate ($3.2 in 2011 PPP) a,b 1.4 1.3 0.9 0.6 0.4 0.3 Upper middle-income poverty rate ($5.5 in 2011 PPP) a,b 16.3 16.5 15.0 13.6 12.3 11.2 So urce: Wo rld B ank, P o verty & Equity and M acro eco no mics, Trade & Investment Glo bal P ractices. No tes: e = estimate, f = fo recast. (a) Calculatio ns based o n ECA P OV harmo nizatio n, using 201 1-HB S and 201 6-HB S. A ctual data: 2015, 2016. No wcast: 2017. Fo recast are fro m 2018 to 2020. (b) P ro jectio n using annualized elasticity (2011-2016) with pass-thro ugh = 0.87 based o n private co nsumptio n per capita in co nstant LCU. MPO 65 Apr 18 Selected Country Pages ●  79 points--first such decline since late 2013, MONTENEGRO Recent developments due to agriculture, mining industry, retail and real estate. While the registered un- employment rate increased to above 22 The economy grew by 4.3 percent in 2017. percent in 2017, given the large informali- Investment made the strongest contribu- ty (one out of three jobs), the survey-based Table 1 2017 tion to growth at 5 percentage points (pp), unemployment rate shows a decline by P o pulatio n, millio n 0.6 as the construction of the Bar-Boljare over 1 pp, to 16.1 percent by September GDP , current US$ billio n 4.7 highway and residential construction 2017 (a four-quarter average). Survey- GDP per capita, current US$ 7528 accelerated. Consumption also grew, con- based employment rate grew by one per- Upper middle-inco me po verty rate ($ 5.5) a 4.8 tributing an additional 3.7 percentage centage point to 45.9 percent along with Gini co efficient a 31.9 points, supported by employment and the activity rate, albeit at a slower pace. Scho o l enro llment, primary (% gro ss) b 94.3 wage growth. Net exports continued to Poverty is estimated to have declined in b 76.9 contribute negatively to growth, but in the past few years as economic growth Life expectancy at birth, years 2017 subtracted less from growth due to a picked up and social transfers surged. In Source: WDI, M acro Poverty Outlook, and official data. record tourism season and a pickup in 2017, however, it was difficult to achieve Notes: (a) M ost recent value (2014), 2011 PPPs. goods exports from the metal industry, significant poverty reduction given the (b) M ost recent WDI value (2015). driven by improved EU demand. Due to withdrawal of the mothers’ benefit in the high import content, the growth impact of second half of the year. Additionally, led the higher investment for highway con- by public sector wage dynamics, real struction is subdued. gross wages declined by 0.4 percent in Credit growth increased by close to 12 2017. Poverty (measured as consumption Economic growth accelerated in 2017 due percent in 2017, as household lending below the standardized middle-income- to surge in investment led by the highway surged, amid subdued corporate lending. country poverty line of $5.5/day in 2011 construction and a historically strong NPLs declined to 7 percent of total loans, PPP terms) declined from 8.7 percent in supported by relaxed voluntary financial 2012 to an estimated 4.4 percent in 2017. tourism season. Employment increased restructuring rules. Current account deficit Inflation picked up in 2017 to 2.4 percent continuing four years of growth. Howev- further widened to 18.9 percent of GDP in on the back of rise in excises on tobacco, er, unemployment remains high amid 2017 on the back of rising construction- alcohol and sugary drinks, and spillovers high informality and increased labor im- related imports and despite rise in exports from international oil and food price. Due of metals, mineral ore sales, and tourism. to the increase in the VAT rate from 19 to ports. Labor force participation increased Net FDI inflows increased to 11.2 percent 21 percent, and excises on tobacco and slightly led by male activation. While of GDP, financing two-thirds of the CAD. alcohol, inflation increased by 2.6 percent fiscal consolidation efforts are underway, Still, after a decline in 2016 to 160 percent, yoy in January 2018. led by tax changes, high deficit and public external debt increased again in 2017 to an Government launched an ambitious fiscal debt require continued efforts. The im- estimated 162 percent of GDP and remains consolidation program in 2017 reducing the highest in the region. the deficit by one percentage point of proved credit rating outlook is providing Robust growth led to employment rise by GDP in 2017 compared to a no-reform easier access to capital market. 2.5 percent in 2017; however, it slowed scenario. By December, tax revenues in- down in the last quarter by 0.2 percentage creased by over 9 percent y-o-y led by FIGURE 1 Montenegro / Real GDP growth and contributions FIGURE 2 Montenegro / Actual and projected poverty rates to real GDP growth and real private consumption per capita Percent, percentage points Poverty rate (%) Private consumption per capita (constant LCU) 10 12 3000 8 6 10 2500 4 2 8 2000 0 6 1500 -2 -4 4 1000 -6 -8 2 500 -10 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018f 0 0 Final consumption Gross fixed capital formation 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017 2019 Change in inventories Net exports GDP growth Upper middle-income pov. rate Consumption pc Sources: MONSTAT, World Bank. Sources: World Bank (see notes to Table 2). MPO 66 Apr 18 80  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 improved collection of VAT and excises. investment will slow down as the high- construction is completed in 2019, growth Spending increased by close to 12 percent way construction gets to its closure, its will slow unless productivity gains and on the back of tripled capital budget. On contribution to growth will remain strong new private sector investments realize. the other hand, wage reduction and abol- in 2018. Current imbalances are likely to Large fiscal deficit and growing public ishment of the mothers’ benefit from the stay high given the import dependence of debt call for the decisive implementation second half of 2017 helped decelerate the current growth pattern. of the recently adopted fiscal consolida- growth of the wage bill and social trans- Inflation is projected at 2.5 percent in the tion program. The fiscal framework that fers. Consequently, general government period 2018-19, as the VAT rate rise adds aims to have a balanced budget by 2019, deficit increased from 3.1 percent in 2016 to the current inflation growth in 2018. from over 5 percent deficit in 2017, will to an estimated 5.2 percent of GDP in Fiscal deficit is projected to be brought require credible spending consolidation in 2017. Public debt including guarantees down to 3.2 percent in 2018, and slowly wage bill, social transfers, and operational increased to 74 percent of GDP by end- reaching surplus by 2020. costs to put public deficit and debt on a 2017. After the initial fiscal consolidation With the potential poverty impact of fiscal sustainable trajectory. efforts, outlook on the credit rating of B+ consolidation measures, in 2018 poverty is External imbalances are still high, adding improved to stable. This has allowed easi- expected to slightly increase as mothers’ to an already high external vulnerability. er access to capital market for a regular benefits phase out. Poverty is likely to Enhancing policy predictability and accel- refinancing of liabilities coming due in resume its decline in 2019-20 to an esti- erating the pace of structural reforms, 2018 and 2019-2021. mated 4.4 percent by 2020, subject to im- would be needed for their moderation. provements in private sector employment Reducing unemployment, especially for and earnings. youth and mitigating short -term poverty Outlook and social impacts of fiscal consolidation and facilitating access to employment The economy is expected to grow by an Risks and challenges need to be an important part of the poli- cy agenda. average of 2.5 percent annually in 2018-20 on the back of public investments and The positive economic outlook faces high, personal consumption. While growth of but moderating risks. As the highway TABLE 2 Montenegro / Macro poverty outlook indicators (annual percent change unless indicated otherwise) 2015 2016 2017 e 2018 f 2019 f 2020 f Real GDP growth, at constant market prices 3.4 2.9 4.3 2.8 2.5 2.1 Private Consumption 2.2 5.4 4.2 2.1 3.3 3.6 Government Consumption 1.9 0.8 1.3 -3.6 -1.9 1.9 Gross Fixed Capital Investment 11.9 27.5 15.8 9.0 1.7 -3.2 Exports, Goods and Services 5.7 6.2 4.1 4.3 5.5 6.1 Imports, Goods and Services 4.4 15.0 8.2 4.0 3.5 3.3 Real GDP growth, at constant factor prices 3.8 2.9 4.3 2.8 2.5 2.1 Agriculture 2.1 3.9 5.1 2.1 2.1 2.1 Industry 3.3 25.8 -2.2 3.0 3.2 3.5 Services 4.8 -20.6 14.6 2.8 1.7 0.2 Inflation (Consumer Price Index) 1.5 -0.3 2.4 3.1 2.1 1.6 Current Account Balance (% of GDP) -13.2 -18.1 -18.9 -18.5 -17.9 -17.3 Financial and Capital Account (% of GDP) 9.3 12.4 15.5 15.2 14.8 14.3 Net Foreign Direct Investment (% of GDP) 16.9 9.4 11.4 11.3 10.9 9.3 Fiscal Balance (% of GDP) -7.3 -3.1 -5.4 -3.1 -0.6 2.2 Debt (% of GDP) 66.2 64.4 66.3 70.5 68.1 63.3 Primary Balance (% of GDP) -4.9 -1.0 -3.0 -0.8 1.8 4.6 Upper middle-income poverty rate ($5.5 in 2011 PPP) a,b 4.6 4.2 4.4 4.8 4.6 4.4 So urce: Wo rld B ank, P o verty & Equity and M acro eco no mics, Trade & Investment Glo bal P ractices. No tes: e = estimate, f = fo recast. (a) Calculatio ns based o n ECA P OV harmo nizatio n, using 2009-HB S and 201 4-HB S. A ctual data: 2014. No wcast: 2015 - 2017. Fo recast are fro m 2018 to 2020. (b) P ro jectio n using po int-to -po int elasticity (2009-2014) with pass-thro ugh = 0.4 based o n private co nsumptio n per capita in co nstant LCU, with estimated impact o f fiscal co nso lidatio n. MPO 67 Apr 18 Selected Country Pages ●  81 continued to rise and labor shortages have POLAND Recent developments started to affect business activity. After two years of persistent deflation, consumer prices rose an average of 2 per- Booming domestic demand boosted real cent in 2017, mainly because of higher GDP growth to 4.6 percent in 2017, from global commodity prices, food inflation Table 1 2017 2.9 percent in 2016. Powered by an ex- and firmer domestic demand. At 2.1 per- P o pulatio n, millio n 37.9 tremely strong labor market and social cent year on year in December 2017, infla- GDP , current US$ billio n 504.7 spending (mainly for the Family 500+ pro- tion is still below the National Bank of GDP per capita, current US$ 13306 gram), private consumption grew by 4.8 Poland (NBP) medium-term target of 2.5 Internatio nal po verty rate ($ 1.9) a 0.4 percent, adding 2.8 percentage points to percent. Demand-side price pressures are Lo wer middle-inco me po verty rate ($ 3.2) a 0.8 GDP growth. modest so far, with core inflation just 0.9 Upper middle-inco me po verty rate ($ 5.5) a 2.6 The biggest positive development in 2017 percent year on year in December. Real a 31.8 was a 5.4 percent expansion in gross fixed monetary conditions eased considerably Gini co efficient b investment. This was a remarkable recov- in 2017, despite nominal appreciation of Life expectancy at birth, years 78.2 ery from a 7.9 percent drop in 2016 caused the zloty. Since March 2015 the NBP Mon- Source: WDI, M acro Poverty Outlook, and official data. by a cyclical fall in EU-funded projects, etary Policy Council has kept its bench- Notes: (a) M ost recent value (2015), 2011 PPPs. reduced FDI inflow, and elevated political mark policy rate unchanged at 1.5 percent. (b) M ost recent WDI value (2015). risk. The rebound in investment resulted The zloty continued to be somewhat vola- from the resumption of EU funding and tile in 2017 but strengthened overall removal of a source of instability in the against the euro and the US dollar. banking sector related to the conversion of It is estimated that poverty and shared foreign-currency-denominated mortgages prosperity indicators continued to im- Real GDP growth picked up to 4.6 per- to local currency. prove in 2017 in light of surging private cent in 2017, driven primarily by private The renewed investment helped to consumption supported by a tight labor consumption. A recovery in investment boost import demand in the second half