I N TERNAT IONAL DEVEL OPM EN T IN PR ACTICE Governing Infrastructure Regulators in Fragile Environments Principles and Implementation Manual INTERNATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN PRACTICE Governing Infrastructure Regulators in Fragile Environments Principles and Implementation Manual © 2019 International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank 1818 H Street NW, Washington, DC 20433 Telephone: 202-473-1000; Internet: www.worldbank.org Some rights reserved 1 2 3 4 22 21 20 19 Books in this series are published to communicate the results of Bank research, analysis, and operational experience with the least possible delay. The extent of language editing varies from book to book. This work is a product of the staff of The World Bank with external contributions. The findings, inter- pretations, and conclusions expressed in this work do not necessarily reflect the views of The World Bank, its Board of Executive Directors, or the governments they represent. The World Bank does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this work. The boundaries, colors, denominations, and other informa- tion shown on any map in this work do not imply any judgment on the part of The World Bank concerning the legal status of any territory or the endorsement or acceptance of such boundaries. Nothing herein shall constitute or be considered to be a limitation upon or waiver of the privileges and immunities of The World Bank, all of which are specifically reserved. Rights and Permissions This work is available under the Creative Commons Attribution 3.0 IGO license (CC BY 3.0 IGO) http:// creativecommons.org/licenses/by/3.0/igo. Under the Creative Commons Attribution license, you are free to copy, distribute, transmit, and adapt this work, including for commercial purposes, under the following conditions: Attribution—Please cite the work as follows: World Bank. 2019. Governing Infrastructure Regulators in Fragile Environments: Principles and Implementation Manual. International Development in Practice. Washington, DC: World Bank. doi:10.1596/978-1-4648-1434-1 License: Creative Commons Attribution CC BY 3.0 IGO Translations—If you create a translation of this work, please add the following disclaimer along with the attribution: This translation was not created by The World Bank and should not be considered an official World Bank translation. The World Bank shall not be liable for any content or error in this translation. Adaptations—If you create an adaptation of this work, please add the following disclaimer along with the attribution: This is an adaptation of an original work by The World Bank. Views and opinions expressed in the adaptation are the sole responsibility of the author or authors of the adaptation and are not endorsed by The World Bank. Third-party content—The World Bank does not necessarily own each component of the content con- tained within the work. The World Bank therefore does not warrant that the use of any third-party- owned individual component or part contained in the work will not infringe on the rights of those third parties. The risk of claims resulting from such infringement rests solely with you. If you wish to re-use a component of the work, it is your responsibility to determine whether permission is needed for that re-use and to obtain permission from the copyright owner. Examples of components can include, but are not limited to, tables, figures, or images. All queries on rights and licenses should be addressed to World Bank Publications, The World Bank Group, 1818 H Street NW, Washington, DC 20433, USA; e-mail: pubrights@worldbank.org. ISBN: 978-1-4648-1434-1 DOI: 10.1596/978-1-4648-1434-1 Cover photo: © Graham Crouch / World Bank. Used with permission; further permission required for reuse. Cover design: Debra Naylor / Naylor Design Inc. Contents Preface  ix Executive Summary  xiii Abbreviations  xxiii PART A: INTRODUCTION 1 CHAPTER 1: The Importance of Ensuring Good Governance of Regulators  3 Introduction: The purpose of the manual   3 A framework for the manual—Ten principles for the governance of regulators   6 Notes  8 References  9 PART B: PRINCIPLES FOR THE GOVERNANCE OF REGULATORS 11 Goals of the section   11 Note on the principles   12 Implementing the principles over time   12 Note   13 References  13 CHAPTER 2: Mandate Clarity  15 Abstract  15 Key takeaways  15 The importance of mandate clarity   16 Mandate clarity and the goal of competition   17 Assessing mandate clarity in the post-fragile context   19 Note  20 References  21 CHAPTER 3: Requisite Powers  23 Abstract  23 Key takeaways  23 What are the powers a regulator should possess?   24 Assessing the adequacy of a regulator’s powers    24 Requisite powers in the post-fragile context   25 Reference  26  iii iv | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS CHAPTER 4: Independence  27 Abstract  27 Key takeaways  27 Introduction  28 How is independence established and maintained?   29 Independence versus accountability   30 Independence and other governance principles   30 Independence issues in the post-fragile context   31 Reference  32 CHAPTER 5: Decision-Making and Governing Body   33 Abstract  33 Key takeaways  33 Choosing the decision-making model   34 Allocation of decision-making powers   36 Membership of the governing body   37 Recruitment and reappointment   38 Term of appointments and term limits   38 Sector-specific versus multisectoral regulators   39 Decision-making bodies in post-fragile contexts   41 Notes  43 References  43 CHAPTER 6: Funding Regulatory Agencies   45 Abstract  45 Key takeaways  45 Introduction  46 Funding methods  46 Funding oversight  49 Incentive issues in relation to funding   53 Funding and fragile states   53 Revenue from fines and penalties   55 Diagnosing funding issues in relation to regulatory agencies   56 Note  57 References  57 CHAPTER 7: Integrity  59 Abstract  59 Key takeaways  59 Introduction  60 A focus on rules—A code of behavior   60 Implementing a code of behavior: Building a culture of integrity  62 Integrity in the post-fragile context   63 Integrity and the other principles for good regulatory governance  63 Conclusion  66 Note  67 References  67 CHAPTER 8: Predictability  69 Abstract  69 Key takeaways  69 Regulations and predictability   70 Changing rules and procedures   71 Predictability and contractual commitment   71 Predictability and the rule of law in post-fragile context   72 the ­ Conclusion: Diagnosing predictability issues in relation to regulatory agencies  72 References  74 Contents | v CHAPTER 9: Engagement  75 Abstract  75 Key takeaways  75 Introduction  76 Quality in engagement processes   77 Ensuring effective engagement in the post-fragile context   80 Conclusion  80 Reference  81 CHAPTER 10: Accountability and Transparency   83 Abstract  83 Key takeaways  83 Introduction  84 Accountability to the minister and the legislature   84 Accountability to regulated entities   85 Accountability to the public   86 Accountability and transparency in the post-fragile context   86 Conclusion  89 Notes  90 Reference  90 CHAPTER 11: Performance Evaluation  91 Abstract  91 Key takeaways  91 Introduction: Performance evaluation in the fragile context   92 Scope of performance evaluation   92 Key characteristics of a good external review process   92 Developing indicators  95 Using performance evaluation   96 Developing performance evaluation over time in post-fragile countries  97 Conclusion  97 Reference  98 PART C: IMPLEMENTING REFORMS TO REGULATORY SYSTEMS AND GOVERNANCE 99 CHAPTER 12: Mobilizing and Engaging Pro-Reform Forces   101 Introduction  101 Engaging stakeholders in the evolution of regulatory policy   104 Conclusion  106 References  107 CHAPTER 13: Central Coordination of Reform   109 Introduction  109 Establishing a specialist body to coordinate and monitor reform  109 Developing a regulatory governance policy for the infrastructure sector  110 A longer-term perspective—Developing a government-wide regulatory policy  113 Conclusion  113 Note  113 References  113 CHAPTER 14: The Capacity for Reform of Regulatory Governance   115 Introduction  115 Whole-of-government capacity requirements for regulatory reform  116 Regulator capacity requirements for reform   119 Building governance capacities for reform over time   121 vi | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS Conclusion  123 Notes  123 References  123 CHAPTER 15: Developing a Strategy for Reform and Putting It Into Practice  125 Introduction  125 Staging reform  126 Putting the plan into practice   130 Conclusion  135 Notes  135 References  135 CHAPTER 16: Maintaining the Strategy Over Time   137 Introduction  137 Commitment, continuity, and policy stability   137 Addressing the “implementation gap”   143 Conclusion  146 Note  147 References  147 APPENDIX A: Glossary of Key Concepts Used in the Manual   149 APPENDIX B: A Review of the Literature Related to Regulatory Governance  155 APPENDIX C: Developing a Government-Wide Regulatory Policy   171 APPENDIX D: Checklist of Anti-Corruption Risks   179 Boxes 2.1 Unclear wording, mandate clarity, and the Rwanda Utilities Regulatory Authority  16 2.2 Promoting competition in Madagascar’s infrastructure sectors   18 2.3 Coordination mechanisms for the Mexican Federal Institute of Telecommunications  19 2.4 Checklist of questions and issues for use in reviews of mandate clarity   20 3.1 A case of insufficient powers for the Latvian Public Utilities Commission?   25 3.2 A checklist for reviewing the adequacy of regulators’ powers   25 4.1 Questions to guide a desk review to determine the appropriate institutional structure and mechanisms needed to ensure independence in a regulator in a post-fragile state  32 5.1 Differing governing structure models: Georgia and Rwanda   35 5.2 View of the Indian Government   41 5.3 Questions for guiding a desk review of a regulator’s decision-making body  42 6.1 Sources of finance for the Rwanda Utilities Regulatory Agency   49 6.2 Limited government audit capacity in Madagascar   50 6.3 Controls on levels of funding by regulatory agencies: Georgia, Rwanda, and Latvia  51 6.4 Failure to hypothecate industry levies to fund the regulator’s operations   54 6.5 The United Kingdom’s Payment Systems Regulator: Financial penalty scheme  56 6.6 Questions for guiding a desk review of regulator funding   57 7.1 What is a declaration of interest?   61 7.2 The Mexican Ethics Code and rules of integrity   61 7.3 Founding legislation for the Rwanda Utilities Regulatory Authority emphasizes integrity  64 7.4 The growth of corruption proofing   66 7.5 Basic questions for guiding a desk review of integrity in a regulatory agency  66 Contents | vii 8.1 Uncertainty and the expropriation of land in Indonesia   73 8.2 Questions for guiding a desk review of predictability   73 9.1 Engagement by the Georgian National Energy and Water Supply Regulatory Commission  78 9.2 The Nepal Telecommunications Authority makes consultation information easily available  78 9.3 Key questions for a desk review of engagement   81 10.1 Finding the right balance between expediting appeals and allowing sufficient time for external review   87 10.2 The development of an appeals process in Rwanda   88 10.3 Checklist for applying the principles   89 11.1 Performance evaluation at the Nepal Telecommunications Authority   94 11.2 Australia’s Essential Services Commission Act develops review mechanism and timing of review, which lead to mandate changes for the regulator   94 11.3 Evaluation of the Rwanda Utilities Regulatory Authority   96 11.4 Applying the principles for performance evaluation   98 12.1 The power sector in Georgia after independence   102 12.2 Reform in the Malagasy electricity industry   103 12.3 Stakeholder engagement by the Georgian National Energy and Water Supply Regulatory Commission   105 13.1 A ministry for reform coordination   110 13.2 The Rwanda Development Board—A central reform body to encourage private-sector investment  111 15.1 Electricity reform in Kosovo   127 15.2 Scanning and principles of regulation matrix   128 15.3 The Kenyan Business Regulatory Reform Unit   132 15.4 The Rose Revolution as an opportunity for reform   134 16.1 Recap of reasons governments may want to pursue contract renegotiations or change regulatory provisions, despite breaking “continuity”   138 16.2 Lack of continuity on regulatory boards in Kosovo   140 16.3 A lack of policy stability in the Rwanda infrastructure sector—2003–10   142 16.4 Presidential projects in Madagascar   143 16.5 Regional forums for utility regulators   145 C.1 The costs of adopting a regulatory governance policy   172 C.2 Better policy planning and Regulatory Impact Assessment in Georgia and Kosovo  173 C.3 Elements of a basic, national regulatory governance policy statement   174 Figure A.1 The regulatory process: A recurrent cycle   150 Tables ES.1 Ten key principles for governance of regulators   xvi ES.2 Summary of the regulation related to energy regulatory agencies using the 10 principles  xvi ES.3 Summary of the regulation related to telecommunications regulatory agencies using the 10 principles   xviii 5.1 Regulatory commission versus governance board model—key characteristics  36 5.2 Benefits of multisector versus single-sector regulators   40 6.1 Legislated ceilings on regulatory fees   55 Preface Two billion people now live in countries where development outcomes are affected by fragility. Fragile states tend to be characterized by weak governments and institutions, low levels of trust, and the inability to deliver core services to their citizens. To help infrastructure investments succeed in an already difficult environment, while also reducing costs for enforcement and monitoring, gov- ernments may initially opt to lower barriers for market entry by keeping general regulation at a minimum. However, while it is crucial for fragile states to address critical short-term infrastructure needs, they should also rebuild their capacity to create and admin- ister good regulation—and promote the establishment of a coherent and high-quality regulatory system reaching beyond and across specific public-­ private partnership (PPP) solutions. There are several very pertinent reasons for strengthening capacity to manage the regulatory system early in the state build- ing process, including bolstering state legitimacy and improving conditions for the private sector. Academic post-conflict literature often refers to a “golden hour” after major crises, wars, and instabilities when existing governance struc- tures are left weak and local patronage networks are disrupted. This is the moment when regulatory agencies, particularly those that require institutional autonomy to prevent local capture, are best generated—simply put, when local veto players and rent-seekers lack the capacity to distort the process. Good regulatory practices can make or break policies. Studies show a strong correlation between regulatory quality and economic growth, improved governance and higher incomes. Eliminating cumbersome procedures and red ­ tape, while sometimes necessary, is usually not enough to achieve sustainable regulatory reform. Optimizing the technical capacities of sectoral regulators to control utility delivery efficiently is also important. These are some of the regulatory governance challenges that governments must address to ensure a high-quality and reliable regulatory environment for investments in infrastructure sectors. Equally important is the central govern- ment’s capacity to establish and maintain a coherent and accountable gover- nance structure for regulators across sectors. Without such capacity, experience has shown that “independent regulators” become unaccountable islands of expertise, which can contribute to significant uncertainties both for potential  ix x | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS investors and regulated entities. These challenges become particularly pertinent in the case of fragile states,1 with limited capacity to adjust and correct regulatory regimes that have been poorly designed from the outset. This manual was prepared to develop and strengthen good practices in this field. The target audience includes policymakers and regulators in developing countries, other reform stakeholders, World Bank technical teams, and other experts. The project was developed and managed by the World Bank’s Regulatory Policy and Management Team (initially located in the World Bank’s Global Governance Practice, subsequently with the Macroeconomics, Trade and Investment [MTI] Global Practice) in close collaboration with the Public- Private Infrastructure Advisory Facility (PPIAF). Early drafts of the report were p ­ repared by Rex Deighton-Smith and Peter Carroll (Consultants). The project team was led by Peter Ladegaard (Lead Private Sector Specialist, MTI) and consisted of Petter Lundkvist (Regulatory Specialist, MTI) and Christine Shepherd Vermeulen (Consultant, MTI/PPIAF). The PPIAF team consisted of Jemima Sy (Program Manager), Sara Ahmed (Operations Analyst, Global Knowledge), Luciana Guimaraes Drummond e Silva (Global Knowledge Coordinator), Giulia Motolese (Global Knowledge Consultant), Philippe Neves (Senior Infrastructure Specialist), and Svitlana Orekhova (Global Knowledge Consultant). Valuable comments were received throughout the project from Professor Mark A. Jamison and Professor Sanford V. Berg (Public Utility Research Center, University of Florida). In addition, important guidance and comments were pro- vided by an advisory group of World Bank experts consisting of Catherine Kadennyeka Masinde (Practice Manager, Global Business Regulation, MTI), Ana Bellver (Global Lead for Government Service Delivery, Governance Global Practice [GGP]), Jerome Bezzina (Senior Regulatory Economist, Transport and Digital Development Global Practice), Helene Grandvoinnet (Co-Lead of GGP Fragility, Conflict, and Violence [FCV] working group), Junglim Hahm (Senior Infrastructure Specialist, PPIAF), Asbjorn Haland Wee (Senior Operations Officer, FCV Cross-Cutting Practice), Joanna Kata-Blackman (Senior Operations Officer, International Finance Corporation [IFC]), Tim Kelly (Lead Information and Communications Technologies Policy Specialist, Transport and Digital Development Global Practice), Daniela Henrike Klau-Panhans (Senior Operations Officer, FCV Cross-Cutting Practice), S. Akhtar Mahmood (Lead Private Sector Specialist, Global Business Regulation Unit [GMTBR]), Yogita Mumssen (Senior Infrastructure Economist, Water Global Practice), Fernanda Ruiz Nunez (Senior Economist, PPP Cross-Cutting Practice), Markus Scheuermaier (Senior Operations Officer, IFC), and Heba Shamseldin (Lead Private Sector Specialist, MTI). The publication was prepared under the overall guidance of Caroline Freund, Director, Trade, Regional Integration, and Investment Climate, Macroeconomics, Trade and Investment, World Bank Group; and Jordan Schwartz, Director, Infrastructure Finance, PPPs and Guarantees, World Bank. This publication is part of the third phase of PPIAF’s Improving Infrastructure Regulation for Low-Income, Fragile and Low-Capacity Countries Program, con- ducted between 2016 and 2018. This program aims to support the development of sustainable regulatory systems and improve the delivery of infrastructure ser- vices by building regulators’ capacity to design and implement regulatory func- tions. Phases 1 and 2 developed the content and tools for regulators in developing Preface | xi countries with low regulatory capacity. The resources developed in the first two phases included an updated Body of Knowledge on Infrastructure Regulation (BoKIR), identification and analysis of best practices for regulation in low-­ capacity contexts, a regulatory maturity taxonomy, and a self-assessment tool. These resources were disseminated online to make them more accessible to practitioners. NOTE 1. For the purposes of this document, “fragile” countries are those included in the World Bank’s Harmonized List of Fragile Situations (see https://www.worldbank.org/en/topic​ /fragilityconflictviolence/brief/harmonized-list-of-fragile-situations). Executive Summary CONTEXT Countries exiting situations of fragility face many urgent priorities and almost invariably suffer from substantial infrastructure deficits. During periods of fra- gility and conflict there is typically very little infrastructure investment, while existing installations are often damaged or destroyed. Immediately after the conflict, especially in poor, rural or peri-urban areas, small-scale providers often emerge to respond to pent-up demand for infrastructure services. While the ­ services they offer, are often expensive and of uncertain quality, they fill a gap  because private investment in infrastructure is limited at such times (Schwartz, Hahn, and Bannon 2004). Building or rebuilding infrastructure on a larger scale that provides high qual- ity services to greater numbers of people at a more affordable rate, requires that countries exiting fragility raise capital to finance the projects; yet they have lim- ited ability to do so. As a result, there is a strong need for private investment. The limited presence of local investors and capital suggests that much of this funding needs to come from foreign sources. Attracting this investment requires that governments ensure an investment climate sufficiently appealing to attract pri- vate and foreign investors, who require returns on their capital commensurate with the risks—invariably high in fragile environments. Indeed, research points to a significant correlation between the risk rating of conflict-affected countries and their success in attracting investment in private infrastructure projects (Schwartz, Hahn, and Bannon 2004). Building a favorable investment climate entails a wide range of factors, with some of the most basic including secure property rights, the enforceability of contracts by an impartial legal system and the free movement of capital. The quality of the regulatory system is also widely recognized as a fundamental ele- ment in this equation: research has found that limited regulatory capacity has an adverse impact on economic growth and, in turn, on a range of social issues (see, for example, Chisari, Estache, and Romero 1999; Estache and Rossi 2005; Jalilian, Kirkpatrick, and Parker 2007; Zhang, Parker, and Kirkpatrick 2005). Thus, while fragile states face an immediate need to focus on reconstruction in post-conflict situations, it is just as important for them to address the medium- and long-term  xiii xiv | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS objectives of creating an institutional, legal and regulatory environment to attract private investment (Bray 2004). Appendix B summarizes the literature on the links between regulatory capac- ity and economic performance, as well as on the more limited, but rapidly grow- ing, research on the connections between regulatory governance (including the governance of regulators) and economic outcomes. A wide body of literature devoted to infrastructure regulation exists and has helped guide the development of this manual. For example, the reader is encour- aged to examine the World Bank’s Body of Knowledge on Infrastructure Regulation.1 This provides an excellent summary of most of the literature, as well as links to key texts and documents. PURPOSE This purpose of this manual is to contribute to improvements in the quality of infrastructure regulation in countries exiting situations of conflict and fragility. It does so by identifying key principles for the governance of infrastructure ­ regulatory agencies, and by suggesting how those principles can be introduced successfully and maintained over time. The introduction of cross-cutting gover- nance principles for regulators is based on the assumption that a uniform set of governance principles can be less costly and complex for governments to imple- ment and enforce, and will provide potential investors with a more consistent and predictable regulatory environment to navigate. Consequently, it is assumed that improvements in governance frameworks for infrastructure regulators will support better and accountable regulatory decision-making, as well as increased investment and overall economic development. WHO IS THE AUDIENCE? The manual can be used by policymakers and experts when legislation is being developed to implement the new regulatory arrangements needed to support a new, competitive structure in a key infrastructure industry. The principles and associated strategies can also serve as a frame of reference for subsequent reviews of the progress of the reforms as well as in the context of an ad hoc review and reform activity that responds to specific problems. In the latter, it is feasible to address only a subset of the principles. This publication is accompanied by materials for a 2-day training program, building on the findings of this book. The program targets analysts, practitioners, or key stakeholders concerned with revitalizing and reforming regulatory systems. It presents ideas, concepts, and perspectives designed to improve ­ decision-making. Moreover, modules based on this book are available for online ­ access on the Body of Knowledge on Infrastructure Regulation (http://­ regulationbodyofknowledge.org). DEFINING “GOVERNANCE OF REGULATORS” The term “governance” refers to the rules that govern the establishment and operation of an organization. Governance concerns the processes whereby Executive Summary | xv organizations make and implement decisions, including how those decisions can be challenged or appealed. Working to ensure good governance provides a sys- tematic way of certifying that an organization has a clear set of objectives and functions, and that it acts consistently in their pursuit. In other words, ensuring good governance is a systemic way of pursuing good outcomes. The governance of regulators is one element within the regulatory gover- nance concept. It refers to the processes whereby regulatory agencies are estab- lished, and their operations governed. Thus, it is concerned with the means of regulatory design, implementation and enforcement. By systematically enhanc- ing regulatory practices over time, improved governance of regulators strength- ens the legitimacy and credibility of both the regulators and the regulation they administer, building trust among the regulated. Definitions of other key concepts used throughout the report can be found in Appendix A. DEFINING “FRAGILITY” This guide often uses the term “fragile” to refer to those countries once classified as fragile and conflict affected, as per the World Bank Group’s Harmonized List of Fragile Situations. Some of the discussion, however, pertains more broadly to “fragile” countries or situations within countries, irrespective of their classifica- tion in the “Harmonized List.” The discussion and principles presented in this guide would be relevant in all cases of fragility, where there is structurally increased risk of events with extreme consequences. The key drivers of these risks include weak state capacity and poor legitimacy and accountability; socie- tal mistrusts and fractures; poor economic resilience (shocks to income are asso- ciated with increases in conflicts); and the lack of capacity to protect firms and families from violence and conflicts. PRINCIPLES OF THE GOVERNANCE OF REGULATORS The Guide identifies 10 key principles needed to establish a sound governance structure for an infrastructure regulator, and how the principles can be addressed in fragile contexts. These principles and their application are described in detail in Section B of this guide and are outlined in table ES.1. Section B of this guide is complemented by five case studies, which examined how these principles manifested in the telecommunications and/or energy ­sectors2 in Georgia, Kosovo, Madagascar, Nepal and Rwanda; all countries “exiting” or that have recently “exited” fragile status. The cases were selected ­ based on regional distribution and exhibited a range of fragility drivers—from conflict, both between internal factions (Georgia, Nepal and Rwanda) and between internal and external forces (Kosovo); economic collapse due to a change in economic model, (Georgia, Kosovo, Madagascar) aggravated by high corruption (Georgia and Madagascar); and extreme political upheaval and insta- bility (Madagascar and Nepal); and, social fractures (Kosovo and Rwanda). Tables ES.2 and ES.3 provide overviews of how the energy and telecom regulatory agencies and their related laws and regulation in the case countries, ­ fared against the “best-in-class” ideal of the 10 principles. The case studies underscored that the principles are mutually reinforcing and inter-related. For example, mandate clarity is important only if the regulator xvi | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS TABLE ES.1  Ten key principles for governance of regulators PRINCIPLE DESCRIPTION Principle 1—Mandate Clarity Regulators should have a clearly defined mandate, which consists of its overall purpose or goal, its specific objectives or aims, and the functions it is required to undertake. Principle 2—Requisite powers The regulator should have the legal authority necessary to undertake the functions and responsibilities assigned to it. Principle 3—Independence For infrastructure regulation, it is important for regulatory decision-making to be independent of political processes. Principle 4—Decision-making Regulators require governance arrangements that ensure they operate effectively, provide for and governing body high-quality decision-making, safeguard the agency’s regulatory integrity, and deliver the objectives of their mandate. Principle 5—Funding The regulator must have access to sufficient resources to allow it to carry out its assigned functions effectively, while funding must be supplied in ways that do not risk distorting the regulator’s decisions. Principle 6—Integrity As with all public governance, regulatory agencies must demonstrate high standards of integrity. Principle 7—Predictability Individual decisions made by regulators should, to a substantial degree, be predictable for regulated entities. Principle 8—Engagement Regulators should have established mechanisms for consultation and dialogue with stakeholders as part of achieving their objectives. Principle 9—Accountability Regulators should be accountable to their governments and parliaments, as well as to regulated and transparency entities and the public, for their decisions and use of resources. Principle 10—Performance Evaluations of the performance of regulators should consider both their effectiveness in carrying evaluation out the functions assigned to them both in legislation and through other directives and the fitness for purpose of the regulatory structures that are in place. TABLE ES.2  Summary of the regulation related to energy regulatory agencies using the 10 principles GEORGIA KOSOVO RWANDA MADAGASCAR NEPAL Mandate Clarity ✓ ✓✓ ✓ ✓ ✓✓ High legal clarity, High legal clarity; yet High legal clarity but Limited legal clarity High level of legal except for its role in vague on tariffs and some conflict partially overcome, clarity. Practical competition; less so strengthening between objectives but led to implementation in practice. socio-economic and no provision for uncertainty and tough due to low cohesion. reviewing laws. limited coordination, level of role clarity exacerbated by low of past body. funding. Requisite powers ✓ ✓✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ Appropriate powers Appropriate powers Appropriate powers Powers in place Several powers specified in law; specified in law. specified in law but though insufficient established in new except regarding limited in practice for setting tariffs, law not yet put into policy advice and by the exercise of standards, and for practice, especially competition. Presidential