market and government social pro- of the year. Hence, despite heavy de- grams. Poverty is expected to have de- in the end of 2017 promises continued mand for Poland ’s exports from outside clined from 2.7 percent in 2015 to 1.3 growth. The main risks to medium term of the euro zone, net exports contribut- percent in 2017 using the $5.50/day 2011 growth relate to labor shortages and lower ed just 0.1 percentage points to overall PPP poverty line. allocation of EU funds for Poland. Pov- GDP growth. More efficient tax collection helped the gov- erty will continue to decline in line with Labor market conditions have tightened ernment to realize its ambitious 2017 spend- further. The ratio of vacancies to unem- ing plans while running the tightest budget growing disposable incomes. Although ployment has shot past 10 percent; in execution on record. This was possible be- the general deficit is at a record low, four years the number of low-skilled un- cause more was collected in taxes, mostly structural weakening is possible. Fiscal employed has been cut in half and now from indirect taxes (due to robust private adjustment may constitute a challenge as accounts for just 30 percent of unemploy- consumption and improved tax compli- ment; and, for the first time since the ance) but also from one-off non-tax reve- Poland prepares for elections. transition, long-term unemployment nues, such as higher NBP profits. In 2016 dipped below 500,000. Employment rates the general government deficit narrowed to FIGURE 1 Poland / Real GDP growth and contributions to FIGURE 2 Poland / Actual and projected poverty rates and real GDP growth real private consumption per capita Percent, percentage points Poverty rate (%) Private consumption per capita (constant LCU) 6.0 14 35000 5.0 4.6 5.0 4.2 3.8 3.7 12 30000 3.6 3.5 4.0 3.3 2.9 10 25000 3.0 1.6 1.4 8 20000 2.0 1.0 6 15000 0.0 4 10000 -1.0 2 5000 -2.0 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017e 2018f 2019f 2020f 0 0 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020 Final consumption Gross Fixed Investment Change in inventories Net exports International poverty rate Lower middle-income pov. rate Statistical Discrepancy GDP growth Upper middle-income pov. rate Consumption pc Sources: MFMod, World Bank. Sources: World Bank (see notes to Table 2). MPO 68 Apr 18 82  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 a 1.6 percent of GDP, a record low, after cycle leading up to the elections. High hitting 2.5 percent in 2016. Despite the zloty appreciating against the corporate profitability and EU funds should support private investment. Ex- Risks and challenges euro and heightened domestic demand, ports and industrial production are like- the strong performance of exports man- ly to benefit from stronger European There are three main clouds on Poland’s aged in 2017 to lift the current account to a demand in 2018-19, but imports may economic horizon: (i) Structural weaken- surplus of 0.1 percent of GDP. outpace both. ing in public finance; (ii) a shortage of la- The general government deficit is set to bor; and (iii) EU sanctions against Poland widen again in 2018 to about 2 percent of for not respecting EU democratic values. Outlook GDP—but still safely below the 3 per- cent EU threshold. Spending is expected First, the government's spending plans, with increases in social benefits and public to rise due to higher government con- investment, and the reduction in the statu- In light of the positive investment results sumption, local pre -elections investment, tory retirement age, could erode the struc- in 2017 and improved growth prospects and the decision to roll back the planned ture of public finances. Strengthening the in the EU, the previous projection of real increases of the retirement age. The reve- fiscal position might be difficult given lo- GDP growth for Poland has been revised nue side will also contribute to the in- cal, presidential, and parliamentary elec- upward by 0.2 percentage points: again, creasing budget gap: non -tax revenues tions all coming up within 18 months. Sec- driven by both private consumption and could be lower this year due to less NBP ond, the shortage of labor may soon weigh investment; economic growth may reach profit, and the change in retirement age heavily on GDP growth, and would be 4.2 percent in 2018 and 3.7 percent in will depress social contributions from exacerbated by retirement of a greater part 2019. Household spending will benefit the cohort eligible for earlier retirement. of the workforce. Too few workers could from growth in the real wage bill of Public debt will stabilize around 51 per- negatively affect production capacities and more than 8 percent in 2018 -19, plus cent of GDP in 2018-19, but the structur- investment. This would heighten pressure higher state spending on pensions and al budget deficit will widen. on the government to encourage immigra- social benefits. Rising real incomes are The current -account is likely to come tion, which could come primarily from expected to lead to further declines in back to a small deficit in 2018 as robust Ukraine. Third, the government's failure to poverty. The $5.50/ day 2011 PPP pov- household consumption, higher invest- address rule of law issues and a vote by erty rate is projected to decline to 1.2 ment, and a firming in global commodity the European Parliament in late 2017 to percent in 2018 and further to 1.0 percent markets push up the volume and cost of initiate Article 7 proceedings against Po- by 2020. imports. Nonetheless, the current - land may lead the EU to impose sanctions, Public spending is likely to be strong, account deficit will remain modest in possibly lowering the EU fund allocation supported by EU funds and the political 2018-20 at less than 0.5 percent of GDP. for 2021–27. TABLE 2 Poland / Macro poverty outlook indicators (annual percent change unless indicated otherwise) 2015 2016 2017 e 2018 f 2019 f 2020 f Real GDP growth, at constant market prices 3.8 2.9 4.6 4.2 3.7 3.5 Private Consumption 3.0 3.9 4.8 4.0 3.7 3.3 Government Consumption 2.4 1.7 3.1 3.7 3.0 3.2 Gross Fixed Capital Investment 6.1 -7.9 5.4 6.7 6.4 6.1 Exports, Goods and Services 7.7 8.8 7.1 6.2 5.2 5.4 Imports, Goods and Services 6.6 7.9 7.3 6.7 5.9 5.9 Real GDP growth, at constant factor prices 3.7 2.8 4.2 4.3 3.7 3.5 Agriculture -8.5 2.8 1.8 2.2 2.2 2.2 Industry 3.8 3.6 4.5 4.1 4.1 4.1 Services 4.1 2.6 4.2 4.4 3.7 3.3 Inflation (Consumer Price Index) -1.0 -0.6 2.0 2.3 2.5 2.5 Current Account Balance (% of GDP) -0.5 -0.3 0.1 -0.3 -0.3 -0.1 Financial and Capital Account (% of GDP) 2.2 5.4 2.9 2.4 1.9 1.8 Net Foreign Direct Investment (% of GDP) 1.9 1.1 1.0 1.5 1.6 1.5 Fiscal Balance (% of GDP) -2.6 -2.5 -1.6 -2.1 -2.6 -2.9 Debt (% of GDP) 51.1 54.1 53.1 51.7 51.0 50.7 Primary Balance (% of GDP) -0.9 -0.8 0.2 -0.3 -0.8 -1.1 International poverty rate ($1.9 in 2011 PPP) a,b 0.4 0.4 0.3 0.3 0.3 0.3 Lower middle-income poverty rate ($3.2 in 2011 PPP) a,b 0.8 0.6 0.6 0.5 0.5 0.5 Upper middle-income poverty rate ($5.5 in 2011 PPP) a,b 2.6 1.7 1.3 1.2 1.1 1.0 So urce: Wo rld B ank, P o verty & Equity and M acro eco no mics, Trade & Investment Glo bal P ractices. No tes: e = estimate, f = fo recast. (a) Calculatio ns based o n EU-SILC harmo nizatio n, using 2004-EU-SILC and 201 5-EU-SILC. A ctual data: 2015. No wcast: 2016 - 2017. Fo recast are fro m 2018 to 2020. (b) P ro jectio n using po int-to -po int elasticity (2004-2015) with pass-thro ugh = 1based o n private co nsumptio n per capita in co nstant LCU. MPO 69 Apr 18 Selected Country Pages ●  83 3.4 percent of GDP at end-2017 reflecting ROMANIA Recent developments the strong imports growth. The labor market benefited from the eco- nomic growth, with unemployment fall- Private consumption (+8.8 percent) was ing to 4.6 percent as of December 2017 – a the main driver of growth in 2017, fueled 25-year low – and real wages increasing Table 1 2017 by tax cuts; hikes in minimum and public- by 8.1 percent. Nonetheless, the low em- P o pulatio n, millio n 19.6 sector wages; and increases in pensions ployment rate of 65.3 in Q3 2017, down 0.2 GDP , current US$ billio n 206.9 that boosted disposable incomes. With a percentage points from the previous quar- GDP per capita, current US$ 10563 5.4 percent increase, investment also ter, reflects persistent structural rigidities Upper middle-inco me po verty rate ($ 5.5) a 25.6 showed signs of recovery. Exports grew in the labor market. Gini co efficient a 35.9 strongly (+9.5 percent), but were outpaced In line with economic growth, a boost in Scho o l enro llment, primary (% gro ss) b 89.8 by imports (+11.1 percent). On the produc- private consumption and labor market b 75.0 tion side, ICT (+10.9 percent) and industry improvements, the poverty rate corre- Life expectancy at birth, years (+8 percent) were the main drivers of sponding to upper middle-income coun- Source: WDI, M acro Poverty Outlook, and official data. Notes: growth, with agriculture (+18.3 percent) tries (using the $5.50/day 2011 PPP pov- (a) M ost recent value (2015), 2011 PPPs. performing better than expected, facilitat- erty line) is estimated to have declined (b) M ost recent WDI value (2014). ed by good weather conditions. from 26.1 percent in 2015 to 23.6 percent Fiscal policy was pro-cyclical in 2017. In- in 2017, continuing its downward path creases in public wages and pensions led since the peak of the crisis in 2011 (31.7 to a 22 percent hike in the compensation percent). High poverty incidence contin- of employees and a 15.5 percent increase ues to be associated with reliance on agri- Private consumption propelled growth to 7 in current spending, outpacing fiscal reve- culture and in rural/marginalized areas. nue growth (+12.5 percent). The deficit, Employment gains in sectors that employ percent in 2017. Growth was supported by however, remained below 3 percent of a large share of low-skilled people have an expansionary fiscal policy, that coincid- GDP because of the decline in public in- helped improve the incomes of the bottom ed with an increase in exports to a resur- vestment (-9.5 percent), including low 40 and prevented a further increase in the gent EU. Improvements in the labor mar- utilization of the EU funds. Gini index in 2015. ket contributed to poverty reduction. The expansionary fiscal policy led to an overheating of the economy, contributing Growth will remain solid in 2018, but medium-term risks to the outlook have also to inflation to 4.7 percent in February 2018 – above the upper limit of the Na- Outlook increased. Pressures on the budget deficit, tional Bank of Romania (NBR) band. In arising from an increase in recurrent response, the NBR board increased the The economy is projected to continue to policy rate by 25 ppts (to 2.25 percent) in grow above potential in 2018. GDP will spending, will continue in 2018. To im- two consecutive meetings in early 2018. likely expand by around 5.1 percent in prove the quality of growth, renewed atten- This came amid robust private sector cred- 2018, driven by the fiscal stimulus and tion should be given to public investment. it growth (up 5.6 percent as of December aided by a resurgent EU. Continued 2017) and concerns over the fiscal stance. growth in consumption is expected to The current account deficit deteriorated to widen the current account deficit to 4.3 FIGURE 1 Romania / Real GDP growth and contributions to FIGURE 2 Romania / Actual and projected poverty rates and real GDP growth real GDP per capita Percent, percentage points Poverty rate (%) GDP per capita (constant LCU) 12 45 10000 10 40 9000 8 8000 35 6 7000 30 4 6000 25 2 5000 20 0 4000 -2 15 3000 -4 10 2000 -6 5 1000 2014 2015 2016 2017e 2018f 2019f 2020f 0 0 Net exports Private Consumption 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020 Gross fixed capital formation Public Consumption GDP Upper middle-income pov. rate GDP pc Sources: World Bank, Romanian National Statistical Institute. Sources: World Bank. Notes: see Table 2. MPO 70 Apr 18 84  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 percent in 2018. Inflation is set to peak at growth in real wages, partly supported by likely tapering of the quantitative easing around 5 percent in mid-2018 reflecting minimum wage increases, should boost in the Eurozone and higher global interest the excess domestic demand and the fad- real incomes and lead to further declines rates may lead to a repositioning in inves- ing out of the base effect of the tax cuts. in poverty incidence. Moreover, the tor sentiment towards the emerging econ- The NBR anticipates a gradual subsequent planned introduction of the Minimum omies and to higher refinancing costs, decline in inflation towards 3.5 percent at Social Inclusion Income program (MSII) is further reinforcing fiscal pressures. On the the end of 2018, due to a slowdown in expected to improve targeting and in- upside, a better-than-projected economic private consumption dynamics as no fur- crease the level of benefits for the most performance of the Eurozone will act as a ther fiscal boost to households’ real dis- vulnerable. The $5.50/day 2011 PPP pov- driver of growth in the broader EU area, posable income is envisioned. erty rate is projected to decline to 22.6 including Romania. The fiscal measures passed in 2017 have percent in 2018, 21.7 percent in 2019, and Renewed efforts are needed to improve put pressure on the consolidated budget 20.9 percent in 2020. labor participation and generate broad - deficit. In the absence of corrective based employment, as unemployment measures, the fiscal deficit is projected to remains high among youth and the low - reach 3.3 percent of GDP in 2018, which would place Romania on a trajectory to re- Risks and challenges skilled, and to ensure that all Romanians obtain access to high quality public ser- entering the Excessive Deficit Procedure vices. Gradually, the focus of the fiscal of the EU. However, the government has Accumulating fiscal pressures and excess policy should be rebalanced away from stated that, like in 2017, it would be ready domestic demand limit the space for poli- boosting consumption towards mobiliz- to promote adjustment measures should cy-makers to maneuver in 2018 and be- ing investment, including from the EU the deficit threaten the 3 percent ceiling. yond. The current account deficit is on the funds, to support a sustainable EU con- The widening of the fiscal deficit would rise, and inflationary pressures persist. vergence path and social inclusion. Re- push public debt to 46.8 percent of GDP at These developments leave the Romanian forms in public administration and end-2020, from 44.5 percent in 2017. De- economy vulnerable to exogenous shocks. SOEs, increased regulatory predictabil- spite this, public debt remains one of the The authorities may need to take correc- ity, as well as policies to address the lowest in the EU. tive measures to keep the deficit below 3 large social and spatial discrepancies Strong private consumption aided by the percent of GDP in 2018 through good should be on the agenda of priorities of expansionary fiscal policy and continued quality fiscal adjustment. Externally, a the government. TABLE 2 Romania / Macro poverty outlook indicators (annual percent change unless indicated otherwise) 2015 2016 2017 e 2018 f 2019 f 2020 f Real GDP growth, at constant market prices 3.9 4.8 7.0 5.1 4.5 4.1 Private Consumption 5.7 7.1 8.8 8.1 7.2 6.6 Government Consumption -0.8 4.8 6.2 5.9 5.4 5.1 Gross Fixed Capital Investment 7.2 0.8 5.4 6.2 5.1 4.8 Exports, Goods and Services 5.3 7.6 9.5 8.3 7.1 7.0 Imports, Goods and Services 9.4 9.7 11.1 9.7 8.4 8.1 Real GDP growth, at constant factor prices 3.6 4.6 7.0 5.1 4.5 4.1 Agriculture -11.1 -0.8 18.3 3.0 2.1 2.0 Industry 6.1 0.4 8.0 6.1 5.2 4.6 Services 4.3 8.1 5.0 4.8 4.4 4.1 Inflation (Consumer Price Index) -0.6 -1.5 1.3 3.7 3.2 3.0 Current Account Balance (% of GDP) -1.2 -2.6 -3.4 -4.3 -4.7 -4.9 Financial and Capital Account (% of GDP) 1.4 2.7 3.5 4.4 4.8 5.0 Net Foreign Direct Investment (% of GDP) 1.8 1.8 2.5 3.1 3.0 3.0 Fiscal Balance (% of GDP) -1.5 -2.7 -2.9 -3.3 -3.0 -3.0 Debt (% of GDP) 39.4 44.5 44.5 45.6 46.3 46.8 Primary Balance (% of GDP) -0.1 -1.3 -1.5 -1.9 -1.5 -1.4 Upper middle-income poverty rate ($5.5 in 2011 PPP) a,b,c 26.1 25.0 23.6 22.6 21.7 20.9 So urce: Wo rld B ank, P o verty & Equity and M acro eco no mics, Trade & Investment Glo bal P ractices. No tes: e = estimate, f = fo recast. (a) Calculatio ns based o n EU-SILC harmo nizatio n, using 2007-EU-SILC, 201 2-EU-SILC, and 2015-EU-SILC. (b) P ro jectio n using annualized elasticity (2007-2012) with pass-thro ugh = 0.7 based o n GDP per capita in co nstant LCU. (c) A ctual data: 201 5. No wcast: 2016 - 2017. Fo recast are fro m 2018 to 2020. MPO 71 Apr 18 Selected Country Pages ●  85 another systemically important private RUSSIAN Recent developments bank (Promsvyazbank, 1.6 percent share by assets) was bailed out by CBR. That made it the third bank to be rescued un- FEDERATION In 2017, Russia’s economy emerged from recession to recovery, with the GDP ex- der a new resolution mechanism. As a result, the share of state-controlled banks panding by 1.5 percent year-on-year. in the combined assets of the Russian Deepening macro-economic stability, banking system has increased to 66.2 per- Table 1 2017 firming energy prices and a recovering cent, most of them under CBR ownership GDP , current US$ billio n 1578.6 global economy contributed to the return (45 percent of assets). This may affect the to growth. Non-tradable sectors, primari- level playing-field and pose a conflict of GDP per capita, current US$ 10771 a ly transportation, retail and wholesale interest between the CBR’s regulatory and Internatio nal po verty rate ($ 1.9) 0.0 a trade, contributed 1.4 percentage points ownership functions. Lo wer middle-inco me po verty rate ($ 3.2) 0.3 (pp) of the 1.5 percent total. Mineral - In 2017, credit grew both in retail and cor- a Upper middle-inco me po verty rate ($ 5.5) 2.7 resource extraction increased by 1.4 per- porate segments (13.3 percent and 3.8 per- a Gini co efficient 37.7 cent, year-on-year, as oil production cent, year-on-year, respectively). The Scho o l enro llment, primary (% gro ss) b 100.5 flattened after Russia joined the OPEC+ share of non-performing loans remained Life expectancy at birth, years b 70.9 agreement. Growth in manufacturing was stable—but high—at 10 percent as of Janu- WDI, M PO, Rosstat, and Bank of Russia. subdued, partly due to lower public ary 1, 2018, and the overall banking sector Notes: spending on defense. capital adequacy ratio was also stable at (a) M ost recent value (2015), 2011 PPPs. Domestic demand was the main engine of 12.1 percent. However, compared to other (b) M ost recent WDI value (2015). growth. Both household and investment emerging markets, both figures point to demand expanded. Private consumption, underlying vulnerabilities in Russia. As of supported by growing real wages and January 1, 2018, profitability in the bank- Russia’s economy has emerged from reces- pensions and by a revival of credit to ing sector declined to 2016 levels, with the sion to recovery, supported by deepening households, contributed 1.8 pp to growth. return on assets and equity at 1 percent Fixed-capital investment in mineral re- and 8.3 percent, respectively. macro-economic stability, firming energy source extraction, transportation, and in The CBR continued its gradual approach prices and global recovery. Growth is pro- the financial sector, mainly supported to monetary easing aimed at anchoring jected to settle between 1.7 and 1.8 percent investment growth. However, growth in inflation expectations. A combination of a in 2018 — 2020. However, many house- manufacturing was not followed by fixed stronger ruble and a bumper harvest, and capital investment growth. While robust relatively tight monetary and fiscal policy, holds remain close to the poverty line, and external demand supported the country’s helped reach record-low inflation levels. many individuals lack formal jobs. Priori- exports, a major increase in imports result- In 2017, consumer inflation reached 3.7 ty policy objectives include limiting the ed in a negative contribution of net ex- percent (year-on-year, 12-month average), role of the state in the economy, increasing ports to GDP growth. down from 7.1 percent in 2016. investment, and promoting fair competi- The Central Bank of Russia (CBR) contin- In 2017, the current account surplus ued to clean up the banking sector: 16 reached US$40.2 billion, strengthened by tion, as well as measures to improve in- banks had their licenses revoked due to an improved trade balance, and was mir- vestments in human capital. non-compliance with regulations, and rored by higher net capital outflows, FIGURE 1 Russian Federation/ Real GDP growth and FIGURE 2 Russian Federation / Actual and projected contributions to real GDP growth poverty rates and real private consumption per capita Percent, percentage points Poverty rate (%) Private consumption per capita (constant LCU) 8 30 300000 6 4 25 250000 2 20 200000 0 -2 15 150000 -4 -6 10 100000 -8 5 50000 -10 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 0 0 Consumption Gross fixed capital formation 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017 2019 Change in inventories Export Import Stat error International poverty rate Lower middle-income pov. rate GDP growth Upper middle-income pov. rate Consumption pc Sources: Russia Statistical Authorities and World Bank staff Calculations. Sources: World Bank (see notes to Table 2). MPO 72 Apr 18 86  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 mainly from the banking sector, which The poverty rate under the national defini- driver of income growth for the bottom 40 continued its external-debt repayments. tion (population share with income per percent. Wage growth and pension indexa- International reserves increased by capita below subsistence minimum level of tion at the inflation level, will support dis- US$15.4 billion mainly on the back of cur- 9,828 rubles per month in 2016) increased posable incomes and contribute to a gradual rency purchases conducted by the CBR on marginally from 13.3 percent in 2015 to decline in the poverty rate. However, many behalf of Ministry of Finance. 13.4 percent in 2016. The international households remain close to the poverty line, The general government fiscal stance im- moderate poverty rate (population share and many individuals lack formal jobs. proved in 2017, aided by higher oil prices, with per capita consumption below 5.5 a recovering economy, an improved tax USD/day in 2011 PPP) increased from 2.7 administration, and lower expenditures. The general government primary budget percent in 2015 to an estimated 3.3 percent in 2016, before decreasing to an estimated Risks and challenges deficit narrowed from 2.8 percent of GDP 2.9 percent in 2017, as wages and pensions in 2016 to 0.6 percent of GDP in 2017. Rus- increased. The extreme poverty rate re- External downside risks stem from a sig- sia’s new fiscal rule, expected to reduce mained marginal, below one percent. nificant drop in oil prices, a sudden tight- the influence of external volatility on the ening of global financial conditions and an budget and the real exchange rate, comes expansion of sanctions. into effect in 2019 and will require fiscal consolidation in 2018-20. Combined with Outlook The performance of the banking sector is expected to remain stable. However, the the move towards inflation-targeting, it bailout of three large private banks points underscores the Russian authorities’ com- Amid the recovered oil prices, macro sta- to the continuing fragility in the sector, and mitment to enhance macro-stability. bilization and improved business and the quality of capital and assets, and related Unemployment declined further in 2017 consumer confidence, we expect Russia’s -party lending will likely remain a concern. to a current 5.2 percent, while real wages economy to keep growing. With the ex- Weak productivity growth and a shrinking and pensions increased on the back of pected price of oil remaining robust at labor force will constrain GDP growth. low inflation. Wage growth was highest US$58, 59 and 60/bbl in 2018, 2019, and Priority policy objectives include limiting in the tradable