dealing with regarding tariffs. authority. consumer complaints. Independence ✓ ✓✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ High level of High level of High level of High level of legal High level of independence in law independence in law independence in law independence independence in restricted in practice restricted in practice restricted in practice restricted by civil law, subject to by funding by funding by President’s power service Board constraints. Limited arrangements. arrangements. to appoint chair. members and experience of new overlapping regulator. responsibilities to ministers. continued Executive Summary | xvii TABLE ES.2, continued GEORGIA KOSOVO RWANDA MADAGASCAR NEPAL Governing body ✓✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓✓ An appropriate Appropriate Appropriate Partly appropriate New law structure and structure and structure and structure but Chair is establishes decision-making decision-making decision-making also CEO, and a appropriate processes. processes except for processes; except for there is lack of detail appointment appointment of appointment of regarding some structure, though commissioners. Managing Director. processes. grounds for removal too broad. Funding ✓✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ Largely self-funding Self-funding in law Largely self-funding Limited degree of Law establishes with a cap on fee but difficulties with a cap on fee self-funding also appropriate levels. caused in the levels but lacks a limited by lack of funding budget approval fund to cover legal budgetary authority arrangements, but process. costs. and independence. does not specify budget-setting process. Integrity ✓ ✓ ✓ NA ✓ Appropriate legal Appropriate legal An appropriate legal Lack of formal Broadly suitable basis for integrity; basis with a code of basis for integrity attention to integrity integrity measures, practical conduct but not but seems to lack a in law and practice, but lacking appeals enforcement limited. published on its code of conduct. with no code of process under new website. behavior. NERC Act. Predictability ✓✓ ✓✓ ✓ ✓ NA Increasingly Increasingly Increasingly Increasing but Lack of sophisticated body sophisticated body sophisticated body limited degree of mechanisms to of regulation and of regulation and of regulation and predictability, ensure predictable plans has increased plans has increased more predictability especially for key decision-making. predictability of predictability of of decision-making; decisions, for History of decision-making. decision-making. but Presidential example, tariffs and corruption, political powers can cause consumer interference and uncertainty. complaints. insufficient funding lead to a lack of predictability. Engagement ✓✓ ✓✓ NA ✓ ✓ A substantial Substantial No regulatory Very limited legal New law requires regulatory basis for regulatory basis for requirements or basis for formal engagement engagement with engagement largely practice of engagement (no on some, but not high levels of access; complied with in consultation with formal policy), all key issues. largely done in practice. stakeholders or the though in practice a Practice shows practice. public. degree of relatively consistent consultation takes approach. place. Accountability ✓✓ ✓✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ and transparency Laws provide for Laws provide for a Growing Law provides for New law includes high accountability, high degree of accountability and several means of several transparency, appeal accountability and transparency but accountability but transparency and rights. transparency. limited regarding there is a lack of accountability rights of appeal and agency transparency. mechanisms, consultation. though gaps exist; actual practice is yet to evolve. Performance NA NA ✓ NA NA evaluation Not prescribed or Not prescribed or Some evaluation Not prescribed or Not prescribed or used. used. required in law; used. used. being put into practice. Note: Extent to which each principle has been addressed: ✓✓ = principle fully addressed; ✓ = principle partly addressed; NA = principle not addressed. NERC = Nepal Electricity Regulatory Commission. xviii | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS TABLE ES.3  Summary of the regulation related to telecommunications regulatory agencies using the 10 principles MADAGASCAR KOSOVO NEPAL Role Clarity ✓ ✓✓ ✓ A lack of role clarity and funds have The law provides a high degree of The role is outlined in generally severely restricted performance. A role clarity for the regulator. clear detail in the law but in current review might remedy these practice some of its functions have weaknesses. been ineffectively implemented, notably in relation to competition. Requisite powers ✓ ✓✓ ✓ While endowed with a wide range The formal powers provided by the In law there are appropriate powers of formal powers it cannot set law are appropriate and adequate. but, in practice, they are more tariffs, lacks power relating to cyber limited with considerable security and, in practice has given government use of a general power little attention to competition or to give directives to the agency, consumer issues. and the lack of detailed and transparent procedures for the removal of board members. Independence ✓ ✓ ✓ In law there is considerable In law there is a reasonable degree In law there is a reasonable degree independence. In practice it is of independence. In practice of independence for the agency limited as regards appointment of financial procedures substantially but this is limited in practice by the board members, strategy and limit independence. government’s use of its power of finance. directive. Governing body ✓ ✓✓ ✓ In law there is an appropriate The law establishes the agency on The law establishes the agency on governing body and key decision sound governance principles. generally sound governance processes. In practice, there is principles, again limited in practice considerable ministerial by the government’s use or involvement, representative board potential use of its power of members and a lack of detail directive. regarding appointment processes. Funding ✓ ✓ ✓ The agency has a limited degree of Unusually, the National Assembly is The law provides for self-funding financial independence but no to approve the agency’s budget and separate accounts. The setting authority in relation to setting fees. although in practice negotiations of license fees and royalties has are with the Ministry of Finance. It been by a tendering process rather has no control over its budget and than on the basis of the recovery of limited financial autonomy. regulatory costs. Integrity ✓ ✓ ✓ There is no explicit clause in the While the law includes a number of The law includes a number of statute regarding integrity or the articles aimed at reducing conflicts articles aimed at reducing conflicts need for a code of behavior. of interest, it does not require the of interest but does not require a development of codes of behavior, code of behavior and there are no nor has the agency developed such required procedures for removing a code. board members. Predictability ✓ NA ✓ Most key decision procedures are The law does not require decision Detailed operational rules based on outlined, briefly, in the law, with the rules to be developed and the legislation have been developed exception of those in relation to agency either has not developed and included in new legislation. competition and consumer them or made them available on its This could improve decision- complaints. website, so predictability is limited. making predictability, assuming levels of corruption fall sharply. Engagement NA ✓✓ ✓ While there has been a new interest The law establishes an appropriate The law has been largely silent in engagement, there is no policy basis for engagement which seem regarding engagement, but, in in this regard and little signs of to be followed in practice, with practice, the agency has practical activity to increase good feedback processes. undertaken on a discretionary basis effective engagement. a relatively high degree of consultation. continued Executive Summary | xix TABLE ES.3, continued MADAGASCAR KOSOVO NEPAL Accountability ✓ ✓ ✓ and transparency The law provides a limited basis to Unusually, the agency is accountable The law contains reference to achieve accountability to ministries, to the National Assembly, not the limited, traditional means for but not to operators or Parliament, Government. This breaks the chain accountability and transparency with a marked lack of transparency. of accountability and limits the and the agency website contains ability of Governments to ensure substantial material to relevant accountability. Frequent elections policies, principles, and procedures. limit the extent to which the However, there is no indication that Assembly can hold the agency independent review of decisions is accountable. available. Performance NA ✓ NA evaluation No explicit requirement for The law does not explicitly require The law does not explicitly require performance evaluation, nor is it performance evaluation but performance evaluation. undertaken in practice. provides general powers that could enable it, but it has not been implemented. Note: Extent to which each principle has been addressed: ✓✓ = principle fully addressed; ✓ = principle partly addressed; NA = principle not addressed. is also able to fully exercise its requisite power; and performance evaluation strengthens the accountability of the regulator. However, despite each country’s different circumstances, the case studies illustrated common path constraints, suggesting that the absence of some of the principles, above others, pose an immediate challenge requiring attention at an early stage in designing regulatory frameworks in post-fragile contexts, namely: • Mandate Clarity, • Predictability, and • Engagement. Assessing and determining the clarity of a regulator’s mandate should begin in the immediate post-fragile stage. Specifying a regulator’s mandate involves identifying its purpose and objectives and setting out the functions it is required to undertake. These need to be clearly understood so that the regulator can set appropriate priorities and develop strategies to ensure their achievement. Clearly specifying the regulator’s mandate is also a precondition for effective evaluation of its performance over time and, in a more general sense, for holding the regulator and its officials accountable for their actions. Doing so involves drafting legislation, which in fragile contexts, due to capacity constraints, can prove challenging. As a work-around, those determining a regulator’s mandate could use key elements of legislation from similar jurisdictions and customize them. Particularly in the fragile context, continuous assessment is needed to ensure that the regulator’s mandate is feasible. Related to providing clarity of mandate for the regulator, ensuring the regula- tor has “requisite powers” that are clearly communicated and understood by relevant stakeholders as well as establishing the regulator’s mechanisms for “stakeholder engagement” are important. Developing a regulator with clarity of mission, strength of powers and robust mechanisms for engaging with all rele- vant stakeholder groups is helpful to guard against possible “regulatory capture,” whereby the regulator is beholden to powerful stakeholder groups. This risk of capture may be more prevalent in fragile contexts, where conflict may have erupted along ethnic or cultural lines or there are vested economic interests and risk of well-connected groups overpowering the interests of others. xx | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS Further, achieving regulatory “predictability” in post-fragile environments is helpful to ensuring the strength of the regulatory system and creating an envi- ronment favorable to outside investment. This may prove challenging, though establishing it should be a high priority. Establishing regulatory functions in law, helping the regulator publish material on how it will carry out its duties, provid- ing regulator staff with clear guidelines so they know how to carry out their duties, and publishing formal written policies are all steps a government can take to help establish regulatory predictability. IMPLEMENTING REGULATORY GOVERNANCE REFORMS In addition to giving context to how the principles could work in post-fragile contexts, the case studies surfaced key lessons that helped formulate the strate- gic advice found in Part C of the guide, which discusses how to manage imple- menting regulatory governance reforms. These lessons pertain to the broad task of adopting and maintaining a program of reform of the regulation of one or more infrastructure sectors, including the establishment of a regulatory agency in accordance with the principles and include: 1. The need to develop a regulatory governance policy and reform strat- egy at an early stage—The cases indicated that little attention is given to policies necessary for robust regulatory governance. Instead, reforms follow- ing fragile situations typically focused on addressing the urgent challenges faced by the sector (asset destruction, financial collapse, etc.) Yet major fail- ings in the regulatory system were frequently key factors frustrating reform initiatives. This suggests that the issue of regulatory policy and governance should be included as a priority item in, for example, post-conflict needs assessment and planning, followed by the adoption and monitoring of rele- vant indicators of progress, for periodic review by cabinet, or the equivalent. This does not mean that widespread regulatory reform should be undertaken while still in fragility. Rather, a basic policy framework should be put in place as part of post-fragility planning and progress made on specific reforms sequentially, in accordance with the specific needs and circumstances of the individual state in question. In addition to establishing a basic policy frame- work, a system-wide evaluation of the state of current regulatory manage- ment practices, including any existing, underlying regulatory policy, should be undertaken. The evaluation should aim to at least: identify major weak- nesses and strengths in regulatory management practices to guide later, rele- vant reforms; and assign priorities to the areas requiring reform.  Well directed and substantial donor aid can help bring about relatively rapid regulatory reform, especially in the infrastructure sector. Where this is not made available, or is available only on a much smaller scale, regulatory reform is likely to be far slower and performance on global rankings much poorer. This reflects both the limited regulatory governance capacities avail- able within government administrations and the importance of opposition from entrenched interests and suggests that governments in countries exiting fragile countries should actively seek partnerships to enable the adoption of early regulatory reform efforts, particularly given the importance of such efforts in enabling and maintaining broader reform in the medium term. 2. The need to assign authority and responsibility for regulatory policy reform to a strong minister at the center of government—A significant fac- tor in the success of specific regulatory and governance reforms was the Executive Summary | xxi allocation of oversight responsibility and appropriate authority to a senior and influential minister, sometimes the Prime Minister or President, at the center of government. This provided a visible sign of the government’s commitment to the reforms, increasing the influence of the officials responsible for implementing the various reforms. This strengthened their role clarity and enhanced the legit- imacy and requisite authority of the eventual regulatory framework established. 3. The need for policy stability—A key risk in recently reformed sectors is that disappointing regulatory performances lead to frequent changes in the institu- tional architecture, with recently established regulators subject to major restructuring or even abolished and replaced with new entities. It is important to recognize that the development of regulatory capacity and credibility, and a reputation for having these qualities, takes significant time to generate. This suggests the need to give significant weight to policy stability as a key objective. This, in turn, is likely to imply seeking to work within the existing regulatory architecture to address emerging issues, wherever reasonably ­ possible, rather than undertaking major changes within short periods. Policy stability improves the experience and capacity of the regulator, increases familiarity of market participants to the rules of engagement and therefore, enhances predictability. 4. The need to take a strategic view of the question of privatization of state enterprises in the context of low-income states with a shallow bench of local private sector and financial markets—Governments in all countries studied rapidly adopted policies to privatize the bulk of the state enterprise sectors. This proved in all cases to be a difficult, lengthy and frequently unsuc- cessful exercise. This result reflected several factors, including the relatively small formal private sectors, lack of fully functioning financial markets, cor- ruption, the opposition of powerful, senior managers of state enterprises, lack of sufficient domestic private sector capital and the reluctance of foreign investors to enter the market. This suggests that the initial reform should be step-wise. It can focus, initially, on the restructuring of state enterprises, with a more considered privatization program being adopted progressively in the medium-term, as government and regulatory capacities develop, and growing investor confidence means that private investment in the infrastructure and other sectors dominated by state enterprises becomes more attractive.  Where infrastructure is dominated by state owned enterprises with monopoly positions, a key risk is that poorly planned privatizations would simply have created private sector monopolies, the effective regulation of which would have proved an extremely challenging task, given low capacities in this area. Systematic engagement with stakeholders through transparent, formal mechanisms can guard against “regulatory capture” by one or more stakeholder. Key data and adequate market-sounding and consultation needs to underpin decision-making.  Moreover, given the status of many state enterprises as public monopoly providers of key infrastructure services, significant attention should be paid to ­ improving governance arrangements within these entities as part of the restruc- turing process. Improving governance, including adequate transparency and accountability in respect of these incumbent service providers can greatly facil- itate the task faced by independent regulators that are typically established as private participation in infrastructure is established and expanded. 5. The need to ensure that the design of regulatory bodies is cognizant of both the broader governance environment and key capacity con- straints—Both the overall degree of independence accorded to a regulator and the distribution of responsibilities between regulators and government xxii | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS Ministries should be considered, in part, as a function of the governance envi- ronment. Where there are significant concerns about the quality of public governance generally, establishing a regulator with substantial independence, subject to appropriate accountability mechanisms can be an effective means of enhancing the credibility of regulation. However, where capacities are low, there can be major challenges in estab- lishing independent regulators with sufficient expertise and resources that can effectively perform their functions. In such contexts, considerations should be given the adoption of a single regulator with responsibilities that can be progres- sively extended across several infrastructure sectors as the reform process unfolds. This option can help to leverage limited regulatory expertise and ensure that the regulation of newly-reformed sectors is undertaken from the outside by an established and credible entity. It can also potentially reduce overall regula- tory costs and increase the effectiveness of knowledge transfer where external expertise is brought into play to address key regulatory issues. In addition, the lack of knowledge, experience and expertise of officials and regulators regarding the operation of markets, the determinants of economic growth and the role of high quality regulation in underpinning efficient markets was a major factor inhibiting reform in all three cases. This suggests that mate- rial on these issues should be included in the earliest training programs provided to senior and mid-level public sector officials in the post-conflict context. NOTES 1. Available at http://regulationbodyofknowledge.org. 2. Investment patterns show private investment can occur immediately after conflict, fol- lowed by investments in the energy sector, whereas they occur much later in transport and the water sector (Schwartz, Hahn, and Bannon 2004). REFERENCES Bray, J. 2004. MIGA’s Experience in Conflict-Affected Countries: The Case of Bosnia and Herzegovina. Social Development Papers. Conflict Prevention and Reconstruction Series, No. 13. Washington, DC: World Bank. http://documents.worldbank.org/curated​ /­en/259151468768013033/MIGAs-experience-in-conflict-affected-countries-the-case-of​ -Bosnia-and-Herzegovina. Chisari, O., A. Estache, and C. Romero. 1999. “Winners and Losers from the Privatization and Regulation of Utilities: Lessons from a General Equilibrium Model of Argentina.” World Bank Economic Review 13 (2): 357–78. Estache, A., and M. A. Rossi. 2005. “Do Regulation and Ownership Drive the Efficiency of Electricity Distribution? Evidence from Latin America.” Economics Letters 86 (2): 253–57. Jalilian, H., C. Kirkpatrick, and D. Parker. 2007. “The Impact of Regulation on Economic Growth in Developing Countries: A Cross-Country Analysis.” World Development 35 (1): 87–103. Schwartz, J., S. Hahn, and I. Bannon. 2004. The Private Sector’s Role in the Provision of Infrastructure in Post-Conflict Countries. Trends and Policy Options Series, No. 1. Washington, DC: World Bank. http://documents.worldbank.org/curated​ /en/619941468141576377​ /­The-private-sectors-role-in-the-provision-of-infrastructure​-in-post-conflict-countries. Zhang, Y., D. Parker, and C. Kirkpatrick. 2005. “Competition, Regulation and Privatisation of Electricity Generation in Developing Countries: Does the Sequencing of the Reforms Matter?” Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance 45 (2–3): 358–79. Abbreviations AFUR African Forum for Utility Regulators BEDU Business Environment Delivery Unit (Kenya) BRRU Business Regulatory Reform Unit (Kenya) EAPIRF East Asia and Pacific Infrastructure Regulatory Forum ERO Energy Regulatory Office (Kosovo) ESCA Essential Services Commission Act (Australia) EWSA Energy, Water and Sanitation Authority (Rwanda) GNEWSRC Georgian National Energy and Water Supply Regulatory Commission IA impact assessment IFC International Finance Corporation KPPU  Commission for the Supervision of Business Competition (Indonesia) LENG Law on Electricity and Natural Gas (Georgia) MCC Ministerial Coordination Committee MD managing director NERC Nepal Electricity Regulatory Commission OECD Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development PAC Project Advisory Committee PPIAF Public-Private Infrastructure Advisory Facility PSR Payment Systems Regulator (United Kingdom) PUC Public Utilities Commission (Latvia) RDB Rwanda Development Board RECO Rwanda Energy Corporation RIA Regulatory Impact Assessments RSC Reform Steering Committee RU Reform Unit RURA Rwanda Utilities Regulatory Authority RWASCO Rwanda Water and Sewerage Corporation  xxiii A Introduction 1 The Importance of Ensuring Good Governance of Regulators INTRODUCTION: THE PURPOSE OF THE MANUAL This manual provides advice aimed at supporting improvements in the quality of infrastructure regulation in countries exiting situations of fragility. Improving the quality of the regulatory systems governing infrastructure will support both increased investment and better performance, thus enhancing overall economic development. This handbook focuses on how to improve the governance of regulatory agencies, since good governance helps to ensure that high-quality ­ regulatory decisions are made systematically. Context Countries exiting situations of fragility face large numbers of urgent priorities and almost invariably suffer from substantial infrastructure deficits. Typically, little infrastructure investment occurs during the fragile and conflict affected period, while existing installations are often damaged or destroyed due to conflict. Immediately after the conflict, especially in poor, rural or peri-urban ­ areas, small-scale providers often emerge to respond to pent-up demand for infrastructure services. While the services they offer, are often expensive and of uncertain quality, they fill a gap because private investment in infrastructure is limited at such times (Schwartz, Hahn and Bannon 2004). Building or rebuilding infrastructure on a larger scale that provides high qual- ity services to greater numbers of people at a more affordable rate, requires that countries exiting fragility raise capital to finance the projects; yet they have lim- ited ability to do so. As a result, there is a strong need for private investment. The limited presence of local investors and capital suggests that much of this funding needs to come from foreign sources. Attracting this investment requires that governments ensure an investment environment sufficiently appealing to attract private and foreign investors, who require returns on their capital commensu- rate with the risks—invariably high in fragile environments. Indeed, research points to a significant correlation between the risk rating of conflict-affected countries and their success in attracting investment in private infrastructure projects (Schwartz, Hahn and Bannon 2004).  3 4 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS Building a favorable investment environment entails a wide range of factors, with some of the most basic including secure property rights, the enforceabil- ity of contracts by an impartial legal system and the free movement of capital. The quality of the regulatory system is also widely recognized as a fundamental element in this equation: researchers have found repeatedly that limited regu- latory capacity has an adverse impact on economic growth and, in turn, on a range of social issues (see, for example, Chisari, Estache, and Romero 1999; Estache and Rossi 2005; Jalilian, Kirkpatrick, and Parker 2007; Zhang, Parker, and Kirkpatrick 2005). Thus, while fragile states face an immediate need to focus on reconstruction in post-conflict situations, it is just as important for them to address the medium- and long-term objectives of creating an institu- tional, legal and regulatory environment to attract private investment (Bray 2004). In the absence of proper regulation, countries become less attractive places to work, do business and live in. Appendix B summarizes the literature on the links between regulatory capacity and economic performance, as well as on the more limited, but rapidly growing, research on the connections between regulatory governance (including the governance of regulators) and economic outcomes. A wide body of literature devoted to infrastructure regulation exists and has helped guide the development of this manual. For example, the reader is strongly encouraged to examine the World Bank’s Body of Knowledge on Infrastructure Regulation.1 This provides an excellent summary of most of the literature, as well as links to key texts and documents. Defining the governance of regulators The term “governance” refers to the rules applied in the establishment and oper- ation of organizations. Governance is concerned with the processes whereby organizations make and implement decisions, including how these can be chal- lenged or appealed. Working to ensure good governance is a way of making cer- tain that an organization has a clear set of objectives and functions, and that it acts consistently in their pursuit. In other words, ensuring good governance is equivalent to pursuing good outcomes. The concept of governance can be applied to a wide range of organizations and situations, both public and private. Public governance is the application of governance principles to the operation of government. Regulatory governance constitutes a specific area of public governance and involves the application of governance principles to the exercise of regulatory powers by governments. Regulatory governance addresses all stages of the regulatory cycle: problem identification and analysis; regulatory development; implementation and enforcement; review and evaluation; and, finally, reform. The governance of regulators is one element within the regulatory gover- nance concept. It refers to the processes used to set up regulatory agencies and govern their operations. Governance of regulators’ concerns regulatory imple- mentation and enforcement. Key elements include: • ensuring that regulators have sufficient independence from government to carry out their authorized functions, and that that regulatory decisions are consistent and impartial; • making certain that the operations of regulators are based on clear legislation which explicitly identifies their objectives, powers, responsibilities and functions; The Importance of Ensuring Good Governance of Regulators | 5 • ensuring that regulators have sufficient funds to carry out their functions and that these funds are provided in a way that does not compromise their inde- pendence or accountability; and • ensuring that the regulator is subject to adequate accountability mechanisms, including reporting requirements and independent appeals processes against regulatory decisions. Governance has both external and internal dimensions. The former aspect relates to an organization’s interaction with its external stakeholders, while the latter refers to the way in which the organization itself is structured and man- aged. In relation to regulators, the external dimensions of governance include the roles and relationships and the distribution of powers and responsibilities between the legislature, the minister responsible, the ministry, the judiciary, the regulator and the regulated. Internal governance dimensions include the regula- tor’s organizational structures, standards of behavior, compliance and account- ability measures, oversight of business processes, financial reporting and performance management. The ten principles of good governance for regulators, listed on page 7 onwards, address both dimensions of governance. They are drawn from a variety of sources and reflect the state of knowledge in the application of general governance prin- ciples to the specific context of regulators, with particular reference to infra- structure. The principles are applicable in a wide range of country ­ contexts. However, Part B highlights key considerations that arise as regards countries exiting fragility. Improving regulatory governance The linkage between improved regulatory capacities and better economic per- formance is well established. According to the World Bank: Good regulatory practices can determine the prospects for policy success or failure. Studies show strong correlations between regulatory quality and eco- nomic growth, better governance quality and higher incomes per capita. (World Bank 2015) This means that all countries have an incentive to improve the quality of their regulatory