sector and above the rate 2020 respectively, our growth estimates the role of the state in the economy, in- of inflation in the non-tradable and pub- stand at 1.7 percent in 2018, 1.8 percent in creasing investment, and promoting fair lic sectors. However, growth in real dis- 2019 and 1.8 percent in 2020. competition. Also, measures to improve posable incomes remained negative, The moderate poverty rate is expected to the quality of and access to health and driven by a decline in income from other fall in 2018 and further through 2019. As education services will be needed to pro- sources, including some not directly reg- public spending is constrained, labor in- mote longer and more productive work- istered by statistics. come will become the most important ing lives. TABLE 2 Russian Federation / Macro poverty outlook indicators (annual percent change unless indicated otherwise) 2015 2016 2017 e 2018 f 2019 f 2020 f Real GDP growth, at constant market prices -2.5 -0.2 1.5 1.7 1.8 1.8 Private Consumption -9.4 -2.8 3.4 3.1 2.5 2.5 Government Consumption -3.1 0.9 -0.9 -0.6 -0.5 0.0 Gross Fixed Capital Investment -11.2 0.8 3.6 2.7 2.7 2.7 Exports, Goods and Services 3.7 3.2 5.4 2.0 3.0 3.0 Imports, Goods and Services -25.1 -3.6 17.0 7.0 4.0 4.0 Real GDP growth, at constant factor prices -1.9 0.0 1.6 1.7 1.8 1.8 Agriculture 2.5 2.9 1.2 1.7 1.7 1.7 Industry -2.4 0.4 0.6 1.1 1.6 1.6 Services -2.0 -0.5 2.2 2.0 1.9 1.9 Inflation (Consumer Price Index) 15.5 7.1 3.7 3.2 4.0 4.0 Current Account Balance (% of GDP) 5.0 2.0 2.5 2.9 2.8 2.7 Financial and Capital Account (% of GDP) -5.2 -1.6 -2.8 -2.9 -2.8 -2.7 Net Foreign Direct Investment (% of GDP) -1.1 0.8 -0.4 -0.5 -0.5 -0.5 Fiscal Balance (% of GDP)a -3.4 -3.5 -1.6 -0.3 0.7 0.7 Debt (% of GDP) 15.9 15.7 15.1 15.6 16.1 16.3 Primary Balance (% of GDP) a -2.6 -2.6 -0.7 0.6 1.6 1.6 International poverty rate ($1.9 in 2011 PPP) b,c 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 Lower middle-income poverty rate ($3.2 in 2011 PPP) b,c 0.3 0.3 0.3 0.3 0.2 0.2 Upper middle-income poverty rate ($5.5 in 2011 PPP) b,c 2.7 3.3 2.9 2.6 2.4 2.1 So urce: Wo rld B ank, P o verty & Equity and M acro eco no mics, Trade & Investment Glo bal P ractices. No tes: e = estimate, f = fo recast. (a) Fiscal and P rimary B alance refer to general go vernment balances. (b) Calculatio ns based o n ECA P OV harmo nizatio n, using 201 5-HB S. A ctual data: 2015. No wcast: 2016 - 2017. Fo recast are fro m 2018 to 2020. (c) P ro jectio n using neutral distributio n (2015) with pass-thro ugh = 1 based o n private co nsumptio n per capita in co nstant LCU. MPO 73 Apr 18 Selected Country Pages ●  87 salaries increased by 3.9 percent in nomi- SERBIA Recent developments nal terms in 2017 compared to the year before, mainly driven by growth of wages in the private sector (increase of 4.5 per- External, one-off factors, such as the dis- cent). The average pension was 2.4 per- ruption of energy production in early cent higher than in 2016. Table 1 2017 2017 and a drought which affected agri- Since employment and labor income play P o pulatio n, millio n 7.0 culture, coupled with the slow imple- a strong role in influencing welfare of the GDP , current US$ billio n 41.2 mentation of the government ’s invest- poor and vulnerable, poverty (living on GDP per capita, current US$ 5860 ment program, led to slower than previ- income under $5.5/day in 2011PPP terms, Internatio nal po verty rate ($ 1.9) a 5.6 ously-projected growth in 2017. Based on the standardized middle-income-country Lo wer middle-inco me po verty rate ($ 3.2) a 11.1 preliminary assessments from the nation- poverty line) is estimated to have declined a 23.6 al authorities, the economy grew by 1.9 from 23.8 percent in 2014, to 23.1 percent Upper middle-inco me po verty rate ($ 5.5) a percent y/y, compared to previously pro- in 2016, to 22.4 percent in 2017. The in- Gini co efficient 39.7 b jected 2.3 percent. Widening external crease of salaries and public sector pen- Scho o l enro llment, primary (% gro ss) 101.3 b deficit, increase in imports and recovery sions helped household budgets to recov- Life expectancy at birth, years 75.5 in consumption are driving a shift from er some of the losses from previous fiscal Source: WDI, M acro Poverty Outlook, and official data. positive to negative contribution of net - consolidation measures. The energy bill Notes: (a) M ost recent value (2015), 2011 PPPs. exports to growth. discount program for vulnerable popula- (b) M ost recent WDI value (2015). Looking at sectors of the economy, both tions was expanded in 2017 to mitigate the services and industry performed well in impact of increases in electricity tariffs, as 2017, growing by 2.2 and 3.9 percent (in part of fiscal reforms. However, a decline real terms), respectively. Construction in agriculture output in 2017 is likely to Despite a slowdown in economic growth sector started to recover as well (growing have adverse impacts on rural poverty (GDP growth, now estimated at 1.9 per- at 1.8 percent y/y) on the back of recent and slow the pace of poverty reduction cent y/y in 2017), labor market perfor- improvements in issuing construction overall. Also, food prices increased (up by permits and lower financing costs as inter- 4.1 percent through December) more than mance improved and unemployment est rates fell in 2017. On the other hand, the average CPI, in particular over the reached 13.5 percent. The state of public agriculture sector output is estimated to summer months, and likely affecting the finances improved significantly and Ser- have fallen by 9.5 percent (in real terms), poor disproportionately. Overall inflation bia showed a budget surplus in 2017. compared to 2016, due to the drought. reached 3 percent by year-end. Growth in industry and services contribut- A good budget performance continued Poverty is estimated to have declined ed to steady labor market performance in throughout 2017 and Serbia ended up from 23.8 percent in 2014 to 23.1 per- 2017, which improved over 2016. The activ- with a surplus of 1.2 percent of GDP in cent in 2016. Over the medium -term, ity rate increased to 54 percent in 2017 2017. As a result of lower financing needs, growth is expected to reach 3 -4 percent, (annual average) while the employment public debt declined to around 62.5 per- although risks remain, especially from rate stood at 46.7 percent (compare to 45.2 cent of GDP year end, compared to 74 percent in 2016), even with unemployment percent at the end of 2016. Part of the rea- policy reversals related to previous fiscal edging up only slightly in the fourth quar- son for improved budget performance lies stability program. ter of 2017, to reach 14.7 percent. Average in under-execution of the capital budget FIGURE 1 Serbia / General government balance (% of GDP) FIGURE 2 Serbia / Actual and projected poverty rates and real private consumption per capita Percent of GDP Poverty rate (%) Private consumption per capita (constant LCU) 2.00 30 400000 1.00 25 0.00 380000 -1.00 20 360000 -2.00 15 -3.00 340000 -4.00 10 -5.00 320000 5 -6.00 -7.00 0 300000 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020 -8.00 International poverty rate Lower middle-income pov. rate 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020 Upper middle-income pov. rate Consumption pc Sources: WB Staff calculations based on the Ministry of Finance and the Statisti- Sources: World Bank. Notes see Table 2. cal office data. MPO 74 Apr 18 88  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 (down -9.5 percent in 2017, in nominal terms), which however had a negative impact on growth. Outlook Risks and challenges The current account deficit (CAD) al- most doubled (in euro terms) in 2017 (an In 2018 as well as over the medium term, As witnessed over the last couple of years, increase of 94 percent, y/y). This resulted growth is expected to pick up, thus helping Serbian economy is highly vulnerable to in widening trade deficit, as import in- with labor market recovery and poverty climate change related events (droughts, creased significantly (14.2 percent, y/y, reduction. Growth is expected to be driven severe winters, floods, etc.). These external or around EUR 2 billion), because of a by increased investment, stimulated by shocks might reoccur at any moment in higher import of energy and consumer reforms to improve the business climate, the future thus endangering growth pro- goods. The growing external deficit con- and the recovery of consumption (as the jections. Also, such events often hurt more tinued to be financed by FDI, which in- fiscal consolidation program gradually the poor who predominantly live in areas creased by 37.5 percent in euro terms. expires and private sector wages continue less protected from climate-related weath- FDI covers 135 percent of CAD. Foreign to grow). Growth is expected to be around er events and who depend more on in- currency reserves dropped by 243 mil- 3-4 percent over the medium term. come earned in agriculture. In addition, lion euros in 2017. With economic growth and improvements faster growth requires further effort to- The dinar strengthened by 4 percent in the labor market, poverty is expected to ward implementation of structural re- against the euro in 2017, while foreign continue its gradual decline. Poverty, meas- forms: in secondary and tertiary educa- currency reserves decreased by about ured as income below the standardized $5.5/ tion; health financing; privatization of EUR 245 million through December. The day 2011PPP line is estimated to continue remaining state stakes in SOEs and finan- banking sector remains stable and loans to declining to around 21 percent by 2019. As cial institutions. Also, special attention the private sector increased by 3.6 percent part of the government’s fiscal consolidation needs to be paid to expanding external by end-December (y/y), but mainly due to program, another nominal electricity tariff imbalances. Any delay with implantation increase in lending to households (up 7.8 increase in 2018 will be considered, though of these reforms can have a major impact percent, y/y). NPLs declined to 11.1 per- smaller than previous increases. The recent- on growth outlook. In addition, the poten- cent through November, due to more ac- ly expanded energy bill discount program tial distributional impacts of these im- tive role of banks in selling and writing off can help protect vulnerable customers, but portant structural reforms may present NPLs. Still, NPLs represent a significant implementation challenges related to pro- continued challenges to faster poverty problem for state-owned banks. cessing of applications remain. reduction in the short run. TABLE 2 Serbia / Macro poverty outlook indicators (annual percent change unless indicated otherwise) 2015 2016 2017 e 2018 f 2019 f 2020 f Real GDP growth, at constant market prices 0.8 2.8 1.9 3.0 3.5 4.0 Private Consumption 0.5 1.0 1.7 2.2 2.9 4.0 Government Consumption -1.5 2.3 4.0 3.6 -0.4 11.8 Gross Fixed Capital Investment 5.6 5.1 3.7 5.6 7.7 2.9 Exports, Goods and Services 10.2 12.0 8.1 6.5 7.5 7.5 Imports, Goods and Services 9.3 9.0 7.0 5.9 6.4 7.3 Real GDP growth, at constant factor prices 0.7 3.2 1.4 3.0 3.5 4.0 Agriculture -7.7 8.1 -9.9 5.0 3.0 3.0 Industry 3.0 2.4 4.5 4.0 5.0 5.0 Services 1.1 2.8 1.7 2.3 2.9 3.7 Inflation (Consumer Price Index) 1.4 1.1 3.0 3.3 3.5 3.5 Current Account Balance (% of GDP) -4.7 -3.1 -5.7 -4.7 -4.4 -4.6 Financial and Capital Account (% of GDP) 3.9 1.5 4.6 3.1 2.8 2.7 Net Foreign Direct Investment (% of GDP) 3.7 3.7 4.7 4.3 4.3 4.1 Fiscal Balance (% of GDP) -3.6 -1.3 1.2 -0.6 -0.7 -1.2 Debt (% of GDP) 76.0 73.2 62.4 60.0 57.5 55.5 Primary Balance (% of GDP) -0.4 2.2 3.9 2.2 2.2 1.3 International poverty rate ($1.9 in 2011 PPP) a,b 5.6 5.5 5.4 5.3 5.3 5.1 Lower middle-income poverty rate ($3.2 in 2011 PPP) a,b 11.1 10.8 10.6 10.4 10.0 9.6 Upper middle-income poverty rate ($5.5 in 2011 PPP) a,b 23.6 23.1 22.4 21.7 20.9 19.7 So urce: Wo rld B ank, P o verty & Equity and M acro eco no mics, Trade & Investment Glo bal P ractices. No tes: e = estimate, f = fo recast. (a) Calculatio ns based o n EU-SILC harmo nizatio n, using 201 5-EU-SILC. A ctual data: 2015. No wcast: 2016 - 2017. Fo recast are fro m 2018 to 2020. (b) P ro jectio n using neutral distributio n (2015) with pass-thro ugh = 0.87 based o n private co nsumptio n per capita in co nstant LCU. MPO 75 Apr 18 Selected Country Pages ●  89 percent of GDP in investment, while keep- TAJIKISTAN Recent development ing current spending below 18 percent of GDP. The fiscal contraction was attained through cuts of non-priority outlays, de- Real GDP growth accelerated to 7.1 percent lays in implementation of further banking in 2017 from 6.9 percent a year ago. The sector bailouts and contained the overall Table 1 2017 economy was largely fueled by private fiscal stance. Construction of the Rogun P o pulatio n, millio n 8.8 consumption, supported by remittances— HPP was on full track, facilitated by pro- GDP , current US$ billio n 7.2 which expanded by about 16 percent ceeds from the Eurobond issuance in late GDP per capita, current US$ 812 through nine months of 2017, y-o-y—and 2017. The latter increased the level of pub- P o verty rate (LCU 187.7/mo nth) a 29.7 by net exports, boosted by metallic miner- lic debt to above 50 percent of GDP, exac- Gini co efficient a 28.0 als. Investments have also fostered growth, erbating the country’s debt-related risks. Scho o l enro llment, primary (% gro ss) b 98.2 despite a deceleration in gross fixed capital The external position continued to im- b 71.0 formation, reflected both more muted FDI prove on the back of the recovering remit- Life expectancy at birth, years as well as a base effect from past increases. tances, net export growth and more gener- Source: WDI, M acro Poverty Outlook, and official data. Notes: On the supply side, growth was supported ally improved terms of trade. During the (a) 2017. by both tradable and non-tradable sectors first three quarters of 2017, the current (b) M ost recent WDI value (2015). with the highest contribution by industry account balance turned positive to 1.5 per- followed by agriculture and services. cent of GDP compared to a 4 percent defi- Annual consumer price inflation accelerat- cit in the same period of 2016. Exports ed to 6.7 percent, slightly above last year’s grew by over 23 percent bolstered by high- 6 percent, yet within the National Bank’s er production of metallic minerals, while Tajikistan’s economy sustained high target of 7±2 percent. Inflationary pressures imports declined by 3 percent in the first growth in 2017 supported by an improved stemmed from the depreciation of the na- nine months of 2017, y-o-y. Foreign direct external environment, reflected in net tional currency (about 11 percent during investments contracted to 2.1 percent of exports and the recovering remittances. the year) which pushed up prices of im- GDP through January-September 2017 (a ported goods along with factors, such as a historical low), compared to 2.9 percent of The positive outlook for the Russian econ- supply-side shock on some food staples GDP in the corresponding period of 2016. omy, the improving regional environ- and increases in utility tariffs. As inflation- The financial sector remains partially in- ment, and construction of Rogun hydro- ary pressures and expectations moderated, solvent despite some reduction of non- power plant (HPP) support strong the National Bank lowered the policy rate performing loans from 47 percent in 2016 to 14.75 percent in the beginning of 2018. to 35.8 percent by end 2017. The two larg- growth projections. However, the slow Preliminary fiscal outcomes for 2017 sug- est problem banks have downsized sig- pace of reforms, heightened vulnerabili- gest that the government adhered to the nificantly and now account for about 20 ties, and the pending decisions in the approved medium-term Fiscal Strategy percent of the banking sector. While banking and SOE sectors present down- 2017-20. The overall fiscal deficit was re- boosting efforts for asset sales, rehabilita- side risks. Poverty reduction prospects duced to 2.6 percent of GDP in 2017 from tion plans have been submitted to the gov- 3.9 percent in the previous year (excluding ernment’s review. The needed, long- remain positive as remittances continue to 6.1 percent of GDP related to the financial pending legislative amendments, which recover and growth is sustained. sector bailout). The authorities spent 13.6 aimed at enhancing the financial sector FIGURE 1 Tajikistan / Real GDP growth and contributions FIGURE 2 Tajikistan / Official poverty rate and real GDP to real GDP growth growth, actual and projected, 2014-20 Percent, percentage points Percent Percent 8 34% 8% 6.9 7.1 6.7 6.0 6.1 6.0 6.0 7% 32% 6 6% 30% 5% 4 28% 4% 3% 2 26% Official poverty rate (LHS) 2% 24% Poverty projection (LHS) 1% 0 Real GDP growth (RHS) 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 22% 0% Agriculture Industry Services Real GDP growth 2014 2015 2016 2017e 2018 f 2019 f 2020 f Sources: TajStat, World Bank staff estimates. Source: World Bank staff estimates. MPO 76 Apr 18 90  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 regulation and oversight, are still under by the improved external environment, line as the construction of the Rogun HPP review by the government. including prices projected for major ex- unwind into imports. Despite strong growth, poverty fell only port commodities, and deepening rela- Poverty is projected to fall to about 24 slightly from 30.3 percent in 2016 to 29.7 tionship with neighbors, particularly Uz- percent by 2020. Strong growth and recov- percent by September 2017 with extreme bekistan. Despite the weak banking sec- ering remittances and expansion of the poverty stagnant at 14.1 percent of popu- tor, growth is expected to be around 6 Targeted Social Assistance (TSA) program lation. Income from employment and re- percent supported by growing remittanc- nationally are expected to push down mittances remain the primary drivers of es, construction of large infrastructure poverty over the medium term. poverty reduction. Lower remittances projects and electricity sales. Inflation is slowed the pace of poverty reduction in forecasted to remain in single digits as- 2014 – H1 2016, but began recovering in H2 of 2016, and rebounded throughout suming the central bank’s move to the inflation targeting framework improves Risks and challenges 2017. Poverty was relatively stagnant in inflation monitoring. urban areas during 2015-16 (hovering at Over the medium term the fiscal stance is Risks are tilted to the downside subject to around 24 percent) but became more dy- expected to remain prudent, in line with external and domestic factors. External namic in 2017 by declining to 22 percent. the deficit ceiling set by the Government’s uncertainties may negatively affect re- During the same period rural poverty fell medium-term fiscal strategy. The fiscal mittance inflows. Domestic vulnerabilities from 36.1 percent in 2014 to 33.1 percent deficit is projected at around 3 percent of include the adequate resolution of prob- in 2017. Food expenditure accounts for GDP, primarily reflecting investments into lem banks, growing contingent liabilities about 75 percent of total consumption for infrastructure projects and higher debt in public enterprises, and a very slow pace poor households. The Listening-to- service obligations. The baseline scenario of structural reforms, particularly to en- Tajikistan survey identified a noticeable does not assume additional budget sup- hance the business climate. The country’s decline in the share of households that port for the banking sector resolution; any deteriorated debt trend and growing debt have reduced food consumption to pay needed bailout would expand the aug- service obligations pose macro-fiscal chal- for other basic needs – from about 45 per- mented deficit concomitantly. lenges and limit the fiscal space for much cent to about 27 percent between Novem- The external balance is expected to deteri- needed social spending. Any potential ber 2016 to November 2017. orate, while remaining below 3 percent of banking sector bailout and/or second- GDP affected by second-round effects of round of Eurobonds issuance will sub- the remittance-driven consumption recov- stantially threaten the country’s fragile Outlook ery and investment-related imports, par- ticularly for the construction of the Rogun macroeconomic stability. HPP. International reserves, which rose to Tajikistan’s outlook for the short- to medi- 5.6 months of imports by the end of Sep- um term remains positive and is explained tember 2017, are expected to decline in TABLE 2 Tajikistan / Macro poverty outlook indicators (annual percent change unless indicated otherwise) 2015 2016 2017 e 2018 f 2019 f 2020 f Real GDP growth, at constant market prices 6.0 6.9 7.1 6.1 6.0 6.0 Private Consumption -15.0 6.4 3.3 3.4 3.5 3.5 Government Consumption 3.3 3.9 -5.9 6.8 7.7 8.5 Gross Fixed Capital Investment 24.4 20.3 2.4 3.6 3.8 3.9 Exports, Goods and Services 0.0 0.0 10.4 8.5 8.2 8.1 Imports, Goods and Services 0.0 0.0 5.0 5.2 5.4 5.5 Real GDP growth, at constant factor prices 5.4 6.6 7.1 6.1 6.0 6.0 Agriculture 3.2 5.2 6.8 5.1 5.2 5.3 Industry 15.7 18.1 14.0 11.0 11.1 11.2 Services 1.6 1.0 2.8 3.3 2.5 2.1 Inflation (Consumer Price Index) 5.8 5.9 7.3 8.5 7.0 7.0 Current Account Balance (% of GDP) -6.0 -3.8 -1.0 -2.4 -2.5 -2.6 Financial and Capital Account (% of GDP) 7.4 8.1 4.5 2.4 2.5 2.6 Net Foreign Direct Investment (% of GDP) 5.3 4.9 3.1 3.3 3.3 3.3 Fiscal Balance (% of GDP) -1.9 -9.7 -2.6 -3.0 -3.1 -3.3 Debt (% of GDP) 35.0 43.2 50.4 51.2 51.7 52.2 Primary Balance (% of GDP) -1.3 -9.2 -1.1 -1.2 -1.2 -1.3 a,b National poverty rate 31.3 30.3 29.7 27.7 25.5 23.9 So urce: Wo rld B ank, P o verty & Equity and M acro eco no mics, Trade & Investment Glo bal P ractices. No tes: e = estimate, f = fo recast. (a) Calculatio ns based o n 201 7 HB S. A ctual data: 201 5, 2016, 2017. Fo recast is fro m 2018 to 2020. (b) P ro jectio n using neutral distributio n (2017) with pass-thro ugh = (0.7) based o n GDP per capita co nstant P P P . MPO 77 Apr 18 Selected Country Pages ●  91 PPP) fell from 23.1 percent to a low of 9.9 TURKEY Recent developments percent in the 10 years up to 2016. It is esti- mated to have declined to 9.1 percent in 2017. The more recent progress was helped Turkey experienced a strong recovery in by the availability of more jobs, coupled 2017 with growth at 7.4 percent growth, with a 30 percent increase in minimum Table 1 2017 stimulated by fiscal measures and a Credit wage in 2016. P o pulatio n, millio na 80.3 Guarantee Fund for SME financing. Con- Strong growth stimulated the labor market GDP , current US$ billio n 850.7 sumption accounted for over two thirds of in 2017. Unemployment rate decreased by GDP per capita, current US$ 10592 growth in this period, and investment start- 2.3 percentage points from 12.7 percent in Internatio nal po verty rate ($ 1.9) b 0.2 ing to pick up. EU recovery helped acceler- December 2016 to 10.4 percent in December Upper middle-inco me po verty rate ($ 5.5) b 9.9 ate exports. 2017. Employment increased by 1.6 million Gini co efficient b 41.9 Strong demand has come at a cost of grow- persons in the same period, mainly driven c 102.5 ing macroeconomic imbalances. Consumer by services (55 percent), industry (19.5 per- Scho o l enro llment, primary (% gro ss) c price inflation averaged 11 percent in 2017. cent) and agriculture (18.3 percent). Labor Life expectancy at birth, years 75.4 The current account deficit widened from force participation rate for females rose to Source: Turkstat and World Bank staff calculation. 