systems across all major policy areas. Improving regulatory gover- nance constitutes a systematic means of improving regulatory quality and has become the preferred approach in a wide range in many countries. By systematically enhancing regulatory practices over time, improved regula- tory governance strengthens the legitimacy and credibility of regulators and the regulation they administer, and helps to build trust among those being regulated. Within an established national policy, well-designed systems of regulatory gov- ernance can: • improve the ongoing review and assessment of regulatory processes and practices, yielding improved regulatory quality over time; • improve regulatory practice, using well-targeted review and assessment processes to help make management more consistent and predictable; • promote greater innovation in organizational structures, processes and practices, encouraging regulators to work more strategically by promoting more systematic approaches to day-to-day operations; • encourage politicians and senior executives to grant more discretion to regulators to apply regulation more flexibly, as better regulatory governance systems lead to enhanced accountability and transparency in operations; and ­ 6 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS • encourage more effective cooperation between regulators and those being regulated, with more transparent, consistent and predictable regula- tory practice leading to greater trust and more positive relationships. However, achieving and sustaining such improvements is a complex and mul- tifaceted task, especially as most post-fragile states have limited regulatory capacity. Regulatory institutions in such countries are often only a few years old, still gaining experience and attempting to build their management capacity (Eberhard 2006). In addition, regulatory frameworks and institutions estab- lished in developing countries are often based on prescriptions and models drawn from more developed nations. These may not translate readily into less-developed or fragile contexts (see Laffont 2005). Strategies for developing regulatory governance in fragile states must take account of key contextual dif- ferences. They must also acknowledge the fact that in an fragile context, gover- nance and institutional development tend to progress intermittently, given scarce human and financial resources and varying levels of political support. This manual takes these factors into account and seeks to tailor its advice to the post-fragile context as far as possible. It draws on a consistent, well-founded set of principles and shows how they can be applied in both the evaluation of existing regulatory governance systems and the implementation of programs aimed at reforming those systems. Importantly, while the principles discussed in the manual can apply to a range of situations, it is recognized that different contexts require diverse approaches regarding, for example, priorities, pace and timing. The following discussion recognizes the importance of socio-economic and political contexts in determining how the principles should be applied and tailors the advice pro- vided specifically towards post-fragile contexts. That said, it is important to acknowledge that there are substantial differences even among post-fragile countries. Thus, the advice provided must be assessed carefully in the light of where it is to be adopted, and modified accordingly. The organization of the manual The remainder of this manual is divided into two main parts: • Part B identifies and discusses the application of ten principles forming the basis of a high-quality system of governance for infrastructure regulators. It is intended to help readers to determine key areas of weakness in current governance arrangements and priorities for reform. • Part C focuses on designing and implementing a program of reform for exist- ing governance systems and assessing capacities for achieving such reform. It also provides advice on using the ten principles to diagnose the strengths and weaknesses of existing governance arrangements, and set priorities for reform, as well as providing a governance template for establishing new reg- ulatory agencies where required.2 A FRAMEWORK FOR THE MANUAL—TEN PRINCIPLES FOR THE GOVERNANCE OF REGULATORS The view that systems of governance should be based on a set of clearly specified principles is not new: Principles exist for a wide range of governance ­ The Importance of Ensuring Good Governance of Regulators | 7 ­ ontexts, like corporate governance, community governance, and environmen- c tal  governance. In some cases, like the AS 8000 Australian Standard Good Governance Principles, countries develop national standards for good gover- nance intended to be generally applicable. However, the development of under- lying principles for regulatory governance is more recent, emerging gradually from several decades of experience with regulatory reform, in both World Bank client countries and OECD nations. While a country’s context will drive the types of regulatory practices, systems and agencies developed, as well as determine how they evolve in response to economic, social and political changes, a consistent set of principles should underpin them. These principles should be at the basis of a national policy for regulatory governance that aims to ensure systematically that the regulator’s decisions are transparent, objective, impartial, and serve the public interest. Ten principles for the governance of regulators The following briefly introduces the ten principles that form the basis of this manual. While the principles draw on a range of sources, they rely particularly on previous work undertaken by Brown et al. (2006) and the OECD (2014). Part B provides more detail regarding the meaning of the principles, their importance and their implementation in the post-fragile context. The ten principles are: 1. Mandate Clarity. The regulator’s purpose and regulatory objectives should be clearly defined and communicated to the regulator, the regulated, and the general public. 2. Requisite powers. The regulatory agency should have the authority to make final decisions within its statutory domain without having to obtain approval from any other government body. That authority varies with the regulator’s objectives and functions, but typically includes the power to: • set tariffs; • establish market, technical and service quality rules; • address market power and market design problems; • investigate and adjudicate consumer complaints; • provide dispute resolution mechanisms for regulated entities; • monitor and enforce compliance with its decisions; • apply remedies—including sanctions—when necessary. 3. Independence. There should be a strong presumption in favor of establish- ing an independent body or bodies to regulate infrastructure. Where lack of qualified and experienced staff makes this impossible, establishing a regula- tor within a ministry as an “arm’s-length”3 body may be an appropriate interim solution. In this case, administrative and financial arrangements should maximize the independence of the regulator. It should also be clear that this will be a temporary arrangement. 4. Decision-making and governing body. Governance arrangements for reg- ulators should promote efficiency, effectiveness and integrity. Independent regulators most often have governing bodies with several members. This reflects the fact that a pluralistic structure is considered better able to make high-quality decisions because collegiality and joint responsibility support independence and integrity. 5. Funding. Regulators require adequate funding to carry out their duties effectively, and funding arrangements should avoid giving rise to conflicts ­ 8 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS of interest or represent inappropriate incentives. Regulators should receive sufficient funding to do their jobs, but no more.  6. Integrity. Like all public bodies, regulatory agencies must demonstrate high standards of integrity. They must hold all personnel to high standards of con- duct and avoid any suggestion that impropriety or illegal behavior is toler- ated. Regulatory integrity is essential to achieve decision-making which is objective, impartial, consistent, and avoids bias and improper influence. This is a major challenge for the infrastructure sector, where major procurement contracts and the revenue-raising processes involved provide rich opportu- nities for corruption. Hence the need for a system of rules or a code of con- duct to prevent improper conduct and maintain integrity among regulatory decision-makers.  7. Predictability. Predictability implies that stakeholders can forecast, with a high degree of confidence, what decision a regulator is likely to take in given circumstances. Predictability is achieved by establishing and publishing clear decision-making rules and ensuring that the regulator follows them. This enables individuals and organizations to judge what behavior is accept- able and what is not so as to make certain they are acting within the law. It also allows them to determine whether the actions they are contemplating are permitted by the regulatory structure, increasing certainty regarding the investment and operating environments.  8. Engagement. Regulators should engage systematically with stakeholders through transparent, formal mechanisms such as consultations in order to guard against “regulatory capture” by one or more stakeholder. At the same time, such mechanisms should ensure that the regulator has the opportunity to obtain key data and opinions to underpin decision-making.  9. Accountability and transparency. Regulators should be accountable to the government and parliament, the regulated and the general public for their decisions and use of resources. This implies that their actions have a high level of transparency. 10. Performance evaluation. Regulators should measure their outputs so that they can update regulatory actions and internal functioning to improve or maintain efficiency. Performance data should be available to anyone to whom the regulator is accountable, including the regulated and the general public. In addition, when the principles are to be applied as part of a review of regu- lation, it should be noted that the extent to which existing regulation corre- sponds to the principles will vary from country to country, as can be seen in tables ES.2 and ES.3 in the Executive Summary. The tables briefly summarizes the extent to which each of the ten principles is addressed in regulation estab- lishing the energy regulatory agency in five different countries. NOTES 1. Available at http://regulationbodyofknowledge.org. 2. As noted above, readers should also refer to http://regulationbodyofknowledge.org for fur- ther material on improving infrastructure regulation. The material on the site provides a wealth of resources for reformers in this field, including: •  ideas that will assist in the launching or revitalizing of regulatory systems in fragile or conflict-affected states; • a number of key reform strategies; The Importance of Ensuring Good Governance of Regulators | 9 • a self-assessment tool for evaluating a variety of challenging situations; • a variety of case studies; and • a set of Frequently Asked Questions and answers for officials in fragile states. This material can and should be used in conjunction with this manual to help decision­ - makers evaluate their current situation, set priorities for reform and plan implementation strategies to improve the regulatory environment and increase the attractiveness of invest- ment in infrastructure. 3. According to a World Bank definition, arm’s-length bodies are commonly removed from the control of politicians and outside the hierarchical control of traditional vertically-­ integrated line ministries and departments (see Manning and Shepherd 2009). REFERENCES Bray, J. 2004. MIGA’s Experience in Conflict-Affected Countries: The Case of Bosnia and Herzegovina. Social Development Papers. Conflict Prevention and Reconstruction Series, No. 13. Washington, DC: World Bank. http://documents.worldbank.org/curated​ /­en/259151468768013033/MIGAs-experience-in-conflict-affected-countries​-the-case​ -of-Bosnia-and-Herzegovina. Brown, A. C., J. Stern, B. Tenenbaum, and D. Gencer. 2006. Handbook for Evaluating Infrastructure Regulatory Systems. Washington, DC: World Bank. http://documents​ worldbank.org/curated​ .­ /­en/428111468177849284/pdf/364990Handbook101OFFICIAL0USE0ONLY1.pdf. Chisari, O., A. Estache, and C. Romero. 1999. “Winners and Losers from the Privatization and Regulation of Utilities: Lessons from a General Equilibrium Model of Argentina.” World Bank Economic Review 13 (2): 357–78. Eberhard, A. 2006. “Infrastructure Regulation in Developing Countries: An Exploration of Hybrid and Transitional Models.” Paper prepared for the 3rd AFUR (African Forum of Utility Regulators) Annual Conference, Windhoek, March 15–16. Estache, A., and M. A. Rossi. 2005. “Do Regulation and Ownership Drive the Efficiency of Electricity Distribution? Evidence from Latin America.” Economics Letters 86 (2): 253–57. Jalilian, H., C. Kirkpatrick, and D. Parker. 2007. “The Impact of Regulation on Economic Growth in Developing Countries: A Cross-Country Analysis.” World Development 35 (1): 87–103. Laffont, J. J. 2005. Regulation and Development. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Manning, N., and G. Shepherd. 2009. “Arms Length Bodies”. Global Expert Team (GET) Brief.  World Bank, Washington, DC. http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en​ /804021468163449274/pdf/534640BRI0GET01n0title010GET0Briefs.pdf. OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). 2014. The Governance of Regulators. OECD Best Practice Principles for Regulatory Policy. Paris: OECD Publishing. http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264209015-en. Schwartz, J., S. Hahn, and I. Bannon. 2004. The Private Sector’s Role in the Provision of Infrastructure in Post-Conflict Countries. Trends and Policy Options Series, No. 1. Washington, DC: World Bank. http://documents.worldbank.org/curated​/en/619941468141576377​/­The -private-sectors-role-in-the-provision-of-infrastructure​-in-post-conflict-countries. World Bank. 2015. “Regulatory Policy and Management”. June 18. http://www.worldbank.org​ /­e n/topic/governance/ brief/regulatory-policy-and-management-incubator-global​ -­solutions​-groups. Zhang, Y., D. Parker, and C. Kirkpatrick. 2005. “Competition, Regulation and Privatisation of Electricity Generation in Developing Countries: Does the Sequencing of the Reforms Matter?” Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance 45 (2–3): 358–79. B Principles for the Governance of Regulators GOALS OF THE SECTION • To identify and briefly describe the key principles that need to be embodied in a sound governance structure for an infrastructure regulator;1 • to explain how each principle contributes to a quality sys- tem of governance; • to discuss a range of issues related to ensuring the princi- ples are addressed in fragile contexts; using examples drawn from ex-fragile countries; • to provide practical advice on how to implement needed reforms in practice. 12 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS NOTE ON THE PRINCIPLES In situations where a country is developing legislation for regulatory arrange- ments designed to support a new, competitive structure in a key infrastructure sector, all principles should be addressed. Importantly too, the principles should be used as the frame of reference for subsequent reviews assessing the progress of the reforms. Finally, they can be helpful when ad hoc review and reform activ- ity is conducted in response to specific problems. In this context, it is feasible to address only a subset of the principles. Many examples contained in Part B illustrate that, while the principles them- selves are applicable in many country contexts, the specific ways in which they are implemented may differ significantly. Implementation strategies must con- sider the country situation in all cases. Part C considers this point further, taking a broader approach to reform implementation issues and providing additional strategic guidance. IMPLEMENTING THE PRINCIPLES OVER TIME While new legislation for regulatory arrangements should address all principles, the relative importance of the principles can vary both as a function of the initial circumstances of the fragile state in question and as a state gradually moves out of fragility. The translation of principles into specific rules and responsibilities will also need to evolve over time, making periodic progress review and reform of laws and policies a key requirement. In general, mandate clarity, requisite powers and adequate funding, together with a well-designed governing body with appropriate decision procedures, are par- ticularly important in guiding initial moves out of the fragile situation. By contrast, independence and engagement, while always important, grows in relative impor- tance as both the regulatory agency and the sector(s) for which it is responsible develop in scale and sophistication over time. The principles of predictability and performance evaluation can only be addressed substantively once regulators have become established and experience and expertise have developed. However, they then become fundamental to maintaining reform momentum over the longer term. By contrast, the principles of integrity, accountability and transparency are always of great importance as serious deficiencies in these areas are usually accompanied by corruption, regulatory capture, inefficiency and poor performance. Governments may also need to set sectoral priorities in implementing the princi- ples. The telecoms sector is often more readily developed in an early post-conflict situation, as its investment needs can be lesser than other infrastructure sectors and can be more readily recouped within shorter periods. Conversely, the long lead- times for investment in the electricity sector mean that putting the regulatory build- ing blocks in place for the development of the sector at an early stage can also be a key priority. While synergies can be obtained from moving to reform several key sectors simultaneously, capacity constraints will often make this unrealistic in fragile contexts, making the selection of priority sectors a key task. Chapter 15 discusses reform strategy, including the staging of reform. Principles for the Governance of Regulators | 13 NOTE 1. As mentioned above, the principles draw on previous work undertaken by Brown et al. (2006) and the OECD (2014). REFERENCES Brown, A. C., J. Stern, B. Tenenbaum, and D. Gencer. 2006. Handbook for Evaluating Infrastructure Regulatory Systems. Washington, DC: World Bank. http://documents​ .­worldbank.org/curated/en/428111468177849284/pdf/364990Handbook101OFFICIAL0U​ SE0ONLY1.pdf. OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). 2014. The Governance of Regulators. OECD Best Practice Principles for Regulatory Policy. Paris: OECD Publishing. http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264209015-en. 2 Mandate Clarity ABSTRACT Regulators should have a clearly defined mandate, with specific objectives and functions that are clearly linked to the government’s policy objectives for the sector. They should also be able to coordinate their work with that of other enti- ties in a positive, cooperative fashion. KEY TAKEAWAYS General takeaways • A regulator’s purpose and objectives should be clear if it is to do its job effectively. • The regulator’s supervising ministry and the entities it regulates should be transparent on its functions and role; this requires clear communication con- cerning the regulator’s mandate. • The regulatory goal of promoting competition often receives most pushback. • A regulator’s mandate can be evaluated over time and altered later as needed. Takeaways specific to post-fragile contexts • Assessing and determining mandate clarity should begin in the immediate post-fragile stage. • Developing a mandate involves drafting legislation. In fragile contexts, capac- ity constraints can make this difficult. • To work around capacity constraints, those determining a regulator’s mandate could use key elements of legislation from similar jurisdictions and ­ customize them. • Particularly in fragile contexts, continuous assessment is needed to ensure that the regulator’s mandate is feasible.  15 16 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS THE IMPORTANCE OF MANDATE CLARITY Specifying a regulator’s mandate involves identifying its purpose and objec- tives and setting out the functions it is required to undertake. These need to be clearly understood so that the regulator can set appropriate priorities and develop strategies to ensure their achievement. Clearly specifying the regula- tor’s mandate is also a precondition for effective evaluation of its performance over time and, in a more general sense, for holding the regulator and its offi- cials accountable for their actions. As box 2.1 indicates, a lack of clarity can lead to uncertainty as to the appropriate actions for the regulator to take and to delays in decision-making. A regulator’s mandate consists of its overall purpose or goal, its specific objec- tives or aims, and the functions it is required to undertake. These need to be clearly understood so that: • The regulator can set appropriate priorities and develop strategies, plans and related activities to achieve them. • The supervising ministry or department is aware of the regulator’s priorities, strategies, plans and activities and how they fit into the government’s broader policies. • The regulated entities and the public are aware of the regulator’s priorities, strategies, plans and major activities and how they may impact on their activities. • Potential investors, domestic and international, have a clear and easily acces- sible understanding of the regulator’s role regarding their previous or future investments in the sector. • Regular and systematic evaluation can be undertaken of the regulator’s per- formance in achieving its stated goals, objectives and aims. • The agency can be held fully accountable for its actions by assessing its activ- ities in relation to its explicit goals and objectives. BOX 2.1 Unclear wording, mandate clarity, and the Rwanda Utilities Regulatory Authority In 2011, Law No. 21/2011 governing Electricity in to be, “harmonious.” As a result, it was unclear what the Rwanda was introduced, with four objectives identi- Rwanda Utilities Regulatory Authority’s (RURA) role fied: the liberalization and regulation of the electricity should be in regard to achieving the objective. sector; the harmonious development of distribution of Similarly, the requirement for “respect for the electric power for all of the population and for all eco- conditions of fair and loyal competition and for the nomic and social development sectors; the creation of rights of users and operators” does not indicate what conditions enabling electric power investments; is meant by “fair and loyal competition,” or the criteria respect for the conditions of fair and loyal competition to be used in assessing whether the relevant and for the rights of users and operators. “conditions” for achieving it are met. This shows how While the Law was framed to further the “harmoni- important it is to ensure that the regulator’s objectives ous development of distribution of electric power” it did and functions are specified, using commonly not clarify what was meant by “harmonious develop- understood phrases and concepts wherever possible. ment of distribution,” or the criteria to be applied in Any more specialized terms and concepts should be assessing whether a decision or action was, or was likely explained. Mandate Clarity | 17 Discussions involved in clarifying the agency’s mandate provide an opportu- nity for stakeholders to participate in the work of the agency in the early days of its operations. This helps promote understanding and a commitment to the agency’s work. In addition, the development of clear, publicly available docu- ments that describe the role of the regulator help to avoid: • Unnecessary duplication or overlap of functions between regulators and other bodies. Resulting in unnecessary conflict and costs. In Georgia, for example, the supervising ministry had responsibility for attracting short-, medium-, and long-term investments in electricity, a role which overlapped with that of the National Investment Agency. There are sometimes good rea- sons for the existence of overlapping functions and objectives but, where they exist, it is important that the reasons for the overlap are made clear and ways found to coordinate the work of the agencies involved. • Possible non-compliance by those being regulated because of a lack of certainty and understanding of the legislation. This could be the case for those interacting with Rwanda’s utilities regulator, as described in box 2.1. • Compliance and enforcement difficulties caused by a lack of clarity as to the regulator’s authority and responsibility. The Georgian National Energy and Water Supply Regulatory Commission (GNEWSRC), for example, has authority to grant permits and licenses for the siting of electricity generation facilities. However, the Georgian Law on Electricity and Natural Gas specifies that the supervising ministry, not the National Energy and Water Supply Regulatory Commission, has authority for granting permits for facilities that are not to be connected to the transmission grid. This could result in electric- ity enterprises not connected to the power grid facing different conditions than those that were part of the grid, and falling under the authority of the Regulatory Commission. Such conflicts can both create tension between the Ministry and the Commission and lead to strategic behavior by regulated entities seeking to evade the conditions for permits set by either body. • Stakeholder confusion as to compliance obligations. This could occur in the above example of split responsibilities for the issue of permits in Georgia. • Delays, uncertainty and increased costs. These may arise from the need to obtain authoritative interpretations of the meaning of ambiguous terms and phrases. As box 2.1 indicates, a lack of clarity leads to uncertainty on the regulator’s part about what action to take, resulting in delays in decision-making while clarifica- tion is sought. Similarly, a clear statement of the regulator’s objectives and the extent of its authority can help determine the legality of the regulator’s actions. MANDATE CLARITY AND THE GOAL OF COMPETITION Responsibility for promoting competition is an area in which the question of mandate clarity frequently arises. In almost all developing countries, infrastruc- ture sectors are dominated by government monopoly suppliers. Thus, a key objective in reforming the regulatory system governing those sectors is to establish effective competition as extensively as possible. Newly appointed ­ sector regulators are frequently given the explicit objective of encouraging and, ­ if necessary, regulating competition. 18 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS At the same time, broader economic reforms often entail establishing a spe- cialist competition authority, with a remit to address competition issues across the economy. This can give rise to confusion as to the relative responsibilities in this area, particularly where the specific role of the sectoral regulator is not clearly identified. Box 2.2 provides an example. To avert confusion, it is important that legislation governing infrastructure regulators provide specific guidance on the nature and extent of their responsi- bilities in promoting competition, where these are allocated. Consideration should also be given to the appropriate assignment of functions as between  ­ infrastructure regulators and competition authorities. As noted, competition issues should generally be the responsibility of the competition ­ authority rather than industry regulators. However, they are not likely to exist in fragile contexts.1 In such situations, it may be therefore appropriate for sectoral regulators to wield these responsibilities. But clear mechanisms for consultation and cooperation with any competition authority should be established. Regulators should promote an understanding of their mandate by making its functions clear to stakeholders. Mention should also be made of the principles adopted for decision-making and any guidelines developed on what regulated entities should expect, including their responsibilities to the regulator and the consequences of misbehavior. Legislation establishing the regulator should, at the very least, specify the following: • a clear, written purpose and a set of objectives facilitating their achievement; • a set of specific functions clearly linked to the statement of purpose and objectives; • prescribed mechanisms for coordinating its work with other relevant bodies to achieve the desired regulatory outcomes; BOX 2.2 Promoting competition in Madagascar’s infrastructure sectors Legislation governing the regulatory agencies there was little expert guidance available on the spe- responsible for electricity and telecommunications cific responsibilities of the industry regulators regard- (ORE and ARTEC, respectively a) in Madagascar ing competition and it was not viewed as a priority in made them responsible for promoting competition. their work. However, the precise role these regulators would When a competition authority finally emerged in play in fostering competition and the priority that 2015 there was no clear specification—either legisla- should be given to that role, was not detailed in the tive or administrative—as to the respective roles of the relevant legislation. competition authority and existing industry regula- In the post-fragile period, general competition law tors in addressing competition issues. In addition, all was rudimentary and no separate competition author- three regulatory agencies—that is, power, telecommu- ity existed. In 2005, the government formally passed nications and competition—were poorly funded and legislation to establish such an authority, but the lacked expert staff, so that competition continued to implementing decree giving practical effect to the reg- receive limited attention, effectively favoring the con- ulation was not adopted until 10 years later. Hence, tinued dominance of government-owned enterprises. a. Office de Regulation de l’Electricité (ORE) and Autorité de Régulation des Technologies de Communication (ARTEC). Mandate Clarity | 19 • clear and comprehensive statements of responsibilities, powers and duties that distinguish it from other government bodies and agencies that also wield authority in the sector. Mandate clarity is particularly important for regulating bodies that have responsibilities for several infrastructure sectors, such as electricity, gas and water, often known as “multisector regulators.” In such cases, it is vital that rel- evant legislation sets out as precisely as possible the varying objectives and func- tions of the regulator for each sector. While a single law will often address these issues, each sector should be covered in a separate section. Mandate clarity is also important in federal states and those with several ­ levels of government, where separate regulatory agencies may exist at each level. In such cases, where coordination between separate agencies is a priority, it is important that legislation explicitly empowers the agencies to cooperate in the achievement ­ egislation in Mexico. of their objectives. Box 2.3 provides an example of this kind of l ASSESSING MANDATE CLARITY IN THE POST-FRAGILE CONTEXT Assessing mandate clarity for regulators should begin in the immediate post-­ conflict stage, during initial policy development, and continue when the process of legislative drafting begins. Policymakers and drafters should aim to ensure that the draft legislation accurately reflects the original intent of the policy as well as identify and address any ambiguities arising from the development of detailed statements of goals, objectives and functions. This will provide an important and necessary basis for: 1. ensuring that the new or amended legislation assigns requisite powers to the agency (for further details see chapter 3); 2. the process of “corruption proofing,” (for further detail see chapter 3); BOX 2.3 Coordination mechanisms for the Mexican Federal Institute of Telecommunications 1. The Mexican Federal Institute of Telecommuni­ 4. The IFT may receive non-binding opinions from: cations (IFT) will coordinate with the federal • The Ministry of Communications and Transport executive to ensure the installation of a shared (SCT) when granting, revoking or authorizing public telecommunication network that promotes concessions or changes in the control, owner- effective access by the population to broadband ship or operation of companies related to such communication and telecommunications services. concessions. 