3.8 percent of GDP in 2016 to 5.5 percent in 33.5 percent, a 1.3 percentage point annual Notes: (a) M id-year official data. 2017 amid rising energy prices, high gold inter-annual increase. Meanwhile, the job- (b) M ost recent value (2016), 2011 PPPs. demand and imports stimulated by strong less rate among the youth fell by 4.8 per- (c) M ost recent WDI value (2015). growth. A recovery in net portfolio flows centage points to 19.2 percent. helped finance half of the current account deficit while FDI inflows declined. Growth Turkey’s strong recovery in 2017 (at 7.4 and import demand accelerated revenue collection, keeping the fiscal deficit at 1.9 Outlook percent) came at a cost of widening mac- percent of GDP in 2017. The Central Bank raised the effective poli- For 2018, economic growth is projected at roeconomic imbalances. Growth in 2018, cy rate from 8.3 to 12.75 percent in 2017 4.7 percent, gradually converging to a however, is projected to moderate closer to due to price and exchange rate pressures. potential rate of around 4.5-5 percent. potential, at 4.7 percent. Poverty is fore- Despite this, inflationary expectations Recent surveys point to a moderation in cast to decrease, although at a slower pace remain high. Growth in money stock (M3) consumer demand, weighed down by moderated slightly but remained high at rising costs and declining real wages. Rap- than previous years. Expansionary poli- 16 percent in 2017 in line with strong de- id credit expansion has increased credit cies will likely in place to stimulate de- mand, driven by a 20 percent expansion in risk and raised lending rates, pointing to a mand, especially ahead of the upcoming private sector credit. The Central Bank slowdown in credit growth in 2018. elections. Key risks include inflation and also introduced stricter regulations on Nevertheless, expansionary policies will tightening of global financial condi- forex debt for corporates to mitigate risks likely in place to stimulate demand to of high forex exposure. maintain growth especially ahead of the tions—all of which could constrain access Poverty in Turkey continued to decline. elections. The 2018 Budget approved in to external finance, raise cost of external The population with per capita expenditure December 2018 was supplemented by debt, and weaken the external balance. below the poverty line ($5.5 a day in 2011 fiscal stimulus measures proposed in FIGURE 1 Turkey / Real GDP growth and contributions to FIGURE 2 Turkey / Actual and projected poverty rates and real GDP growth real GDP per capita Percent, percentage points Poverty rate (%) GDP per capita (constant LCU) 20 40 25000 15 35 20000 10 30 5 25 15000 20 0 15 10000 -5 10 -10 5000 5 -15 2000 2003 2006 2009 2012 2015 2018 0 0 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020 Gov. cons. Exports GFCF Inventories Private cons. Imports International poverty rate Upper middle-income pov. rate Statistical disc. GDP GDP pc Sources: Turkstat and World Bank staff calculations. Sources: World Bank. Notes: see Table 2. MPO 78 Apr 18 92  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 February 2018 to accelerate investment to create new jobs and investments in less The US announcement on steel and alumi- and employment. The latter could poten- developed provinces and reduce high and num tariffs will affect Turkey – the sixth tially raise the budget deficit target fur- persistent regional inequality. largest seller of steel to the US. The direct ther. In addition, despite banking sector impact on the trade balance will likely be pressures, the Credit Guarantee Fund has limited, given the overall level of trade been extended by a further TL 55 billion for 2018. Risks and challenges with the US. The current macroeconomic environment Given the above, inflation is expected to and projected external conditions will re- remain at just above 10 percent in 2018. External vulnerability for Turkey remains quire monetary and fiscal discipline. Sound Core inflation, which remained elevated, high. The US monetary policy tightening macroeconomic policies need to be accom- hit double digits in the last months, and in 2018 could increase the pace and vol- panied by deeper structural reforms to en- could push headline inflation further. The ume of capital outflows. This increases sure a more sustainable economic growth current account deficit is projected to re- interest and exchange rate risks for Tur- trajectory over the medium term. Steady main high at 5.6 percent of GDP. Despite key’s external debt. The private sector is progress in advancing structural reforms continued export growth driven by con- particularly affected as it accounts for 70 will be key to restoring investor confidence, tinued recovery in the EU, the import bill percent of external debt. Although most of mitigating vulnerabilities, enhancing is likely to remain large, not least due to the debt is of long-term maturity, a weak- productivity and supporting growth. rising commodity prices. er Lira and costlier external financing On the poverty and inequality front, the Poverty is forecast to decrease at a slower might adversely impact corporates’ bal- impact of the employment subsidies tar- pace. It is estimated to decline further to ance sheets. geted to disadvantaged populations, and 8.8 percent in 2018 (from 9.1 percent in This raises macro-financial risks. Capital the investment incentives focused on lag- 2017). Poverty could decline more rapidly adequacy and NPL ratios hover around 16 ging regions, remains uncertain, both in if the recently introduced Attraction Cen- percent and 3 percent respectively, alt- the short term and in the long run. In addi- ters Program (ACP) proves effective in hough total troubled assets are estimated tion, uptake from private employers may boosting employment in the poorest re- to be higher. Exchange rate and interest not reach significant levels, and low- gions. The program covers 23 provinces in rate risks, together with a slowing econo- income candidates may lack skills for jobs eastern and southeastern Anatolian re- my, all coming on the heels of rapid credit that become available. Considering these gions where poverty rates are 3-4 times expansion, point to a potential deteriora- constraints, the impact of these policies higher than in the western regions. It aims tion in banking sector asset quality. warrants close monitoring. TABLE 2 Turkey / Macro poverty outlook indicators (annual percent change unless indicated otherwise) 2015 2016 2017 e 2018 f 2019 f 2020 f Real GDP growth, at constant market prices 6.1 3.2 7.4 4.7 4.4 4.0 Private Consumption 5.4 3.7 6.1 4.0 3.8 3.6 Government Consumption 3.9 9.5 5.0 5.0 5.3 4.6 Gross Fixed Capital Investment 9.3 2.2 7.3 5.3 4.7 4.0 Exports, Goods and Services 4.3 -1.9 12.0 6.7 5.5 5.0 Imports, Goods and Services 1.7 3.7 10.3 6.0 5.2 4.6 Real GDP growth, at constant factor prices 5.7 3.1 7.8 4.7 4.4 4.0 Agriculture 9.4 -2.6 4.7 1.9 1.9 1.9 Industry 5.0 4.6 9.1 4.0 3.8 3.6 Services 5.6 3.2 7.5 5.4 5.0 4.4 Inflation (Consumer Price Index) 7.7 7.8 11.1 10.4 9.0 8.2 Current Account Balance (% of GDP) -3.7 -3.8 -5.5 -5.7 -5.6 -5.5 Financial and Capital Account (% of GDP) 2.6 2.6 5.5 5.7 5.6 5.5 Net Foreign Direct Investment (% of GDP) 1.5 1.2 1.0 1.1 1.2 1.2 Fiscal Balance (% of GDP) -0.1 -1.3 -1.9 -2.1 -2.1 -1.7 Debt (% of GDP) 27.6 28.3 28.3 28.4 28.4 28.0 Primary Balance (% of GDP) 2.2 0.7 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.6 International poverty rate ($1.9 in 2011 PPP) a,b 0.3 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 Upper middle-income poverty rate ($5.5 in 2011 PPP) a,b 11.5 9.9 9.1 8.8 8.4 8.2 So urce: Wo rld B ank, P o verty & Equity and M acro eco no mics, Trade & Investment Glo bal P ractices. No tes: e = estimate, f = fo recast. (a) Calculatio ns based o n ECA P OV harmo nizatio n, using 2008-HICES and 201 6-HICES. A ctual data: 2015, 2016. No wcast: 2017. Fo recast are fro m 2018 to 2020. (b) P ro jectio n using po int-to -po int elasticity (2008-2016) with pass-thro ugh = 1based o n GDP per capita in co nstant LCU. MPO 79 Apr 18 Selected Country Pages ●  93 adjustment of the highly subsidized fuel TURKMENISTAN Recent developments prices, including for utilities, and a 10 percent rise in public-sector salaries, pen- sions, and other government payments. The official real GDP growth rate accelerat- The current account deficit remained high ed slightly—from 6.2 percent in 2016 to an in 2017, although with some improvement Table 1 2017 estimated 6.5 percent in 2017. Growth was due to a recovery in global hydrocarbon P o pulatio n, millio na 5.7 largely supported by more favorable terms prices and a substantial contraction in GDP , current US$ billio nb 42.4 of trade, primarily reflecting a recovery in imports. After falling in 2015-16, export global gas prices, which rose by 24 percent revenues grew by 3.6 percent year-on-year GDP per capita, current US$ b 7355 year-on-year. China remains the largest in 2017; still not sufficient to close the ex- Scho o l enro llment, primary (% gro ss)c 89.4 purchaser of Turkmen gas, while a price ternal gap. In contrast, imports continued Life expectancy at birth, years d 67.6 dispute with Iran over gas supplies re- to decline, falling by 23 percent in 2017. Sources: UNPD, M acro Poverty Outlook, and WDI. mains unresolved and has affected export The sharp drop in imports was due to Notes: revenues. In early 2018, Iran announced tighter trade regulations and significant (a) UNPD staff estimates (2016). readiness to file a case with the Interna- pressures on the FX markets as the author- (b) World Bank staff estimates (2017). (c) M ost recent WDI value (2014). tional Court of Arbitration. ities avoided tapping on their buffers, (d) M ost recent WDI value (2015). The domestic retail trade sector grew at an restricting liquidity in the FX markets. annual rate of 19 percent in 2017, as an The monetary authorities continued to expansion of credit and government trans- strengthen oversight and control of FX fers supported consumption growth; the operations, and adopted restrictions that transport and communications sector limited foreign currency withdrawals Turkmenistan’s real GDP growth rate grew by 11 percent year-on-year, and the from cash, bank cards, and cross-border rose by 6.5 percent year-on-year in 2017, service sector grew at an annual rate of 9 transactions in 2017. The drying up of FX mainly supported by a recovery in hydro- percent. However, gross fixed investments liquidity in the domestic markets suggests fell sharply (by almost 9 percent year-on- that a correction of the official exchange carbon prices. The external and fiscal ac- year), as flows of both domestic and for- rate (currently pegged at 3.5 manat per US counts improved according to official da- eign direct investments fell, dampening dollar) may need to be considered, along ta, but inflation surged to double-digits, growth in the construction sector. Moreo- with other macroeconomic and structural hinting at a possible buildup of imbalanc- ver, agriculture output increased by a reforms to reduce the external imbalances. es. The rise of inflation and the gradual mere 5 percent, just below GDP growth, The Turkmen authorities continued their suggesting less growth dividends for a fiscal consolidation efforts and balanced removal of welfare subsidies for utilities large share of the population employed in the state budget in 2017, compared to the has negatively impacted the purchasing the agricultural sector. 1.3 percent deficit in 2016. Compared to power of households. The country’s growth Consumer price inflation hiked from 6.2 government plans, revenue collection over outlook remains positive, but risks are percent in the end of 2016 to 10.4 percent -performed by 1.8 percent in 2017, while by the end of 2017. Inflation was driven by expenditures underperformed by 3.6 per- tilted downwards, given the needed struc- the high pressure on the foreign exchange cent, primarily due to cuts in capital tural reforms aimed at boosting private- (FX) markets, which pushed up the prices spending and a gradual elimination of sector development. of imported goods, as well as an upward welfare subsidies since the last quarter of FIGURE 1 Turkmenistan / Real GDP growth and gas prices FIGURE 2 Turkmenistan / Exchange rate and oil prices Percent Percent USD/TMT US$ per barrel 16 14.7 40 2.6 120 14 30 2.8 100 12 11.1 20 10.2 10.3 3.0 9.2 10 80 10 3.2 0 8 6.5 6.5 3.4 60 6.2 -10 6 3.6 -20 40 4 -30 3.8 20 2 -40 4.0 0 -50 4.2 0 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 Real GDP growth (LHS) Change in gas prices (RHS) Exchange rate, TMT/US$ (LHS) Oil prices, average (RHS) Source: State Statistics Committee of Turkmenistan. Source: Central Bank of Turkmenistan. MPO 80 Apr 18 94  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 2017. Reportedly, civil servant wages, terms of trade) but slow progress on im- drop in energy prices, which may exacer- pensions, and other core social transfers plementing the national strategy’s struc- bate external and domestic imbalances. were protected. It should be noted that the tural reforms aimed at promoting non- Domestic risks include a low quality and state budget does not represent the full traditional (non-hydrocarbon) exports. rapid credit expansion that may potential- fiscal picture as an important share of Inflation would remain high while gradu- ly undermine the performance of the fi- public spending is executed via extra- ally returning to single digits, assuming nancial sector, lower-than-expected re- budgetary funds, including through di- further fiscal and monetary tightening. turns on state-funded projects, and the rected lending. The positive outlook on gas prices and the stalling of structural reforms aimed at Turkmenistan does not release official statis- robust external demand from China would diversifying the economy through private- tics on household welfare, and little is help strengthen the external position. The sector development. known about most recent labor market de- current-account deficit would narrow from An opening of the economy, an improve- velopments. However, the gradual removal its peak level in 2016, largely on the back ment in the business regulatory environ- of subsidies for utilities and rising inflation of the restrain on merchandise imports ment, an acceleration in the corporatiza- is likely to have affected the real purchasing due to FX constraints. Over the medium tion and privatization of state-owned en- power and living standards of households. term, the reduction on imports would also terprises, and more investments in human follow in case the construction of the Turk- capital will be vital to boost private-sector menistan—Afghanistan—Pakistan—India development and achieve the goals of the Outlook (TAPI) gas pipeline project is delayed. More generally, however, a sharp reduc- medium- and long-term national develop- ment strategies. tion of imports driven by FX restrictions Limited access to economic opportunities, The baseline scenario assumes a continua- could impinge on domestic price dynam- and lack of economic diversification re- tion of fiscal consolidation, some moderation ics, and/or curtail the government’s ability main a major obstacle to inclusive growth, in the buildup of external imbalances, and to proceed with ongoing investment pro- especially for households outside the capi- (sustainable) external debt accumulation to jects, harming the growth prospects. tal city Ashgabat. Households in rural help finance the still sizeable (but narrow- areas are more vulnerable to economic ing) current account deficit. This baseline, downturns and the rising inflation, due to however, is not without downside risks. Turkmenistan’s outlook will remain high- Risks and challenges factors that include their limited access to jobs beyond the agricultural sector. Eco- ly dependent on hydrocarbon prices and nomic diversification (beyond the gas and the growth performance of its major trad- There are both external and domestic agricultural sectors) with further private ing partner, China. Over the medium threats that raise country ’s risk profile. sector growth would create more econom- term, the real GDP growth rate is project- External risks include weaker -than- ic opportunities for households, including ed to remain below 7 percent, assuming expected growth in trading partners, those in rural areas and secondary cities. favorable tailwinds (including via the particularly in China, and an unexpected TABLE 2 Turkmenistan / Macro poverty outlook indicators (annual percent change unless indicated otherwise) 2014 2015 2016 2017 e 2018 f Real GDP growth, at constant market prices 10.3 6.5 6.2 6.5 6.3 Inflation: consumer price index, end of period 4.4 6.0 6.2 10.4 6.2 Current account balance (% of GDP) -6.4 -14.1 -21.0 -11.6 -11.5 of which: Exports of hydrocarbons (% of GDP) 42.0 29.9 16.6 14.7 14.4 Financial and capital account (% of GDP) 7.0 5.2 9.8 6.8 7.7 of which: Net foreign direct investment (% of GDP) 8.8 8.6 6.1 4.5 3.6 Fiscal balance (% of GDP) 0.9 -0.7 -1.3 -0.2 0.5 Public debt (% of GDP) 18.0 19.4 23.9 24.3 27.6 Sources: World Bank, International Monetary Fund. Notes: e = estimate; f = forecast. MPO 81 Apr 18 Selected Country Pages ●  95 remained steady in the third quarter of UKRAINE Recent developments 2017 at 9.4 percent, compared to 9.2 the previous year. Real wages grew signifi- cantly by 19 percent in 2017 in part due to Growth remains weak due to key pending higher public-sector wages. This, together reforms needed to strengthen investors’ with real growth of pensions, led to fur- Table 1 2017 confidence. GDP grew by 2.5 percent in ther decline in poverty (consumption per P o pulatio n, millio n 44.8 2017 (and 2.3 percent in 2016) which is a capita below 5.5 USD/day in 2011 PPP) to GDP , current US$ billio n 112.9 weak recovery since it follows a cumula- 5.7 percent in 2017 from 6.4 percent in GDP per capita, current US$ 2522 tive 16 percent contraction in 2014-2015. 2016 and 7.8 percent in 2015. Estimates of Internatio nal po verty rate ($ 1.9) a 0.1 Key sectors exhibiting relative strength poverty by the National Statistical Service Lo wer middle-inco me po verty rate ($ 3.2) a 0.5 such as manufacturing and domestic trade using an absolute poverty line comparable Upper middle-inco me po verty rate ($ 5.5) a 6.4 grew over 5 percent in 2017, while con- over time show much higher incidence a 25.0 struction grew by almost 27 percent. In levels, but a similar modest decline to 51.1 Gini co efficient b contrast, mining and electricity generation percent in 2016 from 51.9 percent in 2015. Life expectancy at birth, years 71.2 contracted due to the trade blockade with The fiscal deficit was within target in 2017 Source: WDI, M acro Poverty Outlook, and official data. Donbas. The growth of fixed investment but spending growth, inflation, and the Notes: (a) M ost recent value (2016), 2011 PPPs. has slowed in the second half of the year, current account deficit remain high. The (b) M ost recent WDI value (2015). while FDI remained weak at 2.1 percent of fiscal deficit remained flat and on target at GDP in 2017, compared to 5 percent on 2.4 percent of GDP in 2017. However, ex- average before the crises. Investor confi- penditures were up by 11.7 percent in real dence has been affected by the slow pace terms and reached 42.6 percent of GDP in adopting key reforms and delays in due to the increase in the minimum wage Economic growth in 2017 remained mod- completing reviews of the IMF program (resulting in higher wages for teachers, est at 2.5 percent for a second year in a given macroeconomic vulnerabilities and doctors, and civil servants), as well as row, which is inadequate to reduce elevat- uncertainty surrounding the 2019 elec- higher spending on social programs. This tions. CPI reached 13.7 percent at the end was balanced by strong revenue growth in ed compared to pre-crisis levels. Foreign of 2017, that is significantly higher than 2017, driven by payroll tax (20 percent in investment and credit to the private sector the NBU target of 8+/-2 percent, due to real terms, due to the hike in wages), VAT is anemic. Macroeconomic vulnerabilities growth of public sector wages and pen- (17 percent, due to higher proceeds from going forward come from significant fi- sions. As a result, NBU raised its key poli- imports) and personal income tax (16 per- cy rate to 17 percent in March 2018 from cent). Public and publicly guaranteed debt nancing needs, fiscal pressures from high- 12.5 percent in April 2017. This has in- level remained high at 70.4 percent of er public-sector wages and social benefits. creased the cost of funds for local curren- GDP in 2017. The boost in wages and so- Completing the pending reforms in ad- cy borrowing for both the government cial expenditures triggered inflationary vance of elections in 2019 will be critical and the private sector. and current account pressures in 2017. to mobilize adequate international financ- Poverty remains above pre-crisis levels, The current account deficit was at 3.5 per- but has registered small decline I in 2017 cent of GDP in 2017. FDI remains weak ing, maintain macroeconomic stability, due to the modest economic recovery and and covered 60 percent of the CAD, with and bolster investment. wage growth. The unemployment rate the remainder financed by public and FIGURE 1 Ukraine / Real GDP growth and contributions to FIGURE 2 Ukraine / Actual and projected poverty rates and real GDP growth real private consumption per capita Percent, percentage points Poverty rate (%) Private consumption per capita (constant LCU) 20 50 25000 15 10 40 20000 5 30 0 15000 -5 20 -10 10000 -15 10 -20 5000 -25 0 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020 -30 2015-Q1 2015-Q3 2016-Q1 2016-Q3 2017-Q1 2017-Q3 -10 0 International poverty rate Lower middle-income pov. rate Agriculture Manufacturing Domestic trade GDP Upper middle-income pov. rate Consumption pc Sources: State Statistic Service of Ukraine. Sources: World Bank. Notes: see Table 2. MPO 82 Apr 18 96  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 private borrowings. International reserves leads to optimizing the school and hospi- fiscal and financial sector imbalances, and grew to $18.8 billion or an equivalent of tal network. Under an alternative scenario promote stronger economic growth. 3.4 month of imports. where reforms do not progress and the Macroeconomic vulnerabilities come total IMF reviews are not completed, growth is fiscal financing needs of $18 billion in 2018 likely to remain at 2 percent, or potentially and 2019 that will require mobilizing Outlook fall further if political and social stability deteriorates around the 2019 elections. about $8 billion in external financing. Ad- ditional fiscal pressures come from the The moderate poverty rate (under 5.5 USD/ rising public-sector wage bill and signifi- Bolstering economic growth and address- day) is expected to decline further in 2018 cant spending on social programs, which ing macroeconomic vulnerabilities will but remain elevated through 2019. As pub- will prove challenging to consolidate require progress on the unfinished struc- lic spending is constrained, labor income through the 2019 elections. tural reform agenda. Progress on the re- will become the most important driver of Financial sector weaknesses from high form agenda and staying on track with increasing incomes for the bottom 40 per- nonperforming loans at 55% of total loans, the IMF program would not only boost cent. Some rebound in the real sector, in- weak corporate governance of the domi- potential growth, but also provide an cluding wage growth in the private sector nant state-owned banks, and weak finan- important signal to strengthen investor will support disposable incomes and help cial position of the Deposit Guaranty confidence. This would help stimulate a the poverty rate to gradually decline. How- Fund not only stand in the way of stimu- sustained recovery in fixed investment, ever, the magnitude of this reduction will lating investment and growth, but also financed by local sources and FDI, and depend on the growth prospects, especially pose significant fiscal risks. boost growth to 4.0 percent by 2019. With in the sectors were most of the poor/ With real household incomes still below agriculture and commodities expected to vulnerable are employed (trade, manufac- pre-crisis levels, continued weak econom- remain relatively flat in 2018, the accelera- turing, agriculture, construction). ic growth of 2 percent going into the 2019 tion in growth is expected to come from elections could undermine overall politi- manufacturing, construction, and ser- cal and social support for the broad re- vices. Meeting the fiscal deficit target of 2.5 percent of GDP will require better Risks and challenges form effort launched since 2014. External risks related to possible decline targeting of social