2. Congress will create an Advisory Council of the IFT, • The Ministry of Finance and Public Credit which will be called on to act as an advisory body. (SHCP) for fixing the fees or dues for the grant- 3. The IFT must notify the federal executive before ing of concessions and the authorization of proceeding with the revocation of concession titles related services. in order for it to obtain, where appropriate, the powers necessary to ensure continuity of service. Source: OECD 2014, 39. 20 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS BOX 2.4 Checklist of questions and issues for use in reviews of mandate clarity 1. What are the goals and objectives of the legislation conflicting objectives? Is this power appropriately and are they clearly defined? constrained? Is its transparency required in its use? 2. Are there any potential conflicts between the 6. Are the respective roles of the minister, ministry objectives? If so, is guidance provided to the and regulator in policy and legislative development regulator on how to manage these conflicts when clearly defined and supported by processes to making regulatory decisions? ensure their effective collaboration? If not, why not, 3. Does the legislation clearly specify the regulator’s and what changes should be introduced? functions? Are these clearly related to achieving the 7. Are there overlaps or gaps in responsibilities identified objectives of the legislation? between regulators, or between the roles of 4. Are the goals, objectives and functions of the regulators, ministries and ministers? If so, what regulator clearly specified and publicly available? If changes are necessary? not, why not? 8. Does the legislation enable the regulator to 5. Does the legislation enable the minister to provide cooperate with other bodies with similar objectives? direction on priority setting when managing If not, what changes are necessary? 3. the process of regulation impact assessment, where this is a requirement, as is increasingly the case; 4. the process of environmental impact assessment. However, qualified and experienced legislative drafters are often in short supply in fragile states, public consultations are frequently limited and there is little informed public debate. Weaknesses can therefore persist after the passing of the legislation, requiring later amendment and further clarification (see Nzanze [2012] for a consideration of the impact on legal drafting of Rwanda’s fragile experience). This issue is acute where legislation must be developed in two or more official languages. In such situations, using key elements of similar legislation sourced from other, relevant jurisdictions can be a useful mechanism. It is important, however, to assess whether any such templates are consistent with local circumstances and needs. Even in the best-resourced policy development and drafting contexts, unan- ticipated problems can arise once new legislation has taken effect. In such cases, it is important to ensure that the practical experience of the new, or reconfigured regulatory agency is assessed, and any problem areas addressed. The views of stakeholders should be weighed in this context, as should feedback from the reg- ulatory agency. Where substantial issues are identified, a more formal assess- ment may be required. Box 2.4 provides a checklist of the types of questions and issues that should be addressed in such a context. NOTE 1. Among the states on the 2018 Harmonized List of Fragile Situations (http://pubdocs​ .worldbank.org/en/189701503418416651/FY18FCSLIST-Final-July-2017.pdf ), only around 20 percent have competition authorities in place. Mandate Clarity | 21 REFERENCES Nzanze, V. 2012. “Challenges of Drafting Laws in One Language and Translating Them: Rwanda’s Experience.” The Loophole, Journal of the Commonwealth Association of Legislative Counsel 1: 42–53. OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). 2014. The Governance of Regulators. OECD Best Practice Principles for Regulatory Policy. Paris: OECD Publishing. http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264209015-en. 3 Requisite Powers ABSTRACT The term “requisite power” implies that the regulator has the legal authority necessary to undertake the functions and responsibilities assigned to it. If it does not have adequate legislated powers, the regulator is unlikely to be able to achieve the objectives set in the legislation as it will be constrained in its ability carry out key functions, for example, gathering information, ruling on key issues and enforcing compliance with its decisions. KEY TAKEAWAYS General takeaways • Regulators should have power to: –– set tariffs at reasonable levels; –– establish, modify and monitor market, technical and service quality rules and policies that are within its authority; –– address market power and design problems (if the agency has a pro-com- petitive role); –– carry out routine functions; –– investigate, adjudicate, or mediate consumer complaints; –– provide dispute resolution mechanisms; –– compel communication of information; –– monitor and enforce decisions; –– resolve problems with appropriate remedies. • Regulator powers should be assessed periodically against the objectives set out in legislation.  23 24 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS Takeaways specific to post-fragile contexts • Granting powers to an independent regulator may face resistance. Nonetheless, ensuring that a regulator has adequate powers, and making sure those are clearly communicated and understood by relevant stakeholders, is very important to prevent outside interference. • One way to ensure that a regulating body is strong enough to exercise its pow- ers without outside influence is to rapidly shore up its capacity. In the fragile context, this could entail crowding in donor support. • Having a supportive enabling environment that includes strong rule of law is also helpful in enabling the regulator to exercise its powers correctly. Although this is probably difficult to achieve in a post-fragile context, it is important that any proposal for new or modified legislation or regulation is carefully assessed to ensure that the regulator has all the legal authority required. WHAT ARE THE POWERS A REGULATOR SHOULD POSSESS? Fundamentally, the regulatory agency should have authority to make final deci- sions within its statutory domain without having to obtain prior approval from any other government agency. While powers required by a regulatory agency responsible for infrastructure will vary, depending upon the objectives and func- tions for which it is responsible, typically they should include: • setting tariffs at reasonable levels for regulated entities for the benefit of con- sumers and regulated bodies; • establishing, modifying, and monitoring any market, technical and service quality rules and policies within its legal authority necessary for carrying out its functions and consistent with the policies and principles articulated in other, related laws; • addressing market power and market design problems adequately, where the agency has a pro-competitive role; • carrying out routine administrative functions; • investigating, as well as adjudicating or mediating, consumer complaints; • providing dispute resolution facilities for regulated entities; • compelling the provision of information; • monitoring and enforcing its decisions; • resolving problems with appropriate remedies, including penalties. ASSESSING THE ADEQUACY OF A REGULATOR’S POWERS Assessing issues related to requisite powers entails identifying the objectives and functions assigned to the agency in the legislation and examining the agency’s powers in the light of these. As with mandate clarity, the process of assessing the adequacy of the regulator’s powers should begin early on in the development of the regulatory reform policy and continue throughout the legislative drafting process. Focus should be placed on ensuring that the key objectives identified, in terms of the adequacy of the regulator’s powers, are appropriately addressed in the law. Once the new regulatory arrangement has existed long enough for there to be experience to review, policymakers and governments should also conduct Requisite Powers | 25 ex-post reviews to determine the adequacy of the BOX 3.1 powers provided. Where the newly established regu- latory system functions well, this will be simple. Where  key regulatory objectives are not being A case of insufficient powers for the achieved for want of requisite powers, a more thor- Latvian Public Utilities Commission? ough review is required. Box 3.1 presents a case where wider powers for a regulator would make the system Latvian companies are required to submit proposed function more efficiently. tariffs for municipal waste disposal in landfills to the Where assessments of the powers of existing regu- Latvian Public Utilities Commission (PUC), which lators are being conducted, these should include full approves or rejects them after performing an analysis consultation with relevant officials in the regulatory and assessment of costs and profits. The PUC does not agency concerned and a careful scrutiny of legal cases have amendment powers regarding tariff proposals, involving the agency and the use of its powers, ini- although it can propose a tariff review. A recent OECD tially guided by the type of questions listed in box 3.2. review highlighted the resulting “back and forth” between the regulator and the operators and noted that it could be simplified and shortened if the regulator REQUISITE POWERS IN THE had the power to amend tariff applications. POST-FRAGILE CONTEXT Source: OECD 2016, 57. In the fragile or immediate post-fragile context, where governments have gone through a period of conflict and their authority is uncertain, a proposed decision to grant substantial powers to an independent regulatory agency is often met with resistance. This may come BOX 3.2 from ministers, who are often r ­ eluctant to give up any significant authority, or departments, who are reluc- A checklist for reviewing the adequacy tant to lose control of activities to a new agency, espe- of regulators’ powers cially where this means the loss of rewarding jobs and promotion possibilities. To check whether a review is needed of the powers However, ensuring the adequacy of these powers is exercised by a regulator and determine the likely scope particularly important in the post-fragile context, as of such a review, several preliminary questions need to governments will often have strong incentives to make be asked, including: decisions that would be contrary to those which  a 1. What sources of information indicate a lack of robust, independent regulator is required to take. For adequate powers and how reliable are those example, it was noted in the Latvian example above sources? that an independent regulator should have the power to 2. What are the issues identified by the available set prices when the market is not yet fully competitive. sources of reliable information? How significant Yet, price-setting is a particularly sensitive function in are they, particularly in terms of the potential to post-fragile contexts, where many customers may have constrain business investment and/or efficient limited ability to pay cost-­reflective tariffs. In such situ- market operation? ations, supervising m ­ inistries and governments are 3. How can the issue(s) identified be resolved? What often reluctant to accept new tariffs or increase existing are the views of key stakeholders, especially those ones. For example, in both Kosovo and Madagascar, who have been affected by the issues. successive governments have used their influence to 4. What changes are needed to resolve the issue? prevent or reduce planned tariff hikes. Is change needed to the law establishing the Thus, it is particularly important that the powers regulator? Are changes to other laws required? of the regulatory agency in this area are very clear and Are broader changes affecting the machinery of can, as far as possible, be exercised without political government, or changes to market rules likely to interference. One way to help achieve this is by rap- be required? idly shoring up the capacity of public-sector entities and regulatory agencies in the immediate aftermath 26 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS of a conflict. Where the government desires to protect vulnerable groups from the price increases needed to achieve cost-reflective tariffs, explicit subsidy arrangements should be put in place, rather than artificially limiting the ability of the regulator to set the right prices. A further issue in the post-fragile context is that the market is frequently characterized by a dominant, state-owned enterprise reluctant to defer to the authority of an agency. It is vital that the latter’s powers are sufficiently clear and substantial to enable it to compel compliance, since ensuring appropriate behav- ior by the dominant entity is fundamental to enabling the development of more competitive markets over time. This can be particularly important in terms of the entry of new competitors into downstream markets (e.g., in the telecoms sector), where dominant incumbents may seek to prevent network access by resellers. Building new or refining existing regulatory systems in the aftermath of a conflict with wide national consensus can help ensure that other parts of government and regulated entities know, understand and agree to the powers of the regulator. Finally, it is important to note that having adequate powers is a necessary, but not sufficient, condition for regulatory effectiveness. If the rule of law is limited, as is often the case in a post-fragile context, then ensuring that the regulator has the necessary powers might not, in itself, be sufficient to result in high levels of compliance with its decisions. In other words, the effective presence of rule of law is a key factor in enabling powers to be exercised appropriately. Hence, it is important that any proposal for new or modified legislation or regulation be carefully assessed to ensure that the regulator has the full legal authority or “competence” necessary to undertake the desired functions and responsibilities. As noted in box 3.1, failure to provide an agency with requisite powers can result in delays in decision-making, increased costs and loss of credibility. REFERENCE OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). 2016. Driving Performance at Latvia’s Public Utilities Commission. The Governance of Regulators. Paris: OECD Publishing. http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264257962-en. 4 Independence ABSTRACT An independent regulator should be able to make decisions within the scope of its authority without interference from the government or individual ministers. KEY TAKEAWAYS General takeaways • Regulators can exist in three broad organizational contexts: 1. as part of the ministry 2. at arm’s length from the ministry 3. as an independent body, established by law. • For infrastructure regulation, it is important for regulatory decision-making to be independent of political processes. An independent regulator should be established. • A regulator’s independence should be guaranteed in legislation: specifically, legislation should grant a regulating body powers to make decisions on its own. • Where ministries or governments can “direct” regulators, those directions must be clearly limited, policy-oriented and subject to transparency and accountability. • While it is important for a regulator to achieve independence, it must also be held accountable for the independent decisions it makes. Takeaways specific for post-fragile contexts • While aiming for an entirely independent structure is recommended, in frag- ile contexts achieving an arm’s-length arrangement is a good interim solution. • It is common in fragile environments for governments to want to change the regulatory structure, if/when a regulator is perceived as not meeting expec- tations. Yet such rapid policy changes can impede a regulator’s independence.  27 28 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS Concerns regarding a regulator’s performance should be addressed through careful analysis and the subsequent implementation of targeted reforms focused on specific, identified problem areas (see Part C, Implementing Reforms to Regulatory Systems and Governance, for details). • Transparency mechanisms (e.g., annual reports, making decisions public, as detailed in chapter 10) can help counter outside interference, quite common in fragile contexts, and preserve regulator independence. • Regulatory capture, whereby the regulator is beholden to powerful stake- holder groups, is a risk in fragile contexts. Favoring a multisectoral regulatory model, which can enable the regulator to scale up to sufficient size more quickly, thus serving as a stronger counterweight to outside pressure, can help mitigate this risk. Ensuring a strong regulatory governance system with transparency, accountability, and probity rules as well as a strong perfor- mance evaluation system is also important. INTRODUCTION Infrastructure regulators generally require a substantial degree of independence to perform their functions effectively, though the degree of freedom that is appropriate may vary with circumstances and time. Achieving independence requires that a regulator can make decisions free of political interference by government or regulated entities. This chapter aims to examine the value of ­ independence, how it can be gained and maintained, and its relationship to other issues. A regulator generally exists in one of three forms: 1. as an integral part of a ministry; 2. as an arm’s-length body, which is formally a part of a ministry but has a degree of independence resulting from administrative and/or financial arrange- ments; or 3. as an independent body, usually established by law. The choice as to which form is most appropriate in a particular regulatory context depends on the relative importance attached to operational indepen- dence on the one hand, and to accountability and responsiveness to government, on the other. Regulatory decision-making that is independent of the political process is likely to be appropriate where: • It is considered important that the regulator should be seen as independent so that the public is confident its decisions are objective and impartial. • It is important for government and non-government entities (SOEs, private businesses), to be regulated under the same framework to achieve “competi- tive neutrality”—that is, equal treatment of government and non-governmen- tal entities. • Regulatory decisions can substantially affect particular interests in a positive or negative fashion, making impartiality important. These factors will almost invariably be present in infrastructure regulation. The first—that is, the need for the regulator to be seen as independent—is likely to be of particularly importance with states in, or emerging from, a fragile or Independence | 29 conflict-affected situation since such contexts are typically characterized by low levels of trust in government. That being the case, there should be a strong presumption in favor of estab- lishing an independent regulator or regulators. However, this might not be prac- tical in a fragile context, where there is an acute shortage of qualified and experienced staff. Thus, those leading the reform process could consider interim alternatives: • Start with an arm’s-length arrangement. It may be preferable to establish a regulator within a ministry as an arm’s-length body. When choosing this option, it is essential not only to ensure that administrative and financial arrangements maximize the regulator’s independence but also to make clear to the public that this is a temporary arrangement. An explicit commitment to establish a fully independent regulator within a set period can help to increase confidence in the government, particularly if the commitment is written into in legislation. • Work through an existing independent regulator. Where an independent regulator already exists with responsibilities in another sector of the econ- omy, expanding its remit to include a newly reformed sector can leverage existing expertise and experience and may help establish independent regu- lation in the short term. Empirical evidence shows that expanding the scope of an existing regulator is a common strategy in many countries (Jordana and Levi-Faur 2010), while multisectoral regulators are relatively common in the specific context of post-FSC countries. In Madagascar, for example, both electricity and water services are the responsibility of one regulatory agency, while in Georgia, both electricity and gas fall under one agency. HOW IS INDEPENDENCE ESTABLISHED AND MAINTAINED? While regulators cannot and should not be completely independent of govern- ment, an “independent” regulator must be able to make decisions without need- ing prior approval from ministers, other agencies, government officials or non-governmental actors and stakeholders. Such arrangements are necessary (but not sufficient) to ensure that the regulator is insulated from political pressure, thus favoring consistent decision-making in line with the regulator’s ­ objectives and priorities. Regulators’ ability to make autonomous decisions should be clearly limited to the specific areas of authority granted to them by government in legislation (these areas of authority or requisite powers are addressed in chapter 3). Moreover, they must remain subject to broad government policy. This may mean that there may be provisions enabling the minister or government to give ­direction to the regulator in certain circumstances. However, where ministers or government have such power, it must be: • Clearly limited. Legislation should spell out specific circumstances in which direction can be given, the kind of direction allowed, and the extent of the power to direct. • Policy-oriented. Power to give directions concerning regulatory decisions should be set out in broad terms, rather than in specific terms that would enable the minister to influence decision-making only in certain cases. 30 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS • Subject to transparency and accountability requirements. Directions given to the regulator by a minister or government should be published at the time and as part of the regulator’s annual report. The most effective means of establishing independence in decision-making is to set out in legislation the powers of the regulator, as well as the powers of the minister or government vis-à-vis the regulator. Since these matters are funda- mental to the operation of the regulator, such provisions should be contained in primary legislation—that is, Acts of Parliament/Congress, rather than in decrees or subordinate regulations. INDEPENDENCE VERSUS ACCOUNTABILITY Independence and accountability must be finely balanced. The greater the inde- pendent regulator’s room for action, the more substantial the accountability mechanisms should be. Key mechanisms of this kind include: • the requirement to give reasons for major decisions; • provision for an independent process of appeal against the regulator’s decisions; • the requirement to publish annual reports containing enough information to judge how the regulator is exercising its functions; • provisions for regular assessments of the regulator’s performance by an inde- pendent assessor or body. Chapter 10 addresses accountability issues in detail and chapter 11 examines performance evaluation. In addition to these specific accountability tools, it must be ensured that the key regulatory principles, practices and procedures to be followed by the regula- tor are identified and specified in sufficient detail in legislation. This issue is discussed further in chapter 7, which deals with specific ways of ensuring the regulator’s integrity. It may also arise during the process of corruption proofing. INDEPENDENCE AND OTHER GOVERNANCE PRINCIPLES In addition to being balanced by appropriate mechanisms, giving a regulator independent status involves addressing other key governance issues. Without adequate governance arrangements, for instance, there is a significant risk that giving the regulator a free hand could lead to undesirable outcomes. It is essential that effective arrangements are in place in relation to: • funding • the decision-making and governing body • integrity • predictability • performance evaluation. Independence | 31 The links between independence and these other governance principles are addressed in chapter 5 (Decision-Making and Governing Body), chapter 6 (Funding Regulatory Agencies), chapter 7 (Integrity), chapter 8 (Predictability), Performance Evaluation). and chapter 11 (­ INDEPENDENCE ISSUES IN THE POST-FRAGILE CONTEXT Policy stability Policy stability is an important factor in developing and safeguarding effective independence in all contexts, but particularly for regulatory agencies in the frag- ile context. Where the performance of recently established regulators fails to meet expectations, there is often a tendency for governments to respond by mak- ing major changes to the regulatory structure, including abolishing and replac- ing existing agencies. However, such major policy realignments tend to come at substantial cost, including that of hindering the development of a robust, inde- pendent culture within the regulator. Such a culture, bolstered by a clear view of the regulating agency’s role and functions and the development of a critical mass of expertise and experience, is essential in order to guarantee the body’s effective independence. This implies that concerns regarding the performance of regulators should be addressed through careful analysis of their legislative and policy environment, in terms of regulatory governance principles, and the subsequent implementation of targeted reforms that address identified problem areas. This issue of policy stability is discussed further in Part C. Transparency mechanisms Recently established regulators, particularly in post-conflict contexts, may be relatively poorly placed to push back against government attempts to under- mine their independence. These could include a government pressuring for of particular decisions, often by reducing budget allocations, especially where a minister of finance has control over the funds (e.g., in Kosovo and Madagascar). Transparency mechanisms can help counter such attempts by involving other actors in defending independent decision-making, thus providing a “distrib- uted” network of accountability safeguards. Such actors may include the press, parliament, other regulated entities, donor bodies and international organizations. However, transparency in regulatory processes, including decision-making, is essential to enable the effective involvement of these groups. Without access to relevant information they cannot determine if a government decision has been made in relation to a regulatory agency, or whether it is appropriate. Avoiding regulatory capture Ensuring that regulators are not “captured” by the regulated is a second major consideration in the maintenance of independence. Avoiding capture is particu- larly important in the post-fragile context, where trust in institutions is fragile and robust transparency and accountability mechanisms are absent. 32 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS BOX 4.1 Questions to guide a desk review to determine the appropriate institutional structure and mechanisms needed to ensure independence in a regulator in a post-fragile state Determining institutional structure for independence: Ensuring independence over time: 1. Are the powers of the regulator set out in 1. Are there transparency and accountability legislation? Are the powers of the minister in mechanisms in place to help safeguard the relation to the regulator set out in legislation? Is regulator’s independence? (e.g., are decisions this material in primary legislation? public? Can outside stakeholders like the press 2. What is the government’s commitment to track these decisions and comment on them?) independent regulation? Is it strong or weak? 2. Are there transparency, probity and accountability Similarly, what is the government’s institutional rules governing the regulator? Is the regulator’s capacity to oversee an independent regulatory performance reviewed through performance function? evaluations? At a structural level, it is generally accepted that regulators with broad man- dates spanning several industries are less likely to become captive than those which regulate a single industrial sector. This is a further element (in addition to leveraging limited expertise and experience, as noted in chapter 4, Introduction) favoring the multisectoral regulatory model. However, while this basic structural characteristic will lessen the probabil- ity of capture significantly, the prevention of capture is a multifaceted task. Various elements of the regulatory governance system should work together to address and minimize the risks of capture, including: • Transparency rules. These should require the regulator to publish informa- tion detailing the basis on which regulatory decisions have been taken, and their expected effects. • Probity rules. Employees of the regulator should be prohibited from taking up positions in the regulated industry for a set period (e.g., 2 or 3 years). • Accountability rules. The regulator should be required to include informa- tion on its performance in terms of set benchmarks in published annual reports. • Performance evaluation. Regular performance evaluations of the regulator, conducted by independent bodies with adequate resourcing and using set benchmarks, can identify major problems and assess whether capture is a contributing factor. Box 4.1 provides a list of questions that can be included in a desk review of regulators in post fragile contexts. REFERENCE Jordana, J., and D. Levi-Faur. 2010. “Exploring Trends and Variations in Agency Scope.” Competition and Regulation in Network Industries 11 (4): 342–60. 