programs, rationalizing in commodity prices and higher inflation public sector staffing, and implementa- Elections scheduled in 2019 pose major in advanced economies that may result in tion of the recently adopted education risks in adopting further reforms needed to higher external trade deficit and cost of and health reform laws in a manner that mobilize international financing, address financing respectively. TABLE 2 Ukraine / Macro poverty outlook indicators (annual percent change unless indicated otherwise) 2015 2016 2017 2018 f 2019 f 2020 f Real GDP growth, at constant market prices -9.8 2.3 2.5 3.5 4.0 4.0 Private Consumption -19.7 1.8 7.8 5.4 4.1 3.8 Government Consumption -0.4 0.0 3.3 4.5 3.2 1.6 Gross Fixed Capital Investment -9.2 20.1 18.2 14.9 9.0 9.2 Exports, Goods and Services -13.2 -1.6 3.5 8.0 6.4 5.9 Imports, Goods and Services -17.9 8.4 12.2 14.0 7.2 5.8 Real GDP growth, at constant factor prices -8.8 2.4 2.5 3.5 4.0 4.0 Agriculture -4.4 6.0 -2.5 0.5 2.0 2.5 Industry -15.1 3.3 2.5 5.0 4.5 4.0 Services -7.3 1.4 3.4 3.6 3.6 4.2 Inflation (Consumer Price Index) 48.7 13.9 13.7 9.9 6.5 6.3 Current Account Balance (% of GDP) -0.2 -3.7 -3.5 -3.7 -3.3 -3.3 Financial and Capital Account (% of GDP) -0.2 3.4 3.3 3.7 3.3 3.4 Net Foreign Direct Investment (% of GDP) 0.2 0.2 2.1 2.3 2.3 2.5 Fiscal Balance (% of GDP) -1.2 -2.3 -2.3 -2.5 -2.7 -2.4 Debt (% of GDP) 79.7 81.2 72.3 75.1 73.5 68.4 Primary Balance (% of GDP) 3.0 2.0 1.4 1.5 1.7 1.6 International poverty rate ($1.9 in 2011 PPP) a,b 0.1 0.1 .. .. .. .. Lower middle-income poverty rate ($3.2 in 2011 PPP) a,b 0.5 0.5 0.4 0.4 0.4 0.3 Upper middle-income poverty rate ($5.5 in 2011 PPP) a,b 7.8 6.4 5.7 5.2 4.0 3.4 So urce: Wo rld B ank, P o verty & Equity and M acro eco no mics, Trade & Investment Glo bal P ractices. No tes: e = estimate, f = fo recast. (a) Calculatio ns based o n ECA P OV harmo nizatio n, using 201 6-HLCS. A ctual data: 201 5, 2016. No wcast: 2017. Fo recast are fro m 2018 to 2020. (b) P ro jectio n using neutral distributio n (2016) with pass-thro ugh = 1 based o n private co nsumptio n per capita in co nstant LCU. MPO 83 Apr 18 Selected Country Pages ●  97 also grew, however, on the back of lower UZBEKISTAN Recent developments import prices and the very significant re- duction in import tariffs implemented in September, which resulted in an expand- GDP growth slowed to 5.3 percent in 2017 ed demand for imported goods. The trade (from 7.8 percent in 2016), led by the de- balance was in surplus in 2017 (compared Table 1 2017 celeration in domestic demand. Total to a deficit in 2016) thanks to the higher P o pulatio n, millio n 32.0 investment moderated relative to previ- commodity prices in the second half of GDP , current US$ billio n 41.2 ous years, while remaining the main 2017, and the recovery of food and manu- GDP per capita, current US$ 1290 growth engine for the economy. This was facturing exports as the demand of Uzbek- Scho o l enro llment, primary (% gro ss) a 102.1 possible thanks to the public investment istan’s trading partners firmed up. Over- Life expectancy at birth, years a 71.1 program, which supported a range of all, the current account surplus strength- sectors (transport, utilities, oil and gas ened further in 2017 compared to 2016, Source: WDI, M acro Poverty Outlook, and official data. Notes: explorations, and housing) as well as owing not only to the stronger trade bal- public enterprises and private investment ance, but the recovery remittances. (a) M ost recent WDI value (2015). activity. On the other hand, private con- On September 5, 2017, the Central Bank of sumption declined slightly in real terms Uzbekistan (CBU) liberalized the ex- due to the pickup in CPI inflation, and change rate; the official rate depreciated despite a recovery in remittance inflows from 4,210 UZS to 8,100 UZS per dollar, as (which rose by 27 percent y/y in dollar it converged with the curb rate; the CBU terms in the first 9 months of 2017, togeth- has pursued a managed floating of the Uzbekistan’s real growth slowed in 2017, er with the strengthening of economic currency thereafter. The authorities also led by a deceleration in domestic demand, activity in Russia). abolished the mandatory sales of a portion including investment as the key growth The average nominal monetary income of firms’ export revenues to the CBU at driver. The medium-term outlook is favor- of the population grew by 12.3 percent the official exchange rate (“surrender re- in 2017, supported by an increase in quirements”), widening the participation able, thanks to the government’s ambi- minimum salaries and pensions by 15 of the private sector in the foreign ex- tious reform program (e.g., a liberalized percent in December 2017 (vis -à-vis an change market. In preparation of the ex- exchange rate regime, an enhanced policy average inflation of 12.5 percent in 2017, change rate liberalization, the CBU raised framework and business climate), and the in line with the IMF ’s methodology). the policy rate from 9 to 14 percent in June improved external tailwinds. Going for- Higher food inflation negatively affected 2017, curtailing the strong credit expan- mostly urban consumers, particularly sion that took place earlier in the year, and ward, ensuring a sound reform imple- among the bottom 40 percent households helping stabilize the banking-loans-to- mentation—including by tackling the for whom food accounts for 61 percent GDP ratio at 43.1 percent in 2017 remaining risks—will be key to sustain- of total consumption. (compared to 26.6 in 2016). Official figures ing inclusive and robust growth and se- Uzbekistan mitigated the impact of export suggest that non-performing loans (NPLs) price declines in 2014-16 via increased were at 0.79 percent in Q2 2017 and 1.2 cure job creation. export volumes. This trend continued in percent at the end of 2017 as per CBU esti- the first half of 2017—albeit at a decelerat- mates; Moody’s assessed NPLs at 2.0-2.5 ing rate as capacity diminished. Imports percent in August 2017; these could be FIGURE 1 Uzbekistan / Real GDP growth and contributions FIGURE 2 Uzbekistan / Poverty, GDP per capita, and small to real GDP growth business development Percent, percentage points GDP per capita, US$ Percent 10 2,500 60 50 8 2,000 40 6 1,500 30 1,000 4 20 500 2 10 0 0 0 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017* Small business, % of GDP Services Construction Agriculture GDP per capita, US$, lhs Industry Net taxes GDP total National poverty rate, % of population, rhs Source: Uzbekistan official statistics. Source: Poverty line is national data based on minimum food consumption at 2,100 calories per person per day and it excludes non-food items. Note: Due to the lack of data access, the Bank cannot validate the official figures. MPO 84 Apr 18 98  ●   World Bank ECA Economic Update May 2018 higher after the exchange rate unification poverty reduction in the past. Income The current account surplus would nar- given the currency exposures of key bor- distribution has become more equitable row as imports continue to rise in the face rowers, particularly public enterprises. over time and the official Gini coefficient of trade liberalization, even as exports During 2017 the government sustained a fell from 0.39 in 2001 to 0.29 in 2013. (both commodities and manufactures) robust (but softer) public investment pro- However, the official unemployment rate maintain a positive growth, and re- gram, while cutting back on current was 5.8 percent in 2017, higher than 5.2 mittances remain solid. Real GDP growth spending to meet its state budget targets. percent in 2016. is projected to accelerate slowly to 5.5 per- The authorities reduced direct taxes on cent by 2020 as the private business cli- firms and citizens while increasing prop- mate improves on the back of the reform erty and resource taxes in an effort to achieve revenue neutrality while support- Outlook process, supporting an acceleration of private investment, including FDI. ing economic activity. The government While data limitations do not allow for launched a privatization program and Robust growth is expected to continue at poverty projections, we expect that in- sold 542 state objects in 2017 with budget about 5 percent in 2018-19, but job crea- creased income growth and the sustained receipts of 0.3 percent of total budget reve- tion may take longer to pick up, as invest- robust net remittances in 2018 will allow nue. The government also drew from its ments may not return quickly to pre-2017 some progress in poverty reduction over significant fiscal buffers (at the Uzbek levels. Fiscal activity (including through the near term. Fund for Reconstruction and Develop- UFRD lending) and bank credit are pro- ment, UFRD, a reserve fund) to cover the jected to become less expansionary than in debts of largest bank and industry public enterprises (particularly in the energy the past to help reign on inflation, which is expected to remain elevated as liberal- Risks and challenges sector) that were affected by the deprecia- ized prices continue to adjust. Budget tion of the official exchange rate. As a re- spending would be geared towards miti- Uzbekistan economy’ upside and down- sult, the augmented budget (including the gating the impact of the exchange rate side risks are broadly balanced. On the state and UFRD activity) incurred a larger adjustment on the vulnerable population, upside, there are benign prospects for com- deficit of -3.3 percent of GDP in 2017, rela- as well as supporting critical public enter- modity prices, and accelerated private in- tive to a -0.6 percent of GDP a year earlier. prises to gradually converge towards vestment (including as FDI) thanks to the The official poverty rate declined slightly greater sustainability and cost-recovery, authorities’ bold reform agenda. On the from 12.5 percent in 2016 to an estimated and sustaining the public investment pro- downside, a slower recovery in the Russia’s 12.4 percent in 2017. Still robust economic gram. Monetary policy is expected to be economy, potential delays in other struc- growth, small business development, and tighter than in previous years, also aiming tural reforms and higher inflation could social safety net programs have driven at containing inflation from trending up. undermine growth and job prospects. TABLE 2 Uzbekistan / Macro poverty outlook indicators (annual percent change unless indicated otherwise) 2015 2016 2017 e 2018 f 2019 f 2020 f Real GDP growth, at constant market prices 7.9 7.8 5.3 5.0 5.1 5.5 Private Consumption 1.1 1.0 -0.3 1.2 1.2 2.2 Government Consumption 7.2 -12.8 -8.3 -7.6 -4.3 -1.1 Gross Fixed Capital Investment 9.5 9.5 7.1 6.9 7.0 7.5 Exports, Goods and Services 5.6 11.6 13.9 18.5 17.4 16.0 Imports, Goods and Services -2.1 -3.6 7.1 16.4 16.9 17.2 Real GDP growth, at constant factor prices 7.8 7.9 5.3 5.0 5.1 5.5 Agriculture 6.8 6.6 2.0 3.6 3.7 4.4 Industry 8.5 6.9 4.8 3.7 3.8 4.1 Services 8.0 9.0 7.1 6.1 6.2 6.5 Inflation (Private Consumption Deflator) 8.5 8.0 12.5 19.5 12.9 9.1 Current Account Balance (% of GDP) 0.7 0.7 3.7 0.4 -1.0 -1.4 Fiscal Balance (% of GDP) -1.3 -0.6 -3.3 -1.3 -1.2 -0.2 Debt (% of GDP) 9.2 10.5 24.5 22.3 20.8 21.2 Primary Balance (% of GDP) -1.2 -0.5 -3.2 -0.8 -0.7 0.5 So urce: Wo rld B ank, P o verty & Equity and M acro eco no mics, Trade & Investment Glo bal P ractices. No tes: e = estimate, f = fo recast. MPO 85 Apr 18 WORLD BANK ECA ECONOMIC UPDATE MAY 2018 ocurrencies and Blockchain Crypto With growth in Europe and Central Asia likely at its peak, this report addresses two questions. How well is the region prepared for an expected slowdown? How well has the economic upswing been used to adjust to the digital revolution? The report specifically focuses on cryptocurrency and blockchain activities in the region. ISBN (electronic): 978-1-4648-1299-6 © 2018 International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank Some rights reserved 1818 H Street NW, Washington, DC 20433 Telephone: 202-473-1000 Internet: www.worldbank.org This work is available under the Creative Commons Attribution 3.0 IGO license (CC BY 3.0 IGO) http://creativecommons.org /licenses/by/3.0/igo.