5 Decision-Making and Governing Body ABSTRACT Regulators require governance arrangements that ensure that they operate effectively, provide for high-quality decision-making, safeguard the agency’s regulatory integrity and thereby deliver the regulatory objectives of its mandate. KEY TAKEAWAYS General takeaways • When developing a regulator’s decision-making body, or board, a key choice to make is whether it will be a single-, or multi-member body. Multi-member bodies are recommended: they are known for more robust decision-making. • Two main variants of a multi-member board include the “governance board model” and the “commission model”: each have their pros and cons. • Distribution of decision-making powers between the regulator and political authority should be clearly stated in legislation. • Members appointed to a regulatory decision-making body should serve the general public interest; the appointment process should help ensure this by being explicit, public, and fully transparent to those making decisions. • When recruiting board members, the following factors should be considered: skills needed and availability of those skills on the market. • Recruitment should guarantee enough decision-makers on board to ensure actions are expedited. Appointments should also be structured (or staggered) in such a way as to guarantee continuity and renewal in the decision-making body. Takeaways specific to post-fragile contexts • In a fragile context, the “commission model” for decision-making has advantages in that it may provide greater accountability for major  33 34 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS regulatory decisions. The direct, collegial accountability for major deci- sions that the commission model embodies is likely to provide greater con- fidence that capture will be avoided. • Key considerations when structuring a decision-making body in a fragile environment include: –– Ensuring the body has relevantly qualified staff but that qualifications are not prescribed in such detail as to limit the available pool of board members. –– Documenting explicitly broader recruitment policies for board members. CHOOSING THE DECISION-MAKING MODEL Single member versus multi-member decision bodies The decision-making model adopted for an independent regulator should reflect the nature and extent of its functions and responsibilities. The basic choice is between a single-member and a multi-member governing body. Most countries have multi-member ones. This is because the multi-member structure is consid- ered more likely to take sound decisions. Key benefits of the multi-member structure include: • Collegiality and collective responsibility, making the regulator less vulnerable to capture. This helps maintain integrity. • More robust decision-making processes, yielding higher-quality decisions, due to the presence of members with a range of backgrounds and skills. This is particularly important where discrete decisions by the regulator have major implications for stakeholders. • Greater regard to principles and precedent, thereby supporting consistency and predictability in decisions due to collective decision-making. The main- tenance of “corporate memory” over time is also a factor here. • Improved ability to provide strategic guidance to the regulator CEO and staff and to support them in carrying out their functions. • Greater guarantee of continuity over time, avoiding the risk that the regulator loses strategic focus or direction following the departure of a single decision-maker. Many of these factors are likely to be important in the context of infrastruc- ture regulators, including the need to avoid capture, to ensure decisions are predictable and consistent, and that continuity in key directions is maintained over time. Governance boards versus commission boards There are two main variants of the multi-member board model, known as the governance board model and the commission board model. The main differ- ences are: • The governance board model (such as Rwanda’s, as described in box 5.1) sees responsibility for making key decisions as lying primarily with the CEO and senior officials of the regulatory agency, with the board’s main function being to determine operational policy and provide strategic direction and oversight. This includes addressing governance standards and risk management. Decision-Making and Governing Body | 35 • By contrast, the commission model (such as Georgia’s, as described in box 5.1) has the members of the governing board (or commission) taking most substantive regulatory decisions, with the agency being responsible primarily for implementation and for day-to-day management of the r ­ egulatory system. Choosing between these two models is not simple. Indeed, most regula- tory boards exhibit some ­ elements of both models. For example, while a regu- latory c­ ommission will typically seek to make the most important decisions internally (often using sub-­committees to increase effective decision-making), it will often need to delegate less fundamental decisions, or those that are time-­ critical, to the CEO or management committees. Conversely, a governance board may take on decision-making responsibility in respect of key strategic choices. In the post-fragile context, the commission model, often but not always, has several important advantages over the governance board model, in par- ticular with regards to accountability. The commission ­ model’s direct, colle- giate accountability for major decisions is likely to instill greater confidence that ­capture will be avoided and that individual decisions may be subject to undue influence. By contrast, decision-­ making by the CEO under the regula- tory board model, while subject to board oversight, may neither provide the same degree of institutional robustness nor prevent undue influence being exercised. Second, given the commission model allows mem- bers more decision-making authority, it may attract BOX 5.1 candidates with the necessary expertise and experi- ence more easily. This may be a particularly important Differing governing structure models: consideration in low-capacity environments. Georgia and Rwanda Conversely, the commission model is not without risks either. If there are only a small number of com- The 1997 Georgian Electricity Law established an missioners (as in Georgia), there may be a greater independent National Electricit y Reg ulatory risk of undue influence being exercised as there are Commission consisting of three commissioners only the three commissioners to influence. This sug- appointed by the President for 6-year terms, with gests the benefit of appointing a larger commission authority to regulate the sector. The commission (for example, Kosovo’s Law on the Energy Regulator members were to make all regulatory decisions, with provides that the Board of the Energy Regulatory staff being responsible for implementation. This Office [ERO] should have five members),1 although exemplifies the commission model. capacity constraints may make this difficult to In contrast, the 2001 Rwandan law establishing an achieve. Agency for the Regulation of Certain Utilities put in Second, the method of appointment of board place a seven-member Regulatory Board that was members, or commissioners, and their broader terms primarily responsible for oversight, strategic guidance of engagement, are of key relevance. For example, and operational policy, with regulatory decision- where commissioners are nominated and appointed making functions largely delegated to the Managing by the President or Prime Minister without any other Director (MD) and senior staff. This is an example of checks or controls, they may be as susceptible to the governance board model. (Note, however, that undue influence as a CEO. Recognizing this issue, the President, not the Regulatory Board had the power some legislation provides for board members to be to appoint the MD, reducing the Board’s authority in appointed by parliament, as in the case of Kosovo’s relation to the President and placing the MD in a ERO, while others specify that appointments be difficult position if the views of the President and the made by a minister or president but confirmed by Regulatory Board differed.) parliament. 36 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS TABLE 5.1  Regulatory commission versus governance board model—key characteristics COMMISSION MODEL GOVERNANCE BOARD MODEL Accountability Commission collectively Indirect accountability, with CEO for Regulatory accountable to minister and/or accountable to board in the first Decisions parliament instance, then to the minister/ parliament Ability to Attract Greater possibility of recruiting Potentially more difficult to Quality Staff commissioners due to more attract board members due to substantial roles/responsibilities limited roles Key Risks Small commission size or poor Lesser access to a wide range of appointment provisions may high-level expertise to underpin compromise independence quality decision-making The model initially adopted in Georgia for its National Energy and Water Supply Regulatory Commission (GNEWSRC) combined appointment of com- missioners by the president with a provision in the law that the state would assist commissioners to gain further employment once their terms were complete. This latter provision made commissioners susceptible to undue government influence for fear of losing the assistance of the state on expiry of their terms. Recognition of these issues led to subsequent changes that severely curtailed the Georgian President’s power to nominate and appoint commissioners and increased the number of commissioners to five. Key characteristics of commis- governance board models are summarized in table 5.1. sion versus ­ ALLOCATION OF DECISION-MAKING POWERS Decision-making powers must be allocated carefully between the responsible political authority, the regulator’s governing body and the CEO. The responsi- ble political authority is typically an individual minister but may also be the cabinet or parliament. In allocating powers, the following should be considered: • broad policy frameworks; • key decisions under the enabling legislation; • criteria for deciding more routine regulatory matters; and • the implementation of higher-level decisions. The distribution of powers between the political authority and the regulator should be clearly and unambiguously specified in legislation and the powers pro- vided to the regulator should be consistent with the functions and responsibili- ties given to the agency—which should also be identified clearly in law, as discussed in chapter 3. Specifying powers in legislation may be supplemented by formal correspon- dence between the two parties that explores the distribution of power in more detail and contributes to the development of a clear shared understanding of respective roles. One option is to develop a formal “framework agreement” between the minister and the agency to clarify key issues such as the corporate identity of the regulator and the extent to which it is bound by general govern- ment policies. Importantly, such materials should be made publicly available in the interests of transparency and accountability. Decision-Making and Governing Body | 37 Where the regulator has a multi-member governing body (i.e., a governance board or a commission), the CEO should be accountable solely to this body, not to the supervising ministry. Hence, the CEO should be appointed by (or on the recommendation of ) the governing body, helping to maintain both the account- ability of the CEO and the independence of the regulator. MEMBERSHIP OF THE GOVERNING BODY The issue of accountability is also important in determining the membership of the governing body. It should be clearly established that members are appointed to serve the general interest. This requires independent, impartial decision-making, which in turn requires that members of the governing body are insulated from inappropriate pressure from ministers, industry, and other stakeholders. This principle has important implications for the appointment process. Using appointment mechanisms in which members are nominated by specific stake- holders is obviously problematic –appointees risk seeing themselves as repre- senting the interests of the stakeholders that nominated them, rather than that of the broader community. This risk can be reduced if the legislation governing appointments clearly specifies that any appointees nominated by stakeholder groups are to serve as members of a collegiate governing body and not as representatives of the stake- holders who nominated them. However, nominations by stakeholders will still entail risks, to the extent that nominees feel themselves to be indebted to the nominating body. This may be important if the renewal of their terms of office depend on the stakeholder group. But governments may favor the nomination of board or commission members by stakeholder groups to ensure that: 1. The views of these groups are adequately represented in decision-making. 2. Their specific expertise and knowledge is available to the regulator. Both of these are potentially important considerations, but they can be addressed in different ways. One preferred approach is to establish a formal advisory group to provide specialist inputs to the governing body. In fragile con- texts, the presence of such a group, while not a long-term solution, will also help address capacity constraints by bringing in external experts. This approach is preferable because: • It helps ensure transparency and accountability regarding the advice ­ provided to the regulator by stakeholders. • It creates a clear separation between technical advice (and representation of sectoral interests), on the one hand, and decision-making by the regulator, on the other. • It avoids any uncertainty on the part of governing body members about the nature of their role. For similar reasons, the appointment of ministerial representatives to the governing body should be avoided. Where a regulator is intended to act inde- pendently (as these principles indicate), the key concern is maintaining that independence and avoiding role conflict. Such conflicts can arise where the short-term political priorities of government—or even of the minister 38 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS ­ esponsible—differ from the long-term orientations for the sector. In such a r situation the ministerial representatives may tend to favor short-term solutions. This principle also indicates that senior staff of the regulator should not gen- erally be members of the governing body. That is because they are usually civil servants and thus accountable to the minister. At the very least, wherever senior staff of the regulator are members of the governing body, consideration should be given to according them non-voting status. It is also important that the appointment of board members be predictable, in the sense that the criteria and processes for recruitment, selection and appoint- ment be: • explicit • public • fully and properly observed by those making the decisions. This will help ensure that their decisions as to who will be appointed as board members comes as no surprise to interested parties and the public. There is always a degree of subjectivity involved in making such decisions, but a properly constituted process can reduce it to a minimum and produce more acceptable decisions. RECRUITMENT AND REAPPOINTMENT As indicated on page 31 a multi-member governing body can help ensure appoint- ment of members with a range of skills and experience, thus supporting robust, high-quality decision-making. In weighing the appropriate size of the governing body, the following considerations should be taken into account and balanced against each other as necessary: • Skills Needed. The governing body should be large enough to enable a suffi- cient breadth of skills and experience to be represented on it. • Availability of qualified staff on the market. Capacity constraints should be recognized: the governing body should not be so large as to raise practical problems in filling the required positions. • Decision expediency. The governing body should be large enough to ensure that a quorum of members to take significant decisions can be maintained, even if some members are absent from time to time. In Georgia, for example, only three commissioners were initially appointed to the Georgian National Energy and Water Supply Regulatory Commission. But it became extremely difficult for proceedings to be expedited if only two members attended a meeting and there was a disagreement between them. At the same time the body should not be so larger as to be unwieldy. TERM OF APPOINTMENTS AND TERM LIMITS Appointments should be structured to ensure both continuity and renewal of the governing body. This implies that appointments should be for fixed terms, and “staggered” so that the governing body board typically includes a mix of recent appointees and members with longer experience. One way of achieving this is to Decision-Making and Governing Body | 39 replace any members who resign with appointees who serve a full term, rather than simply filling the departing member’s remaining term. Appointees should have security of tenure, as this is important in safeguard- ing their independence. Consequently, it should only be possible to dismiss members in limited and very specific cases such as unresolved conflicts of interest, significant criminal behavior, failure to carry out their functions, and corruption. Termination should ideally only be based on findings from an inde- pendent investigative body. However, the requirement for a minister or the cabinet to explicitly state the grounds of termination, together with the right of appeal, also provides significant protection against political interference in the governing body. Consistent with the need to ensure both continuity and renewal, there should be a clear limit on the number of terms members of the governing body can serve. However, the importance of continuity—that is, of the regulatory agency at all times having a quorum on its decision-making body—makes it desirable that board members remain in their positions until replacements are appointed. Such a provision can guard against decision-making bodies being blocked due to political disputes over new appointments (as happened in Kosovo). Regulated entities must have confidence in the competence and impartial- ity of the regulator’s governing body. To help ensure this, the criteria for appointing members of the governing body and the policy and processes to be followed in selecting and appointing members should be published and read- ily available, as well as being consistent with any wider rules or policies on appointments to public bodies. The appointment policy should address all of the following issues: • Who is responsible for managing the appointment process; • What are the key elements of the appointment process; • Who makes the appointments; • How is the Chair nominated and appointed; • What is the role of the Minister, the Parliament and the Cabinet (if any); and • How are conflicts of interest to be addressed. Governing body appointment policies should include all relevant details. SECTOR-SPECIFIC VERSUS MULTISECTORAL REGULATORS All governments reforming the regulation of infrastructure (and, as part of this process, establishing independent regulators) must decide whether to set up separate regulators for each sector or whether to establish one or more multisec- toral regulators instead. Each of these options has trade-offs and the research literature yields no clear, generally applicable conclusion as to which model is preferable. Table 5.2 outlines some of the benefits of each. As noted in chapter 4, some empirical research shows that there is a clear tendency to progressively broaden the remit of established regulators, suggest- ing that practical experience leads governments to favor leveraging the skills and reputations of established regulators by giving them responsibility for new sec- tors (Albon and Decker 2015; Jordana and Levi-Faur 2010). Box 5.2 summarizes 40 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS TABLE 5.2  Benefits of multisector versus single-sector regulators BENEFITS MULTISECTOR REGULATOR SINGLE-SECTOR REGULATOR Resource efficiency • Potential to exploit economies of scale by establishing • May help ensure appropriate allocation of a small number of larger regulatory institutions resources between sectors, avoiding that a multisectoral regulator will focus too closely on one sector while neglecting others Regulatory expertise • Better use of existing regulatory expertise— • Can foster greater build-up of sector expertise experienced regulators can apply skills to newly over time reformed sectors Approach • Consistency across related sectors reducing likelihood • Legislation likely more appropriately tailored of regulatory distortions to the requirements and circumstances of individual sectors • More strategic, able to take account of circumstances and dynamics in several sectors Accountability • Less potential for regulatory capture because likely to • Higher level of accountability on the regulator achieve critical mass more quickly, enabling a more since it is responsible for the performance of robust, independent culture, and because it does not one sector only interact exclusively with one “client” sector how India arrived at the decision to favor a multisector regulator approach. In practice, multisectoral regulators are often the long-term result of this dynamic, rather than a deliberate choice. Choosing the regulatory model in post-fragile contexts Several factors appear to favor the adoption of multisectoral regulators in post-fragile societies. A key consideration relates to the often pressing limits on available resources and expertise. Independent regulators in post-fragile coun- tries are often extremely few and face uncertain budgetary environments. For example, Madagascar’s ERO has around 25 staff in total, including both profes- sional and support employees. Moreover, while it notionally receives direct payments from regulated entities totaling 1.2 percent of turnover to fund its ­ activities, the ongoing financial difficulties of the incumbent electricity provider mean that much of this notional revenue is not received in practice. In these circumstances, a multisectoral regulator is significantly more likely to reach a critical size enabling it to operate effectively and to benefit from econ- omies of scale. The ability to leverage the skills of experienced regulators by applying them to newly reformed sectors is also likely to be important in the post-fragile context and, in particular, in relatively small countries. This latter point was highlighted in a review of the first decade of operation of Jamaica’s multisectoral infrastructure regulator: The operation of the multisector model is not without its drawbacks but the experiences of the OUR2 over the last decade or so, lend credence to the claim that it offers effective pragmatic solutions for small countries with limited financial resources, small technical skill pool and the risk of political interven- tion. Employing this model, Jamaica has been able to oversee full liberalization of its telecommunication sector, privatization of its electricity sector with some scope for fostering competition on the generation side and undertake greater scrutiny of its still state dominated water sector. At the same time, time it is demonstrable that the model delivers in terms of rationalizing costs and sharing limited resources. (Hewitt 2009) Moreover, if the regulator relies on a wider range of revenue sources, uncer- tainty as to budgetary position may be minimized. In addition, concerns about regulatory capture is necessarily heightened in environments in which Decision-Making and Governing Body | 41 BOX 5.2 View of the Indian Government The Government of India reviewed international States should be encouraged to consider this approach approaches to the regulation of infrastructure indus- and the scope of their existing electricity regulators tries and assessed them in the light of India’s context could be extended to other sectors. and objectives, with the Committee for Infrastructure The document also highlighted the increasing publishing the resulting guidance document, importance of regulators being subject to consistent, Approaches to the Regulation of Infrastructure, in good governance arrangements and nominated in full September 2008 (Government of India 2008). The independence and autonomy. Directions to regulators, paper concluded that a general preference in favor of their functions, accountability, transparency, competi- multisectoral regulators should be adopted, stating: tion and appeals mechanisms are key mattes to be Drawing from international experience from several addressed by the governance framework: countries, India should consider opting for multisectoral Given the growing importance of regulation in sev- regulators such as for (a) communications; (b) electric- eral critical sectors of the economy, the governance ity, fuels and gas, and (c) transport. This would elimi- relating to regulatory institutions has assumed an nate proliferation of regulatory commissions, help build important role. It is, therefore, necessary to specify an capacity and expertise, promote consistency of approach agreed philosophy and overarching principles that and save on costs. The central government would take a would govern regulatory commissions across sectors. decision on a case-by-case basis about the institutional Consistent with an overarching regulatory framework location of the multisectoral regulator. In the case of for the orderly development of infrastructure services, States, a single regulatory commission for all infrastruc- the regulators could continue to function under sector-­ ture sectors may be more productive and cost-effective specific statutes that are administered by the respective as compared to sectoral regulators for each sector. Ministries. Source: Government of India 2008. institutions, including government bodies, are relatively weak and concerns about corruption widespread. Thus, the tendency for the multisectoral model to provide greater resistance to regulatory capture, noted above, is likely to be a particularly important factor. All this suggest that the merits of adopting a multisectoral model should be weighed carefully in post-fragile contexts and, if a sector-specific model is pre- ferred, that care should be taken to design governance and other supporting arrangements that minimize the issues identified above. DECISION-MAKING BODIES IN POST-FRAGILE CONTEXTS A major concern in post-fragile contexts is the tendency for high-level political appointments to be made in regulatory bodies. This undermines ­ independence and is likely to yield appointees with lesser professional skills in some circumstances, thus compromising decision-making at the technical level. 42 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS To safeguard against this risk, key elements of the appointment process should be made explicit and public, so that wide scrutiny of these elements can exert pressure toward the maintenance of its integrity: • Relevant qualifications and other requirements should be established. However, these should avoid undue prescriptiveness, which can exclude high-quality candidates and give rise to legal challenges. It is not, for example, necessary that all board members of a regulatory agency responsible for electricity have substantial qualifications or experience in working in the ­ electricity sector (although some should), so long as they have other qualifi- cations and substantial business experience. • Broader recruitment policies and processes should be documented explicitly. This should include key details such as who is responsible for managing the process, who makes appointments (or who recommends can- didates and who has final decision-making authority), who nominates or appoints the Chair and how conflicts of interest are to be addressed. An appointment process which involves appointments formally made by the executive branch but requiring ratification or approval by the legislature can improve the accountability of the process. These policies and processes should, as far as possible, be consistent with generally applicable, public- sector appointment requirements. However, where broader public-sector reforms have not been undertaken, higher standards may need to be developed and adopted in key regulatory bodies. A further issue related to the tendency for political appointments to be of particular concern in post-fragile countries is ensuring continuity in the opera- tions of the governing body. Where rival groups seek to have their own candi- dates appointed to key positions, the outcome can often be a failure to make such appointments. This can be of particular concern where the commission model has been adopted, since the regulator may be unable to take key decisions for extended periods due to the lack of a quorum. This issue, and potential means of addressing it, are discussed further on page 34. Box 5.3 provides a set of ques- tions that can guide a desk review of a regulator’s decision-making body. BOX 5.3 Questions for guiding a desk review of a regulator’s decision-making body With regards to staffing of the governing board: With regards to decision-making continuity: 1. How many sectors are covered by the regulator? 1. Does the regulator’s founding legislation describe 2. What skill sets are needed to make regulatory how the governing board will be appointed? Does decisions? Are these skills detailed in the regula- such a process ensure continuity in decision-making tory agency’s founding legislation? ability—that is, a quorum to take decisions? 3. Are the appropriate skills available on the local 2. Are there clearly defined term limits for board market? members? 4. Is there sufficient budget to pay the salaries needed to attract well-qualified staff Decision-Making and Governing Body | 43 NOTES 1. See Article 5. https://mzhe-ks.net/repository/docs/law_no._05_l-084_on_the_energy​ _regulator_(1)eng.pdf. 2. Office of Utilities Regulation. REFERENCES Albon, R., and C. Decker. 2015. “International Insights for the Better Economic Regulation of Infrastructure.” Australian Competition and Consumer Commission (ACCC)/Australian Energy Regulator (AER) Working Paper Series, Working Paper 10. https://www.accc.gov​ .au/system/files/International%20Insights%20for%20the%20Better%20Economic%20 Regulation%20of%20Infrastructure.pdf. Government of India. 2008. Approach to the Regulation of Infrastructure. New Delhi: Secretariat for the Committee on Infrastructure, Planning Commission, Government of India. http:// planningcommission.gov.in/sectors/ppp_report/reports_guidelines/Approach%20to%20 Regulation%20of%20Infrastructure.pdf. Hewitt, A. E. 2009. “Country Report: Jamaica.” Paper presented to the UNCTAD (United Nations Conference on Trade and Development) Multi-Year Expert Meeting on Services, Development and Trade: The Regulatory and Institutional Dimension, Geneva, 17–19 March 2009. http:// unctad.org/sections/wcmu/docs​/c1mem3p33​_en.pdf. Jordana, J., and D. Levi-Faur. 2010. “Exploring Trends and Variations in Agency Scope.” Competition and Regulation in Network Industries 11 (4): 342–60. 6 Funding Regulatory Agencies ABSTRACT The two key considerations regarding the funding of regulators are adequacy and incentives. The regulator must have access to sufficient resources to allow it to carry out its assigned functions effectively, while funding must be supplied in ways that do not risk distorting the regulator’s decisions. KEY TAKEAWAYS General takeaways • Giving regulators access to appropriate levels and sources of funding sup- ports good regulatory decisions by strengthening regulators’ independence • Ways to ensure proper funding for regulators include: 1. imposing direct regulatory fees on industry participants (the economi- cally efficient option); 2. allocating funds to the regulator as part of the budget process; 3. a combination of the two. • A regulator’s funding levels should be commensurate with its responsibilities and be subject to oversight. • The risks of a regulator receiving too little or too much funding should be managed through effective legislation and transparent processes. Takeaways specific to post-fragile contexts • In a resource-constrained post-fragile environment, ensuring funding for a regulator is challenging as there will always be other pressing areas in need of financing. Using a multisector regulator can help by promoting economies of scale. • Allocating funds as part of the budget process is typically adopted in the initial phases of setting up a regulator and would make sense in a post-fragile context.  45 46 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS But such an approach should be phased out over time, given that arrangements of this kind are more susceptible to political interference. • To counter pressure to divert funds earmarked for the regulator to other gov- ernment purposes: –– Funding arrangements can be detailed in legislation. –– Reserve accounts can be set up to absorb unexpected expenses. –– Legislative rules can be set, for example, if regulatory expenses fall below level x, then reduce levies charged on industry participants. –– Be transparent about funding uses. INTRODUCTION The infrastructure sector requires large capital investments, making an impar- tial, competent regulator that produces predictable and appropriate regulatory decisions a key element for investors. This, in turn, requires that regulators have sufficient operating independence to ensure their decisions are not affected by political considerations, as discussed in chapter 4. It is therefore extremely important that the regulatory agency has sufficient funds to provide for a well-administered regulatory system. It is also essential that regulators have adequate access to, and control over, these funds, so that control of their supply cannot be used by other parts of government to influence regulatory decisions, as has happened, for example, in both Madagascar and Kosovo. Access to appropriate levels and sources of funding supports good regulatory decisions by underpinning the independence of the regulator and thus support- ing its ability to make impartial and high-quality decisions. In addition, it is important that the agency’s funding arrangements—that is, the sources, manage- ment and uses of its funds—be fully transparent. This will enhance confidence that the regulator is fair, efficient and effective. Where, for example, an agency’s budgeted funds are held in an account controlled by a ministry of finance, espe- cially where it is not subject to detailed and effective parliamentary scrutiny, there is the potential for the agency to be “starved” of funds and unable to discharge its duties in an appropriate and efficient fashion. ­ FUNDING METHODS The fundamental choice in the funding of infrastructure regulators is between funding via: • the imposition of direct regulatory fees on industry participants; • the budget process; • some combination of the two. There may also sometimes be a case for charging additional fees for specific services. The merits of each of these sources are discussed below. Imposing regulatory costs on the regulated enterprises The most common means of funding industry regulation is to impose fees on the regulated industry. This “internalizes” regulatory costs within the regulated sec- tor, effectively ensuring that the producers’ and consumers’ decisions reflect the full cost of producing industry outputs—including the cost of regulation. Such an Funding Regulatory Agencies | 47 approach is economically efficient because of this internalization of regulatory costs to the industry. It is also equitable, because the industry and its consumers pay the costs of its regulation, rather than this being subsidized by taxpayers through the budget process. These characteristics imply that there should be a presumption in favor of funding via industry fees and it is our preferred option. However, this model effectively assumes that there is: • a tradition or culture of full payment for the provision of electricity or other forms of energy by consumers; • a continuing capacity to pay; and • that the enterprises have efficient financial systems, ensuring high levels of payment. Where these conditions are met, industry fees constitute a reliable and rela- tively easy to administer means of funding. It can also easily be made transpar- ent, assuming that the regulated entities agree (which should always be the case), or that the government requires them to do so. It is also consistent with the aim of regulatory independence as it frees, at least in theory, the regulator from dependence on the government as a source of funds. However, some states in situations of fragility do not have a culture of pay- ment for infrastructure services, with state agencies, for example, frequently failing to pay electricity charges (e.g., several of the ex-Soviet states in the early years after independence, such as Georgia [World Bank 2008]). Similarly, as is often the case in ­fragile states, where the economy is in a state of rapid decline, low-income consumers lack the capacity to pay commercial rates without state subsidies. Also, state-owned utility enterprises, often dominant in, for example, the electricity sector, frequently lack efficient payment and collection systems. The result is increasing indebtedness, making them heavily dependent upon state subsidies and reducing their independence from government. In such situ- ations, imposing the cost of regulation on the regulated enterprises, at least in the short term, may simply increase the size of the government subsidies via the budget—as happened in the electricity sector in Madagascar, limiting the gov- ernment’s ability to fund other projects. Even in these challenging circumstances, funding via regulatory fees sends a signal to the market that the costs of regulation form part of the cost-base of the industry and that government, ideally, will increasingly use regulatory fees as the major source of funding, as the financial performance of regulated entities improves. Where regulatory fees are adopted to fund regulatory costs, they should be applied consistently to all industry participants, whether publicly or privately owned. While various factors can be significant, the cost of regulating an entity is likely to be broadly proportionate to the size of its operations. Thus, fees are typically set on a volumetric basis (e.g., kWhs for electricity). This process is in theory relatively simple, although the actual collection of revenues can be a seri- ous issue, as noted above. In addition, in post-fragile countries where the rule of law is exercised in only a limited fashion, it can be difficult to enforce payment from large, often government-owned, enterprises. In Zambia, for example, ZESCO, the state-owned, vertically integrated generation and transmission enterprise, refused for several years to pay its assessment to the Energy Regulation Board (ERB, established in 1995), for a variety of financial and polit- ical reasons (Brown 2008, 15). 48 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS The costs of regulation can also be applied on the basis of “cost causation,” where regulatory costs are imposed on those who bring them about, sending very clear price signals to regulated entities. However, the major problems here are that: • the transaction and accounting costs are high relative to alternative models, with each enterprise needing to possess sophisticated financial systems and highly qualified staff to operate them, a situation not usually found in fragile states; and • each enterprise has to be separately billed, in full detail. Moreover, it is likely to result in disputes about the costs they are being asked to pay, given that they are sent detailed invoices. All this means that this approach is typically restricted to specific, high-cost regulatory activities that are usually undertaken only infrequently—such as assessing applications for the grant or renewal of licenses. Thus, in practice, these “cost-based fees” are usually combined with a volume-based levy, which covers a wider range of regulatory costs that cannot easily be measured for indi- vidual regulated entities. In a post-fragile context, where sophisticated accounting systems and highly qualified staff are in short supply, funding on the basis of cost causation is not likely to be successful and volumetric approaches generally provide a more fea- sible option. Funding by an appropriation from general tax revenues in the budget process The second most common way of funding the cost of regulation is by an appro- priation from general tax revenues in the normal budget process. This approach is very likely to be adopted in an initial, regulatory reform period, when there is likely to be limited opportunity to levy fees on regulated entities. However, this course of funding raises a number of issues in terms of the incentives to the reg- ulator and its ability to carry out its functions credibly and impartially: • It enables political interference, as governments may seek to change or restrict the funding according to the regulator’s behavior, as noted above. • Even where there is no political interference in the budget process per se, broader fiscal concerns mean that budget funding can result in less ­reliable revenue flows for the agency. Recently created regulators may be particularly vulnerable to government cost-cutting due to the lack of well-established networks and lobbying avenues. Diminished revenue restricts them in operating effectively and fully discharge their statutory duties. • While a government and parliament can agree to an appropriation for an agency, there is usually a set of rules that govern when and how the agency can actually receive and use the funds. One means of addressing many of the above concerns is to establish multi- year funding arrangements—for example, legislating that the agency’s budget is established for a three-year period—thus protecting agencies from budget cuts motivated by, for example, short-term political reactions to unpopular decisions such as raising tariffs (Kelley and Tenenbaum 2004). Funding Regulatory Agencies | 49 Funding by fee for service The third and least-common general method is to charge specific fees for the ser- vices provided. This is invariably a supplementary funding source, used to ensure cost recovery for individual, regulated entities as regards particularly resource-in- tensive regulatory actions. It does send accurate price signals to the market but, again, has high transaction costs and can lead to less revenue s­tability and reliabil- ity, as revenue will fluctuate in line with demand for the services provided. However, fees can be a useful mechanism for providing additional funds for agen- cies when required for specific purposes, as in Rwanda (see box 6.1). FUNDING OVERSIGHT As a public body, a regulatory agency has an obligation to be efficient, effective and accountable in using the funds entrusted to it, whatever the means and sources of funding. In turn, the government and, often, parliament, have the right to review the funding of the agency. Auditing considerations The ordinary fiscal controls, auditing policies and practices, and budgetary con- trols of the government should apply to a regulatory agency. However, where a government lacks an effective auditing capacity, as demonstrated in box 6.2, it can be better for the boards of regulatory agencies to appoint their own auditors from the private sector, subject to approval by the Government or parliament, or both. BOX 6.1 Sources of finance for the Rwanda Utilities Regulatory Agency It is common for regulatory agencies to be authorized 2. grants, donations and legacies; to use several means of financing. Article 35 of 3. fees for services rendered to each utility by the Rwandan Law No. 39/2001 OF 13/09/2001 establishing regulatory agency; an Agency for the Regulation of Certain Public Utilities, 4. loans; specifies that the new Rwanda Utilities Regulatory 5. annual fees based on a percentage of turnover from Agency can fund its expenses from a number of the activities of each public utility: that percentage sources, making it self-financing, but not profit- is set by a decree of the minister determined by the making, although the bulk of its revenue comes from President of the Republic; and annual fees levied on each utility it regulates (item 5). 6. fines imposed by the Regulatory Board. The actual mix of means selected is left to RURA’s In practice, the funds received from annual fees discretion, from the following sources: increased progressively over time, to become the 1. fees levied for the application for, and grant of, dominant source of funding. Fees levied on licenses, licenses, approvals, permits, contracts, concessions approvals, permits, contracts, concessions and and allocations to each utility operator; allocation also increased. 50 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS BOX 6.2 In a situation like Madagascar’s, the appointment of a reputable auditor from the private sector would help ensure audits are completed in a timely and Limited government audit capacity in effective manner. It may also help limit any untoward Madagascar pressure by a government auditing body too sympa- thetic to government wishes, thus providing some In Madagascar, for example, the Court of Auditors, protection against corruption. which is the supreme audit institution, suffers from a shortage of magistrates, auditors and financial resources. Although the situation is improving, the Determining funding levels consideration of annual Appropriations Bills and In general, the overall spending authority of an agency external audit reports is not systematic and falls far should be subject to government approval. This is behind schedule. The monitoring arrangements especially the case if all, or the bulk of its funds are regarding its audit recommendations are not formal- provided on a cost-recovery basis, with the conse- ized and external audit covers only a limited portion of quent danger that the agency could overestimate its the Court’s field of control. It audits only half of total needs, imposing an unreasonable burden on the enter- expenditure. As accounts and the draft Appropriations prises charged and, eventually, the consumer. Bill Report are frequently submitted late for judgment, Hence, there needs to be arm’s length oversight of the Court has several times exceeded statutory time- the process to reduce the risk of unreasonable regula- frames in fulfilling its obligations of verifying finan- tory fees being charged, within the context of the ­policy cial statements. As of June 2014, for example, draft objectives and fees guidance set by government, ideally Appropriations Bills for fiscal years (FY) 2008, 2009, in the statute establishing the agency. In Portugal, for 2010, 2011, 2012 had not been passed by the National example, initially the budget of the energy regulatory Assembly. agency, ERSE, was prepared by the agency’s Board of Directors then submitted to a Consultative Council, an Source: African Development Bank Group 2014. internal body of the agency composed of representa- tives from consumers, electricity enterprises and three ministries. The Council was empowered to reject the budget, although it never did so. There is no standard formula for determining an adequate level of funding for a regulatory agency. Adequate funding will depend upon: • Number of: –– functions and associated tasks undertaken –– enterprises regulated –– customers the enterprises serve –– licenses awarded. • frequency of tariff proceedings; • complexity of the sector the agency is responsible for; • extent to which the details of its funding sources and processes have been specified in the law or decree establishing the agency.1 Some governments, such as Georgia’s, have chosen to provide regulatory agencies with a high degree of discretion in relation to their levels of funding, while others exercise tighter controls, as can be seen in box 6.3. But whatever the means, level and sources of funding, the agency’s annual report and accounts should make clear who pays for the regulator’s operations, how much and why, including government subsidies. This helps to improve the agency’s credibility. Managing risks to regulator funds In the case of budget-sourced funding, the risk of politically motivated bud- get reductions is ever-present. Often, determining the regulator’s budget is Funding Regulatory Agencies | 51 either enshrined in law or is part of a “safeguard” process whereby the regu- lator presents a budget based on an assessment of its funding requirements for government approval. In the latter case, the fact that the regulator initi- ates the process by specifying the amount it believes necessary to perform its obligations provides some degree of safeguard against politically motivated attempts to constrain its activities. The risk of reduced funding can, however, be mitigated in two main ways: effective legislation and transparent processes. Effective legislation can help insulate against risk of funding uncertainty • by specifying that the agency be provided with a minimum level of fund- ing, for example, a dollar amount per connected customer, or per kWh sold; • by ensuring—in cases where government approves budgets proposed by the regulatory agency—that if the proposed budget has not been authorized by a specified date, then funding should be set at the level of the previous year’s budget; • by including statutes that the agency should have its own specific resources, over which only the regulator’s governing body has control. BOX 6.3 Controls on levels of funding by regulatory agencies: Georgia, Rwanda, and Latvia Governments vary in the level of control they exercise part, RURA’s funding will come from an annual regu- over the funding levels set by regulatory agencies and latory fee based on a percentage of the turnover (as the ways they calculate those levels. Examples from opposed to load forecasts in Georgia) of each regu- Georgia, Rwanda, and Latvia demonstrate this, and as lated service. But beyond saying that the fee should shown in the Latvian case, how funding is allocated to not exceed one percent of turnover the statute does the regulator can lead to conflicts of interest. not specify the actual level of the fee. Georgia. The 1999 Law of Georgia on Electricity Latvia. The regulatory fee for the bulk of the fund- and Natural Gas, for example, gave the Georgian ing for the operations of the Latvian Public Utilities National Energy and Water Supply Regulatory Commission (PUC) is set by the cabinet. This raises Commission a high degree of discretion in setting its some concern since state-owned enterprises in Latvia so-called “regulatory fee.” Article 19 of the law indicates are important actors in the sectors overseen by the only that it should be based on “the [energy] load fore- PUC. The ceiling of the regulatory fee is set in law, but casts for the following year received from licensees, the actual level is decided by the cabinet, which importers and suppliers,” without giving further details. includes several ministries that are shareholders of Rwanda. Law No. 09/2013 establishing the Rwanda the public utilities regulated by the PUC. This creates Utilities Regulatory Authority (RURA), in Article 36:3, a potential conflict of interest and can serve to bring goes a little further than Georgia, specifying that, in political pressure on the regulator. Source: OECD 2016, 21. 52 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS Transparent processes can ensure enough pressure in the system to adequately fund the regulator • Where the regulator’s funding is not enshrined in law and a regulatory agency proposes a budget for government approval (usually via the Ministry of Finance or, in some cases, parliament), a more transparent process can help create external pressure on both government and regulator. Government will need to justify any reduction in funding vis-à-vis the proposed budget and the regulator will have to explain any proposed increases. Transparency can be achieved by making both budget proposals and the government responses public. Dealing with unanticipated expenses All regulatory agencies face the prospect of carrying out activities that were unan- ticipated in the budget, including complex and difficult license applications, spe- cial, “one-off,” investigations, and major and unanticipated court actions. Sometimes funding these will be difficult or impossible within the standard bud- get allocation, yet they can be vital regulatory tasks as, for example, when the reg- ulator’s credibility requires it to start legal proceedings to enforce it decisions or to counter inappropriate conduct by regulated entities. Three key options exist for funding such activities: 1. Ad hoc requests to the portfolio minister. Where the regulator applies to the minister responsible for additional funding for a specific purpose. 2. Funding reserve. Where the legislation governing the regulator authorizes the accumulation of a funding reserve, within stated limits, either via unspent levies, monetary sanctions, or some combination of the two, to cover unantic- ipated costs. 3. Legislative power to raise loans. Where legislation authorizes the regulator to raise loans from the non-government sector in identified circumstances, with loan expenses being covered by an increase in future fees levied on its sector of competence. The first option, a funding request to the minister is the least-preferred option. In the case of major litigation, for example, if an independent regulator has to seek ministerial and government approval for funds, it runs the risk of unwanted polit- ical interference and of reducing its credibility. On the other hand, it faces the same risks if it chooses not to take or to defend a costly legal action, opening itself to accusations that it took the decision under political pressure. The second option, a funding reserve, is only feasible where funds from unspent levies, monetary sanctions or a combination of the two are likely to be sufficient to cover large, unexpected costs such as major litigation. Where a gov- ernment is not providing sufficient funds to cover a regulator’s normal activities, then building up a sufficiently large reserve is unlikely. Hence, the third option, raising loan funds is the preferred option, with the statute specifying how the agency can secure the necessary funds, authorizing it, for example, to take out loans from the non-government, financial sector. The processes of setting fee levels, gaining funding approval and controlling and reviewing finances should be clear, understandable and accessible to all stakeholders and the general public, including by parliamentary scrutiny. Such transparency can reduce the risks to the regulator’s political and administrative independence from both government and major interest-group lobbying (Kelley and Tenenbaum 2004). It can also improve the efficiency of regulatory Funding Regulatory Agencies | 53 operations by providing the information necessary to hold the regulator to account for its activities and expenditures and making any attempt to exercise undue influence more visible (Hüpkes, Quintyn, and Taylor 2006). INCENTIVE ISSUES IN RELATION TO FUNDING Imposing regulatory fees or levies can help make regulatory agencies account- able for their budget. If the government increases the fees charged to industry to fund its regulation, it should be able to demonstrate that such increases are jus- tified and necessary and that the regulator is operating efficiently. If fees are sig- nificantly higher than in comparable industries or countries, this potentially provides a signal that this is not the case. However, revenue from industry fees is typically collected by the Ministry of Finance, with the regulator being funded through a separate budget allocation. While this process of central collection of fees is a very widespread accountabil- ity mechanism within government, it has the potential to create perverse incen- tives in relation to the funding of regulators and to break the link between the size of the levies charged and the expenditures of the regulator. This both sub- stantially reduces the accountability of the regulator for its use of resources and means that the regulator does not benefit from the secure and predictable fund- ing that a regulatory fee is intended to provide. This issue is likely to be particu- larly acute in post-fragile environments, as discussed in the next section. Another common issue in relation to the funding of regulators is their lack of access to, and control over, their budgets. Control over the spending of the allo- cated budget is a major aspect of the independence enjoyed by a regulator in practice. This requires that it have a separate account, into which its budget is paid and over which it has control, subject only to the specific limits on its finan- cial powers set out in authorizing legislation. FUNDING AND FRAGILE STATES While funding is a constraint on all government actions, it is felt even more sharply in post-fragile states with very limited financial and human resources. Thus, the funding of a regulatory agency is a significant challenge in the post-­ fragile context. This issue is likely to be particularly acute in small countries unable to benefit from the economies of scale available in countries with larger populations, where the relatively fixed costs of regulation as spread over a larger base (Domah, Pollitt, and Stern 2002). As discussed in chapter 4, the use of a multisectoral regulatory model may help reduce funding pressure by using scarce resources to regulate several sectors. A significant issue identified in some post-fragile contexts is that industry levies designed to constitute a stable funding base for a sectoral regulator can instead be diverted to general government revenue. This can occur if the rele- vant legislation does not explicitly link the revenue raised via industry levies to the budget allocated to the regulator. This can mean that substantial industry levies are imposed, which are paid directly into consolidated revenue, while the budget approved for the regulator is substantially smaller—and often inad- equate to enable it to fulfill its tasks. Where governments face major problems in raising budget revenue—as is very commonly the case in post-fragile 54 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS BOX 6.4 Failure to hypothecate industry levies to fund the regulator’s operations In Kosovo, the Law on the Electricity Regulator annually in industry levies in recent years, but has had authorizes an industry levy of up to 2 percent of turn- annual budgets averaging around €1 million over the over to provide funding for the Energy Regulatory same period. Office (ERO). The actual levy is determined by the In Madagascar, the 1998 Law on Electricity pro- ERO board and is currently set a much lower rate of vides that the rate of the industry levy is determined 0.56 percent. However, the budget provided to ERO jointly by the Ministers of Finance and Energy, has historically been substantially smaller than the rather than by the Energy Regulator (ORE), while revenue derived from the levy, with the remaining the funds from the levy are also deposited into the funds used for general government purposes. While consolidated fund. This means that, while the ORE ERO currently faces substantial budget pressures, it budget is notionally subject only to the approval of has nonetheless indicated a desire to reduce the levy its Council, in practice the ORE must ask the rate from its current level, as it believes that it could be Ministry of Finance to provide funding to cover the adequately funded if it received the full proceeds of a approved budget. As in Kosovo, the practical reality levy set at a lower rate. A similar dynamic has oper- in recent years is that the budget funding received by ated in the telecoms sector, where the industry regu- ORE has been only a small part of the revenue from lator, ARKEP, has collected around €5 million industry fees. ­ ontexts—there is a clear incentive for this approach. Box 6.4 provides some c examples. One means of limiting the size of this potential issue is to include a ceiling or ceilings on the size of the regulatory fees that can be imposed in the legislation establishing the regulator and setting out its functions. This is a commonly adopted approach, with the ceiling usually specified as a percentage of industry turnover. However, as shown in table 6.1, the specific percentage ceiling set in  legislation varies widely. The ceilings identified in the table vary from 0.3 ­percent to 2.0 percent of turnover. As noted above, the scope of the responsibilities and powers of the regulator is one determinant of the size of its budgetary requirement and is therefore a factor in explaining the difference in the fee ceilings. However, it is likely that governments’ desire to use regulatory fees as a source of general revenue may be another. This appears be a significant factor in Madagascar, for example, where the fee ceiling is set at 2 percent, but there is no requirement for the revenue generated to be directed to its budget. The use of regulatory fees to generate general revenue for the budget risks undermining the credibility of the regulatory system, particularly if the reg- ulator is left too poorly resourced to provide high-quality regulatory services to regulated entities despite the payment of unusually large fees. Thus, it is important to ensure that adequate disciplines on the amount of fee revenue raised exist. One means of counteracting the incentive for governments to divert fee rev- enue to the budget is for the legislation establishing the regulator to state clearly that funds received from any industry levy can only be used for the regulation of the industry. Such an approach can still be compatible with central approval of the regulator’s budget. For example, any revenue which exceeds the budget Funding Regulatory Agencies | 55 TABLE 6.1  Legislated ceilings on regulatory fees COUNTRY SECTOR/ACT FEE CEILING COMMENT Rwanda Law on the Electricity Regulator 1% of turnover Actual fee set by Regulatory Board Nepal Telecoms Act 1997 None Several fee sources established in law Nepal Nepal Electricity Regulatory 1% of turnover No specified process for determining Commission Act 2017 actual fee Madagascar Law on Institutional Reform of the 2% of turnover (licensed operators) No requirement for fee revenue to be Telecoms Sector [2005-023), directed to regulator’s budget 1.5% of turnover (“free plan” Decree 2016-213 enterprises) Madagascar Electricity sector None Law 1998-032 authorises turnover- based fees. Decree 2001-803 authorises the fee to be set by joint order of Ministers for Finance and Electricity Kosovo Law on the Electricity Regulator 2% of turnover Actual fee set by the regulatory board Kosovo Law on Electronic 0.5% of turnover Actual fee established by the regulator Communications 2012 via regulation Georgia Law on Electricity and Natural Gas 0.3% of turnover No specified process for regulator to 1999 determine actual fee approved for the regulator could be required to go into a separate reserve fund, from which the regulator’s board could draw, with Ministry of Finance approval, to meet unanticipated expenses (such as major legal actions). This approach provides a high degree of transparency on the use of the funds and creates incentives for industry levies to be limited to the amount required to fund reg- ulatory costs. An alternative approach is for the legislation governing the regulator to spec- ify that if regulatory expenditure falls significantly below the level of revenues raised by industry levies, the levy amount must be reduced accordingly the fol- lowing year. This approach has the additional benefit of directly ensuring that industry levies can only be used to defray the costs of regulating the industry. Both of these approaches have the benefit of eliminating the incentive for gov- ernments to starve the regulator of funds in order to increase the revenue it has available for other purposes. A “lighter-handed” alternative is to provide for a high degree of transparency as to the uses made of the funds from the industry levy. For example, the regula- tor could be required to include information in its annual report on the revenue generated by the industry levy and its uses—including the proportion actually spent on industry regulation. This approach also provides a degree of incentive to limit industry levies to the amount needed to cover regulatory costs. REVENUE FROM FINES AND PENALTIES Regulators must have the ability to levy significant fines and other monetary penalties to ensure that their decisions are complied with and the conduct of market players conforms with legislative and other requirements. The revenue from such penalties can potentially be significant, raising the issue of whether the regulator should be able to retain this revenue as a partial funding source, or whether it should be required to remit the revenue to the Ministry of Finance. 56 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS Retention of the revenue from fines can potentially reduce the size of the fees that regulated companies must pay if the regulator is operating on a full cost recovery basis and has the advantage of helping ensure a larger proportion of the regulator’s budget comes from companies whose non-compliance with the rules gives rise to significant regulatory activities and costs. However, allowing the regulator to retain fine revenues also has several disadvantages. In particular, if the regulator is responsible for determining the size of the penalties levied, the ability to retain the revenue collected gives rise to a clear conflict of interest. In such circumstances, the existence of a credible appeals mechanism independent of the regulator becomes particularly important. In sit- uations in which enforcement and the determination of penalties are responsi- bilities of the courts or administrative tribunals, it is usual practice that the resulting revenues are remitted to the central budget. A second concern is that the amount of revenue derived from fines and other monetary penalties is likely to vary widely from year to year. Thus, reliance on this revenue as a significant source of funding for the regulator’s ­budget is likely to give rise to significant uncertainty regarding the amount of funding available. This issue may potentially be addressed if fine revenues are hypothecated to the funding of a contingent liability—notably the need to fund legal actions. A third concern is that retention of fine or penalty revenues can distort reg- ulatory effort, both between and within regulators, reducing their focus on addressing the most important harms. The areas where imposing fines is easi- est are likely to gain more resources, even if they are not those which are fun- damental to ensuring that underlying regulatory objectives are being achieved. Areas where offenders have limited assets, or it is hard to establish an offence, may not receive sufficient regulatory effort. The incentive to maximize penalty revenue could also BOX 6.5 reduce the regulator’s focus on encouraging compli- ance in favor of an excessive emphasis on The United Kingdom’s Payment enforcement. Given these factors, it is generally preferable for Systems Regulator: Financial penalty the revenue from fines and other monetary penalties scheme to be paid into the general budget, rather than used to The Payment Systems Regulator (PSR) is authorized fund the activities of the regulator. Where there is a to impose penalties for non-compliance. These must, desire to retain penalty revenue, the above incentive in general, be remitted to the Treasury. However, the issues should be addressed. One model which does PSR is able to deduct amounts to recoup its enforce- achieve this outcome has been adopted by the Payment ment costs before remitting the remainder of the pen- Systems Regulator in the United Kingdom and is set alty revenue. The governing legislation requires the out in box 6.5. retained revenue to be used for the benefit of those regulated under the scheme, but does not allow the entity sanctioned to benefit from it. Consequently, the DIAGNOSING FUNDING ISSUES IN revenue is used to reduce the fees that would other- RELATION TO REGULATORY AGENCIES wise be payable by compliant regulated entities in the following year. As the size of the PSR’s budget is set In general, a review of the funding of regulatory independently of the penalty revenue it collects, the agencies tends to be politically sensitive, involving regulator has no direct organizational incentive to key governmental and non-governmental actors, as maximize penalty revenue. well as media attention, even where the issue might seem to be minor and technical. This sensitivity, Source: Payment Systems Regulator 2017. combined with the typical fragile context of serious resource limitations and political instability, makes Funding Regulatory Agencies | 57 BOX 6.6 Questions for guiding a desk review of regulator funding 1. What sources of information indicate that funding 5. Develop a preliminary action plan for resolving the is an issue and how reliable are the sources? funding issue that is appropriate to the country’s 2. What are the specific issues identified by the needs and context. available sources of reliable information and do 6. Support the action plan with strong arguments, they represent a major issue or constraint for such as those related to efficiency, effectiveness, business and investment? communication, transparency and coordination. 3. If it is a major issue or constraint, what are the 7. If the action plan is endorsed, a communications government’s priorities in relation to the funding strategy should be developed to ensure that all of regulatory agencies compared to other issues those inside and outside government likely to faced by the infrastructure sectors? be affected by the reforms are informed of the 4. How can the issue be resolved? This should involve changes in good time. This should include the consultation with key stakeholders, especially media, as well as more institutional means of those who have been affected by the lack of clarity, communication, such as speeches by officials and but only after clearance has been gained at senior ministers, publication in the Government Gazette levels for such a consultation, given its sensitivity. and annual reports. it vital to identify and assess the need for a review of legislation, however small. It will also tend to involve senior staff from within the agency and, often, senior staff from within the supervising ministry, who should be informed of the potential issue as soon as possible. It also means that even greater attention should be paid to ensuring that a preliminary desk review be undertaken as thoroughly as possible. The typical questions to address in such a desk review are indicated in box 6.6. Where desk review reveals that a more detailed and lengthy review is neces- sary, appendix D contains an example of the types of questions that could be addressed. NOTE 1. A useful guide to the factors that should be taken into consideration in using a cost-­recovery basis for funding agencies is OECD 1998. REFERENCES African Development Bank Group. 2014. Madagascar. Combined Report on the 2014–16 Interim Country Strategy Paper and the Country Portfolio Performance Review. Abidjan: African Development Bank. https://www.afdb.org/en/documents/document/madagascar​ -­c ombined​-report- on-the-2014-2016-interim- country-strategy-paper-i- csp​ -and-the-country-portfolio-performance-review-cppr-11-2014-50396/. Brown, A. C. 2008. The Funding of Independent Regulatory Agencies. A Special Report to the Public Utilities Commission of Anguilla. Harvard Electricity Policy Group, John F. Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University, Cambridge. http://citeseerx.ist.psu.edu​ /­viewdoc/download?doi=10.1.1.696.7010&rep=rep1&type=pdf. 58 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS Domah, P., M. G. Pollitt, and J. Stern. 2002. “Modelling the Costs of Energy Regulation: Evidence of Human Resource Constraints in Developing Countries.” Working Paper WP 0229, Department of Applied Economics, University of Cambridge, Cambridge. Hüpkes, E., M. Quintyn, and M. W. Taylor. 2006. Accountability Arrangements for Financial Sector Regulators. Economic Issues 39. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. Kelley, E., and B. Tenenbaum. 2004. “Funding of Energy Regulatory Commissions.” Energy and Mining Sector Board Working Notes 30525, World Bank, Washington, DC. Payment Systems Regulator. 2017. The Payment Systems Regulator’s Financial Penalty Scheme. https://www.psr.org.uk/sites/default/files/media/PDF/Financial-Penalty-Scheme_0.pdf. OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). 1998. “User Charging for Government Services.” Occasional Papers No. 22, OECD, Paris. ———. 2016. Driving Performance at Latvia’s Public Utilities Commission. The Governance of Regulators. Paris: OECD Publishing. http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264257962-en. World Bank. 2008. Georgia – Judicial Reform Project; Third Structural Adjustment Credit Project; Reform Support Credit Project. Project Performance Assessment Report 46832, Washington, DC. http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/257411468032037102/Georgia​-Judicial​ -Reform-Project-Third-Structural-Adjustment-Credit-Project-Reform-Support​ -Credit-Project. 7 Integrity ABSTRACT As with all public governance, regulatory agencies must demonstrate high stan- dards of integrity. They must hold all personnel to high standards of conduct and avoid any suggestion that impropriety or illegal behavior can be tolerated. Regulatory integrity is essential to achieve decision-making which is objective, impartial, consistent, and avoids bias and improper influence. Safeguarding integrity is an ongoing challenge with the growing interconnectedness of gov- ernment and the private sector, as well as public-private partnerships, increas- ingly large public expenditures, and the opportunities for corruption provided by the major procurement contracts and processes that are a feature of infra- structure sector. KEY TAKEAWAYS General takeaways • A regulator that performs duties with integrity does so honestly and in the public interest. • To protect integrity, a system of rules and a code of behavior are needed—for example, regulatory staff should abide by a code of conduct, which includes at the very least: –– prohibition against: bribes; all forms of conflict of interest; any form of preferential treatment; and use of insider information for personal gain; –– reasonable disclosure of personal financial interests; –– clear specification of policy on external and post-separation employment. • Regulators can develop their own code of conduct or abide by a govern- ment-wide code. When abiding by a government code, this should be clearly stated in regulatory policy. • Establishing rules and codes of conduct need to exist alongside a “culture of integrity,” where the manager and supervisors set the tone and employees have mechanisms to seek advice or report concerns.  59 60 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS • Integrity is affected by several other principles important for regulatory gov- ernance, including: –– Mandate clarity: policy statement establishing a regulator should mention that it will perform its duties with integrity. –– Independence can help reduce risks to a regulator’s integrity—either at the institutional or organizational level. –– Accountability and transparency are necessary to assess a regulator’s integrity. –– Funding: a system of checks and balances on funding can reduce the risk of “featherbedding” regulator budgets and of funds being misappropriated. Takeaways specific to post-fragile contexts • Establishing a culture of integrity may be more challenging in post-fragile environments, though given the often weak institutional situation there, it is important to try to develop one. • In post-fragile contexts, government-wide integrity systems are likely under- developed. It is thus extremely important for the regulator to have its own, sufficiently robust code of conduct. INTRODUCTION Public officials should perform their duties with integrity—that is, discharge their duties honestly and in the public interest. One of the aims of regulatory governance is to help ensure that integrity is achieved and sustained systematically, with the governance mechanisms working together to both promote integrity and to pro- tect the regulator from external actors seeking to have it favor private interests. This chapter outlines the need for a system of rules, or code of conduct, to help govern the behavior of decision-makers in the regulatory agency, and to help prevent improper practices and maintain integrity. This is particularly important where corruption is deeply embedded and has become the norm. The chapter also briefly examines the relationship between integrity and the other principles for good regulatory governance, role clarity, requisite powers, independence, funding, decision-making and the governing body, predictabil- ity, engagement, accountability, transparency, and performance evaluation. A FOCUS ON RULES—A CODE OF BEHAVIOR Regulatory agencies must be seen to have or to be developing a culture of integ- rity, with all personnel held to high standards of conduct. They should be required to abide by an explicit, published set of ethical standards, or code (ide- ally, set out in law for all government employees, including those in regulatory agencies), with such standards binding and rigorously enforced. Where such a code does not exist, the board of the regulatory agency should require that one be developed. The code should identify: A competent and independent office or unit empowered to investigate and report on alleged breaches, for example, for cases of major corruption. This is Integrity | 61 generally the Auditor-General’s office or the equiva- BOX 7.1 lent, if it has the capacity and expertise for such work. Alternatively, the board of the regulator should ensure that an independent unit is established within the What is a declaration of interest? agency and that its operations are fully transparent and its decisions made publicly available. A declaration of interest is an official statement by a A competent mechanism for systematic disclo- board member that indicates his or her association sure of the financial interests of members of the reg- with an outside person, organization or activity, in ulator’s governing body . The law establishing a those cases where the board member might not be regulatory agency should reference the standards completely fair and independent when taking a code, where one exists, and the fact that members of decision affecting them. the board or commission and the staff of the agency are subject to those standards and to investigation by the independent body, including a required declara- tion of interests (see box 7.1) by board members. While the list of standards included in the code can vary (box 7.2 provides one example), it is important that the core minimum include: • prohibition against the making and acceptance of bribes, gifts and gratuities of any kind; • prohibition of all forms of conflict of interest; • prohibition against any form of preferential treatment; • reasonable disclosure of financial interests; • prohibition of use of inside information for personal gain; • a clear specification of policy on outside and post-separation employment; • a clear specification of what constitutes a reasonable use of information and communications technology and other regulatory agency resources. BOX 7.2 The Mexican Ethics Code and rules of integrity The Mexican Ethics Code is built on the constitution-  3. public contracting, licensing, permits, authorizations ally defined principles of legality, honesty, loyalty, and concessions impartiality, and efficiency, together with a set of  4. governmental programs additional values: Public interest, respect, respect for  5. public procedures and services human rights, equality and non-discrimination, gen-  6. human resources der equity, culture and environment, integrity, coop-  7. administration of public properties eration, leadership, transparency, and accountability.  8. evaluation processes In turn, a set of integrity rules complement the  9. internal control ethics code by specifying desired and undesired 10. administrative procedures behavior in 13 areas: 11. permanent performance with integrity  1. public behavior 12. cooperation with integrity  2. public information 13. decent behavior Source: OECD 2017. 62 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS IMPLEMENTING A CODE OF BEHAVIOR: BUILDING A CULTURE OF INTEGRITY While an explicit set of ethical standards or rules is fundamental to ensuring integrity, it is not, by itself, sufficient. The standards must be internalized by indi- viduals to create a “culture of integrity” in the regulatory agency, and the work- place culture must support and encourage ethical behavior. This should aim at inspiring integrity through raising awareness of, and commitment to, ethics, public-sector values, and the public interest. The combination of a stan- dards-based system (often known as a compliance-based system) with a val- ues-based system that emphasizes self-policing and motivation, is far more effective than simple reliance on ensuring compliance with the standards (Whitton 2001). Where a civil-service wide code of behavior already exists, the regulator should develop and release a policy that stresses the agency’s commitment to the code and use it as the basis for its own code. The policy should: • state that unethical conduct and behavior which breaches the code will not be tolerated; • set out the responsibilities of the agency head, senior executives, other man- agers and employees to create a culture that supports ethical conduct; • provide a clear view of, and strategies to promote, appropriate standards of behavior for employees at all levels; • ensure all employees have easy access to the agency’s policies on ethical conduct and behavior and regularly remind employees of their responsibilities. The policy should identify clear channels for employees to report unethical or corrupt conduct and managers should inform employees, as far as possible, of any action they have taken to deal with their reports of inappropriate behavior. It is useful to nominate ethics officers to provide points of contact for employees to raise ethical issues, and to provide a forum for discussion of such issues in the agency. Training in what constitutes ethical decision-making and behavior for all employees should be provided, making sure they understand and apply the code and the values it contains. It should be reinforced on a regular basis with further training and be a compulsory part of the induction process for new employees. Individual managers and supervisors should model their own actions on the code’s values, as this helps send clear messages to staff about expected behavior. In addition, they should be able to provide advice on: • ways for employees to report concerns, including formal and informal pro- cesses and external avenues; • where to go for advice and/or support, for example, employee assistance or counseling services, agency contact officers; • relevant internal and external review mechanisms; and • how to manage real or potential conflicts of interest. Managers should also report on, and address misconduct and other unac- ceptable behavior in a fair, timely and effective way, declaring any personal inter- ests that may impede ethical decision-making. Integrity | 63 INTEGRITY IN THE POST-FRAGILE CONTEXT Ensuring high standards of integrity is likely to be challenging in many post-­ fragile situations. Corruption typically flourishes in an environment of weak institutions and limited enforcement of legislative standards. At the same time, addressing corruption, and changing perceptions of corruption, is a crucial element in changing views of the attractiveness of the regulatory environment. ­ Companies based in OECD countries typically face explicit legal prohibitions on payment of bribes, commissions and other incentives in their operations in third countries, thus establishing major disincentives to investment in countries with doubtful standards of integrity. Recent work by the OECD1 highlights the multidimensional nature of addressing integrity issues, with action needed in areas including prevention, detection and prosecution. However, it also underlines that a strong governance environment is a crucial component of the integrity toolkit. In a context in which civil-service-wide integrity systems are likely not well-developed, it is particularly important that codes of conduct specific to reg- ulators are sufficiently robust to both clearly set out the required standards of behavior and underpin enforcement action by officials within the regulator and externally. The role of top management in modeling the expected behavior is also likely to be particularly important. As noted above, an integrity system that combines compliance-based and ­values-based elements is likely to be more effective than reliance on one or other of these approaches. Several formerly fragile states have achieved substantial reductions in the degree of corruption and perceived corruption by pursuing this strategy for example, Rwanda, Botswana, Mauritius and Cabo Verde. INTEGRITY AND THE OTHER PRINCIPLES FOR GOOD REGULATORY GOVERNANCE Integrity issues are closely connected with several governance principles. Hence, in evaluating a system of regulatory governance and, in particular, when consid- ering possible changes to that system, it is important always to consider the possible impact of the changes on integrity issues. ­ Integrity and role clarity Integrity should be explicitly addressed by the policy or statute establishing the regulator (as for Rwanda as in box 7.3); specifically, the policy or statute should state: • that the regulator shall perform its functions with integrity; • how the integrity of board members is to be achieved and sustained; • that the existing code of behavior for the public service also applies to the regulator. Integrity and independence Independence is a means of reducing the risks to individual and organizational integrity, because it limits the extent to which the regulator is subject to undue influence and conflicts of interest. Establishing a regulator with a degree of inde- pendence thus creates greater confidence and trust that regulatory decisions 64 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS BOX 7.3 will be made with integrity. Integrity should therefore be a major concern when deciding on the governance arrangements for a regulator. Founding legislation for the Rwanda The founding statute should also specify what con- Utilities Regulatory Authority stitutes appropriate grounds for the removal of board emphasizes integrity members and commissioners and should describe the required process, together with their rights of appeal. The key regulator in the electricity sector in Rwanda This protects them from unreasonable and inappro- is the Rwanda Utilities Regulatory Authority (RURA). priate action by the minister or government as well as The importance of ensuring its independence and maintaining trust in their integrity. integrity was recognized in several ways by the law (No. 39/2001) which established it. The first was the law itself, for, in establishing a separate and Integrity, accountability and transparency independent regulatory agency, the government was Accountability refers to the obligation for the regula- sending a clear message to markets that it valued tor to accept responsibility for a decision or action and integrity highly in regulatory decision-making and to report, explain and be answerable for the resulting was establishing an independent regulator to achieve consequences. In the context of regulatory gover- it. Secondly, Article 13 explicitly requires that nance, transparency refers to the degree to which the regulatory boards must at all times act in an major decisions and actions of a regulator, together independent, open, transparent and objective fashion with the grounds on which they were taken, are open and not discriminate in any way. Third, Article 23 to scrutiny. Transparency is a fundamental require- requires all ministers to respect the independence of ment for achieving effective accountability. In turn, an agency and it’s Regulatory Board in all cases. accountability and transparency are necessary to enable the integrity of a regulator to be assessed, since such assessments must be based on scrutiny of the regulator’s decisions and actions. Integrity and funding In general, the ordinary fiscal controls, auditing policies and practices, and bud- getary controls of the government must apply to the regulator, since these are fundamental controls aimed, in large part, at ensuring regulatory integrity. However, higher standards are likely to be required in some areas, as a balance to the greater independence granted to the regulator. Hence, it is vital that the law clearly sets out the obligations and responsibilities of regulators and the ­ standards they must comply with. It is also important to have a system of internal checks and balances on the regulator’s finances, with some kind of arm’s-length oversight of the system to reduce the risk of both “featherbedding” its budget and misappropriation of funds. Ideally this should be described in the statute establishing the agency. Integrity and stakeholder engagement While stakeholder engagement can contribute substantially to regulatory quality, it also entails integrity risks: where engagement is not conducted openly, with access available to all interested parties, the regulator risks giv- ing too much weight to the interests of particular, influential stakeholders. Development of new forms of relationship between the public sector and the business and non-profit sectors, involving closer collaboration than in the past, including public-private partnerships and self-regulation, increases this risk. Integrity | 65 Hence, it is important that stakeholder engagement be guided by clear policies and guidelines aimed at safeguarding regulatory integrity. Key requirements are to: • develop and publish an explicit stakeholder engagement policy in con- sultation with representatives of stakeholder groups to ensure that engage- ment is both transparent and open to all stakeholders; • identify all groups who have a stake in the outcome, or that are likely to be affected in relation to each engagement project. Understand their responsi- bilities, core motivations and interactions; • organize the type and level of engagement that is appropriate for the project in question, keeping the process flexible so as to cope with changing circumstances while aiming to provide high levels of access; • allocate sufficient financial and human resources to make the engage- ment effective, and share the information needed for decision-making, ensuring good information flows; • support stakeholder confidence in the value of participating in engage- ment by ensuring that feedback is provided on their inputs and these are con- sidered in decision-making, including explanations of why proposals have not been adopted, where appropriate; • regularly assess the process and outcomes of stakeholder engagement projects to find out what went well and what did not, so as to improve future engagement projects. Integrity and performance evaluation As integrity is a primary element of good governance, it should be assessed during performance evaluation. This can help: • convince supervisory bodies, legislators, journalists, citizens and stakehold- ers that the agency is performing with the required degree of integrity; • establish what works and does not in relation to maintaining integrity, so that relevant processes and activities can be improved over time; • improve staff morale by celebrating successes in sustaining integrity. The policy and procedures related to integrity should be examined regularly as part of the routine evaluation of agency performance. Integrity and “corruption proofing” The underlying objective behind efforts to develop and implement a sound gov- ernance structure for regulators is to ensure systematically that they will carry out their functions effectively and efficiently, thus supporting the economic per- formance of the regulated sector. A major hurdle to effective regulation, partic- ularly in post-fragile countries with relatively undeveloped institutional structures, is corruption. The growing danger of corruption has recently given rise to a body of literature which focuses on identifying and addressing that risk in relation to legislative drafting. Corruption proofing refers to the systematic assessment of the form and substance of draft or enacted legislation and regula- tion to identify and address provisions that risk giving rise to corruption. Box 7.4 describes how corruption proofing has been implemented on country-level. Appendix D presents a corruption proofing checklist developed in the con- text of the South-Eastern European Regional Anti-Corruption Initiative, an 66 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS BOX 7.4 The growth of corruption proofing Thirteen countries (Albania, Armenia, Azerbaijan, legislation is responsible. More often, an external body Kazakhstan, the Republic of Korea, the Kyrgyz such as an anti-corruption agency is responsible for Republic, Latvia, Lithuania, Moldova, the Russian corruption proofing, preparing assessments that Federation, Tajikistan, Ukraine and Uzbekistan) have include recommendations to minimize the risk, as in put in place a method to be used to systematically assess Latvia and the Republic of Korea. Sometimes civil soci- whether their legislation may open the way to corrup- ety reviews laws pertaining to corruption and develops tion. In some cases, corruption proofing is undertaken its own methodology, as in Moldova and Ukraine, by the government during the legal drafting process, which requires that draft laws are published at an early such as in Albania, where the ministry drafting the stage and made available for public comment. Source: Hoppe 2014. BOX 7.5 Basic questions for guiding a desk review of integrity in a regulatory agency 1. Is there a national integrity policy? 5. Does the agency’s induction program for new 2. Is there a reference to a code of behavior or staff include material and training in relation to standards code in the agency’s statute and integrity? requirements as to its application? 6. Does the agency have a unit or senior official 3. Does the agency have an integrity and/or anti- responsible for integrity and corruption? corruption policy and associated processes? 7. Are board members and senior staff required to 4. Does the agency have a code of behavior as part of make a declaration of their financial interests and, its integrity policy? if so, how is this undertaken? intergovernmental regional organization sponsored by the European Union and covering nine states: Albania, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Bulgaria, Croatia, North Macedonia, Moldova, Montenegro, Romania, and Serbia. The anti-­ corruption checklist may provide a useful additional resource when seeking to embed governance principles in new legislation or attempting to diagnose existing regulatory arrangements and address priority problems. CONCLUSION This chapter has outlined the need for a system of rules, or code of behavior, to help prevent improper conduct and maintain integrity among decision-makers. This is particular importance wherever corruption is deeply embedded or has become the norm. The chapter also briefly examined the relationship between integrity and the other principles of good regulatory governance, role clarity, requisite powers, independence, funding, decision-making and the governing body, predictability, engagement, accountability, transparency, and performance evaluation. Key ques- tions that can help guide desk reviews of integrity are contained in box 7.5. Integrity | 67 NOTE 1. See, for example, the OECD country surveys in relation to corruption and material in rela- tion to anti-corruption at www.cleangovbiz.org. REFERENCES Hoppe, T. 2014. Anti-Corruption Assessment of Laws (“Corruption Proofing”): Comparative Study and Methodology. Southeast Europe 2020 SEE2020 Series. Sarajevo: Regional Cooperation Council. OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). 2017. OECD Integrity Review of Mexico: Taking a Stronger Stance against Corruption. OECD Public Governance Reviews. Paris: OECD Publishing. Whitton, H. 2001. Implementing Effective Ethics Standards in Government and the Civil Service. Berlin: Transparency International. 8 Predictability ABSTRACT Individual decisions made by regulators should, to a substantial degree, be pre- dictable for regulated entities. Predictability adds certainty to their operating environment, thus favoring effective decision-making. It also enhances confi- dence in the impartiality and quality of the regulator’s decisions. Predictability can be achieved by ensuring that the principles and rules that the regulator follows when making decisions are explicit, publicly available and well ­ understood. KEY TAKEAWAYS General takeaways • Predictability in regulatory decision-making is a commonly cited investor concern. • Clear regulations enable individuals or organizations to judge what behavior is acceptable and what is not. • Often, however, regulations do not provide sufficient detail on how the regu- lator will carry out its responsibilities. This creates uncertainty on the part of the regulated and of possible investors, which can be mitigated by making regulatory practices more explicit—through published policies, procedures, etc. • While changes in regulatory policies or decisions (e.g., tariff methodology) may be required, changes, particularly significant ones, should only be intro- duced after significant public notice. • “Predictability” should be committed to in the law; basic regulatory princi- ples, practices, procedures should also be articulated.  69 70 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS Takeaways specific for post-fragile contexts • Predictability may be hard to achieve in post-fragile environments, though establishing it should be a high priority. Taking the following actions can help: –– establishing regulatory functions in law; –– helping the regulator publish material on how it will carry out its duties; –– providing regulator staff with clear guidelines so they know how to carry out their duties; –– publishing formal written policies. REGULATIONS AND PREDICTABILITY Predictability in regulatory decision-making is one of the most commonly cited investor concerns (OECD 2015, 16). Regulations on what sort of behavior is per- mitted or prohibited often carry a penalty for those who break the rules and sometimes positive incentives for those who abide by them. They provide high- level criteria on which regulators base their decisions as to whether a person’s behavior is in breach of the rules. They enable individuals and organizations to determine what behavior is acceptable and what is not, thus enabling them, if necessary, to modify their actions to make certain that they are acting within the law. However, a key issue is that regulations frequently fail to provide enough detail on how the regulator’s key responsibilities must be exercised. This is likely an issue of concern in post-fragile countries, where specialist drafting skills are scarce and many regulatory structures are being developed for the first time. For example, it is common for regulatory agencies in infrastructure sectors to be given, as an important part of their role, authority and responsibility for setting tariffs. However, sometimes the statute establishing the agency provides no details as to how, or according to what principles, tariffs should be calculated. This was the case in Brazil, where the method for valuing assets in the recalculation of elec- tricity distribution tariffs was left entirely to regulator discretion. Private-sector distributors claimed they had been promised that the asset base would be pur- chased at the prevailing price at the time of sector privatization, whereas others countered that there was no such commitment. Both the law and the concessions were silent on the question. The result was uncertainty and a lack of ­predictability as to tariffs at a critical time in the development of the country’s infrastructure markets. Both could have been minimized, if not entirely eradicated, if the basic methodology and criteria for calculating tariffs had been made explicit either in the law or in relevant contracts. This would have provided greater predictability for investors and ­ consumers and, of course, guidance for the regulators. While predictability can often be enhanced by ensuring the regulation pro- vides high-level guidance on how to deploy regulatory powers, the need for ­ regulators to exercise their own judgment and discretion necessarily remains. Predictability issues must also be addressed in these contexts. While formal ­legislation is almost always widely published and available for scrutiny, it is often not supported by formal policy statements from regulators giving their interpre- tation of the regulatory requirements that they must implement and providing clear guidance as to how they will be applied in practice. The predictability of regulatory decision-making can thus be enhanced if the regulator develops and publishes additional material, such as formal policies, internal processes and guidelines. This material should always be consistent with the legislation governing the operations of the regulator and should focus on inter- preting the law and its purpose, working to apply it e ­ ffectively in practice. Predictability | 71 The process of developing explicit policies, processes, guidelines and other such materials has benefits for both regulatory agency staff and regulated entities. Regulatory agency staff and explicit agency policies For regulator staff, availability of formal, written policies and procedures pro- vides clear guidance on how to carry out their roles in ways that are legitimate and appropriate—that is, that are consistent with the law and broad government policy. This is likely to be particularly important in post-fragile environments where there is typically a lack of well-qualified staff and, in a context of newly established (or recently reformed) law and institutions, a lack of experience in the practical application of that law. From the perspective of a regulatory agency, the impact of such formal policies, internal processes and guidelines in enhanc- ing the predictability of decisions is that they: • give confidence to staff in undertaking their functions and making decisions and also help to provide organizational resilience (as opposed to undue dependence on a few experienced and well-trained individuals); • provide an explicit framework for assessing staff decisions; • enhance the perceived legitimacy of the regulator, through increased predict- ability, in the eyes of regulated enterprises, the public and the government— something particularly important for newly established or reformed regulators. Making formal, written policies and procedures available to regulated entities Publishing formal, written policies and procedures gives regulated entities a clearer understanding of the factors underlying the regulator’s decisions. This enables them to predict the regulator’s responses more reliably, (e.g., when approving applications), including its likely decisions and actions if regulated ­ ­subjects break the rules. This predictability underpins investor confidence by pro- viding a high level of assurance as to the expected outcomes of investment, opera- tional and other decisions. It also enables regulated entities to clearly see when a regulator’s decisions are inconsistent with its policy framework and standard procedures, and whether an appeal against a decision is likely to be successful. ­ CHANGING RULES AND PROCEDURES To underline the value of predictability is not to argue that regulations should never change. Change is needed to respond to different circumstances and facil- itate innovation, but significant changes should be introduced only after reason- able public notice and meaningful consultation with interested parties. Regulated entities should be given sufficient time to adjust to the impact of the changes on their operations and future investment plans. In particular, policy and regulation should never be retroactive. PREDICTABILITY AND CONTRACTUAL COMMITMENT Predictability, the law and agency decision-making The basic regulatory principles, practices, procedures, and policies followed in infrastructure sectors should be articulated in law, preferably in a statute or pri- mary law. The aim is to ensure stability and predictability in the entire regulatory 72 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS system, leading to more rational, efficient decision-making by investors and con- sumers. Where these matters are not made explicit and enshrined in the law gov- erning the agency, decision-making will generally be less transparent and decisions less predictable. This implies that investors face greater “regulatory risks” and, as a result, will be less likely to make investments. Where it is not possible or feasible to address these matters in legislation, they should, at a minimum, be included in policy and procedural documents developed by the regulator and made publicly available. Crucially, the regulator staff’s actual decision-making practices should consistently be based on the content of these documents. Predictability and contractual commitment Part C of this manual examines the importance of contractual commitment in detail, notably in relation to attempts by governments and their agencies to rene- gotiate contracts. In summary, the maintenance of contractual commitment pro- vides an important basis for predictability in decision-making and, in turn, in ensuring and maintaining investor confidence. PREDICTABILITY AND THE RULE OF LAW IN POST-FRAGILE CONTEXT THE ­ While predictability is an important feature of all regulatory systems, it is usually in short supply in fragile and early post-fragile situations. In the period of fragil- ity, regulatory decisions are typically unpredictable due to political, economic and social instability and conflict. There is also frequently a lack of transparency and participation in decision-making, making it difficult for stakeholders to pre- dict government decisions. After a country exits from fragility and conflict it faces the challenge of rebuilding and reforming its regulatory system. This results in rapid changes to regulations and regulatory processes, resulting in further unpredictability, at least in the short term. ­ It follows that high priority should be given to establishing predictability, as it will be a key factor in creating a positive environment for domestic and foreign investment. If investors cannot be certain about the enforceability of their rights and obligations, this raises the cost of capital, thereby weakening firms’ compet- itiveness and reducing investment. In addition, uncertainty and ambiguity in a regulatory system can also foster corruption as investors may be more likely to seek to protect or advance their interests through bribery, and government actors may seek undue benefits. These tendencies are only slowly reversed as trust, credibility and predictability are achieved. Hence, attention should be paid to predictability issues from the early stages of the reform process. Box 8.1 provides an example of the problems that can arise due to a lack of predictability, specifically in the context of land acquisition for public projects, as well as a summary of reforms adopted to address this issue. CONCLUSION: DIAGNOSING PREDICTABILITY ISSUES IN RELATION TO REGULATORY AGENCIES This chapter examined the importance of the predictability of regulatory deci- sion-making for agency staff and regulated entities, stressing the value of formal, written policies to guide behavior being made available to regulated subjects. Key questions for undertaking a desk review of predictability are contained in box 8.2. Predictability | 73 BOX 8.1 Uncertainty and the expropriation of land in Indonesia Many infrastructure projects require land to involved in acquiring land, the long time between be  expropriated, especially those involving the identifying land and purchase allowed speculators to construction of roads and dams. Public-private drive up the price. This led to a significant escalation partnerships (PPPs) in Indonesia were adversely of total project costs. affected by the laws governing expropriation and the A new, 2011 law regarding expropriation of land for delays that resulted from uncertainty as to their likely public works and PPPs improved matters. From the impact on road projects. Owners delayed selling their perspective of the investor it made the timing of when land to PPPs for as long as possible in the hope that the land would be available through expropriation their bargaining position—and hence the price— more certain. The law set tight deadlines for appealing would be strengthened as the project progressed. expropriation decisions and the level of compensation, Also, because of the drawn-out negotiation process to be based on the market price of the land. Source: OECD 2012, 22. BOX 8.2 Questions for guiding a desk review of predictability Ideally, potential predictability issues should be 5. How can the issue be resolved? This should involve identified when a policy and its related statute are thorough consultations with key stakeholders, being developed, particularly during the corruption- especially those who have been affected by the proofing process. Where a lack of predictability is alleged lack of predictability. believed to be an issue, key questions in diagnosing the Where the review indicates that significant changes issue and proposing solutions are as follows: are required, the following steps should be taken: 1. Are laws and regulations and their implementation 1. Develop a preliminary action plan for resolving and enforcement transparent and readily accessible? the predictability issue that is appropriate to the Do they set out key processes in sufficient detail? Are country’s needs and context. laws stable—that is, are they not changed very fre- 2. Support the action plan with key arguments, such as quently? those related to private-sector investment, efficiency, 2. How are the interests of investors taken into effectiveness, communication, transparency and consideration when policy and regulations are coordination. amended? 3. If the action plan is endorsed, a communications 3. What sources of information indicate that strategy should be developed to ensure that all those predictability is an issue and how reliable are the inside and outside government likely to be affected sources? by the reforms are informed of the changes in good 4. What are the specific issues identified by the time. This should include a selection of media, as well available sources of reliable information and do as more institutional means of communication, such they represent a major issue or constraint for as speeches by officials and ministers, publication in business and investment? the Government Gazette and annual reports. 74 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS REFERENCES OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). 2012. Indonesia: Strengthening Co-ordination and Connecting Markets. OECD Reviews of Regulatory Reform. Paris: OECD Publishing. http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264173637-en. ———. 2015. Policy Framework for Investment . Paris: OECD Publishing. http://dx.doi​ .org/10.1787/9789264208667-en. 9 Engagement ABSTRACT Regulators should have established mechanisms for consultation and dialogue with stakeholders as part of achieving their objectives. Effectively drawing on the knowledge of regulated sectors and understanding the views of regulated businesses and citizens systematically improves the quality of regulatory ­ decisions. Ensuring stakeholder views are heard and weighed also helps confer legitimacy on the regulator and its decisions and supports compliance. However, engagement processes must be designed in ways that avoid regulatory capture and conflicts of interest. KEY TAKEAWAYS General takeaways • Stakeholder engagement is the process whereby a regulator discusses key regulatory issues with those affected by its decisions. • Key purposes of such engagement include: (1) gathering information to allow the regulator to better analyze key issues; (2) helping promote confidence in the regulator and the decisions it takes. • Regulatory issues that require engagement depend on the regulator’s specific functions, though they should include broader issues like development of operational policies and significant regulatory decisions. • A quality engagement process is: systematic; open; supported by the provi- sion of adequate information; timely; characterized by feedback; sustained throughout the policy cycle; and evaluated. Takeaways specific for post-fragile contexts • Given civil society organizations are less common and generally less well-­ developed, identifying relevant groups to engage with might be more chal- lenging. It may be appropriate for the regulator, or the relevant ministry, to help in the formation of such bodies.  75 76 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS INTRODUCTION Stakeholder engagement refers to processes in which the regulator discusses key regulatory issues with those who are affected by its decisions. The primary stakeholders are the producers and consumers of the regulated industry’s outputs. Other stakeholders include potential entrants to the industry, partici- ­ pants in downstream industries and final consumers. The aim of this chapter is outline the value of effective engagement, with a focus on how to ensure a to ­ well-functioning engagement policy and process is put in place. The purpose of stakeholder engagement is to: 1. gather information needed for a better analysis of key issues in the regulated industry to improve the quality of regulatory decision-making; and 2. promote confidence in the regulator and its decisions by ensuring that the opinions of affected groups are seen to be taken into account. This, in turn, promotes the legitimacy of the regulating body and its decisions. The kind of issues requiring stakeholder engagement depend to some extent on the specific functions of the regulator. However, they should generally include both broader themes, such as the development of operational policies, and sig- nificant regulatory decisions. In relation to policy development, the focus of engagement will likely be to obtain a clear understanding of what the community views as the key regulatory issues. This should inform the regulators’ priorities. Where engagement relates to individual decisions, or specific sets of decisions, engagement will seek to obtain information to inform decision-making. This could include gathering specific data and improving the regulator’s understanding of key market dynamics. The use of formal advisory bodies Constituting a formal advisory body is one option in implementing and demon- strating commitment to systematic engagement. Having an advisory body with legislative status can make stakeholders confident that the regulator will take account of their views. Where this is the objective, ensuring that a wide range of interests are represented will be paramount. Alternatively, these bodies can be structured with a focus on ensuring that a range of expertise is available to the regulator. An expert advisory body may provide significant benefits in the early stages of reform, when it might be difficult to recruit expert members to the regulator’s governing body. However, several risks are associated with this model. One is that the advi- sory board may be seen as a substitute for developing a strategy for wide-rang- ing engagement with stakeholders. This can result in the regulator hearing too narrow a range of opinions. A second is that reliance on an advisory board for expert input is ultimately a poor substitute for developing these capacities in-house. Associated with this is the risk of the advisory board becoming a mechanism leading to regulatory capture, as the regulator comes to depend substantially on the advice of the same interlocutors over a period in carrying out its functions. However, in a fragile context, while these are risks in the immediate post-­ conflict stage, the benefits of the advisory board’s additional capacity outweigh long-term risks associated with the regulator never building those capacities. Engagement | 77 These risks suggest that if an advisory board is adopted in the early stages of reform, consideration should be given to including a “sunset clause” in the relative legislation, thus setting a term for its existence or at least providing for its review after a certain period. This is consistent with the objective of gradually moving to reliance on internal expertise. Second, the membership of the board should be rel- atively broad so as to reduce the potential for its capture by specific interests. In addition, the legislation could also include specific requirements for the regulator to conduct broader and more open consultation besides the advice of the board. QUALITY IN ENGAGEMENT PROCESSES A high-quality engagement process should be: • systematic • open • supported by the provision of adequate information • timely • characterized by the provision of feedback • sustained throughout the policy cycle • evaluated. Systematic The regulator should develop and publish a stakeholder engagement policy. This should explain in what circumstances it will conduct consultations and who will be consulted. It should also identify the general processes to be used, including how notice of consultation opportunities shall be given, what types of consulta- tion mechanisms will be used (e.g., written submissions, public hearings, formal meetings) and what time will typically be allowed for responses. Publishing a policy provides confidence among interested parties that they have a right to be heard and helps them understand how to engage. It also allows the regulator to be challenged if they do not engage with stakeholders in accord with the policy. Openness A key risk with stakeholder engagement is that it involves only selected interests, with which the regulator has established relationships. Where highly structured approaches to engagement, such as advisory boards, are used, this risk can be higher. Restricting the range of interests consulted will mean the regulator risks having a less sound understanding of the regulatory environment, opening it to greater risk of capture and detracting from its legitimacy by creating resentment among those excluded from the process. These risks can be avoided if the regulator explicitly acknowledges the principle that any interested party can participate in consultation. Importantly, consultation practices should ensure this principle of open engagement is a practical reality. This means that the existence of opportunities to engage are made widely known, that enough time is allowed for submissions to the regulator and that efforts are made to identify and remove other impediments to less organized and resourced interests being engaged. Particularly in a low-income country context, the regulator 78 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS should take an active approach to this principle, trying BOX 9.1 to identify relevant interests and inviting their participa- tion in the process in the least costly manner available. Engagement by the Georgian National Another element of openness is that stakeholders Energy and Water Supply Regulatory should have the opportunity to hear what views oth- Commission ers have put to the regulator. This means it is good practice for written submissions to be published on The legislation governing GNEWSRC requires that all the regulator’s web page, that hearings are held pub- sessions, decisions, resolutions, orders, minutes and licly as far as possible, and that stakeholders should be documents of the Commission are made available to able to challenge views put by other parties. the public and interested parties and stakeholders. There will be circumstances in which the regulator This provides the basis for a very full engagement seeks confidential material from some parties, and its between the Commission and the public and a sensitivity must be respected. However, there is a much-reduced potential for its regulatory capture and need to minimize any exemptions from the general conflicts of interest. While the Commission does not principle of openness if engagement is to yield effec- appear to date to have developed a formal engagement tive communication and retain the confidence of the policy, the requirement that a wide range of its key stakeholders and the public. Box 9.1 provides an exam- activities and documents be available to stakeholders ple from Georgia, showing how all documents should and the public provides a mechanism for engagement be made available to the public. by interested parties and a degree of expectation that consultation will be undertaken. Supported by the provision of adequate information A quality engagement strategy provides all parties with an equal opportunity to join in the process. However, where technical- ly-based issues are being considered, less organized and well-resourced groups (e.g., consumer organizations) often have difficulty in engaging effectively. This means that regulators should support engagement by such groups by publishing relevant information in discussion papers or similar documents as the starting point for the consultation process. These should: • provide relevant background information to enable the issue in question to be properly understood; • identify the key focus of the consultation, possibly by including specific ­ questions that stakeholders can address in developing BOX 9.2 their responses; • be written in a way that is easily understood by The Nepal Telecommunications people without a detailed knowledge of the issue in question. Authority makes consultation information easily available This material must be made available in advance of the consultations so stakeholders can obtain and The Nepal Telecommunications Authority’s (NTA) understand it before engaging. It should be published ­website includes a public notice page listing forthcoming on the regulator’s website and made available on consultations as well as the broader activities of the reg- request. The Nepal Telecommunications Authority, as ulator. Detailed consultation papers, which explain the outlined in box 9.2, has an engagement strategy which issue being addressed and identify a range of specific makes relevant information available in easy-to-­ issues on which information and feedback are sought are understand form to interested parties. also published on the website. The papers remain avail- able for several years. The NTA has published an average Timeliness of three consultation papers annually in recent years. Engagement must occur before regulators have decided an issue or determined a broad course Engagement | 79 of action. This means planning consultation initiatives at an early stage in the decision-making process and carrying out the necessary preparations, such as drafting discussion papers. A common problem in relation to government policy development is that open, public consultation is seen as a formal obligation that must be complied with, rather than an important information source and integral part of decision-making. Very often, initial, informal discussions with key businesses ­ and other powerful interests lead to policy directions being formed before broader consultation starts. This is a major risk, for several reasons: • The quality of decision-making is likely to be compromised where the regu- lator relies on limited sources of information and advice. • There is a clear risk of capture if wider interests are excluded from effective engagement with the regulator. • Stakeholders, seeing that their views are not weighed appropriately, often cease to engage, causing legitimacy problems and closing off sources of future information and advice. Accountability mechanisms should be developed requiring the regulator to demonstrate that it has consulted appropriately and weighed the inputs received. This will help to develop a culture in the agency that sees stakeholder engage- ment as an important aid to carrying out regulatory functions more effectively. Providing feedback Even though the willingness of stakeholders to engage will quickly diminish if they do not see any benefits deriving from their involvement, their views do not neces- sarily need be adopted. However, the regulator should provide formal feedback after a consultation, indicating what views were received, how it weighed and ana- lyzed those views, and how those views affected the final decisions. This can be done at an aggregate level by publishing a single summary docu- ment setting out the key opinions put forward by each major party consulted and how they were assessed. However, there is also merit in responding directly to submissions by individual groups, particularly where less well-organized and well-supported groups have made significant efforts to engage. Sustained throughout the policy cycle It is important that the engagement policy cover stakeholder engagement at each stage of the regulatory governance cycle. This means that as well as consulting stakeholders when new regulations are being made, or regulatory decisions adopted, it is important to seek stakeholder views during regulatory implementa- tion. Feedback from those directly affected by regulatory decisions can help to iden- tify poor outcomes more quickly and enable any problems to be addressed promptly. Evaluated The regulator should ensure that its approach to consultation is assessed from time to time to identify and address shortcomings. This does not need to be a very detailed or formal process. However, ensuring that an independent body (e.g., an auditor-general) is given the task of undertaking evaluations, and that 80 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS stakeholders can participate without fear of adverse consequences, is crucial to ensuring that accurate assessments are obtained. ENSURING EFFECTIVE ENGAGEMENT IN THE POST-FRAGILE CONTEXT The importance of engaging consumers and citizens, as well as producer inter- ests, has been emphasized above. In the post-fragile context this engagement, while extremely important, is also extremely challenging. Data indicates that greater citizen engagement in rule-making is associated with higher-quality reg- ulation, stronger democratic regimes and less corrupt institutions (Johns and Saltane 2016). However, in a post-fragile environment where the social contract is in flux and many lingering unaddressed grievances remain, ensuring that citi- zen engagement occurs and yields its desired outcomes may be difficult. The flow of accurate unbiased information—such as between a regulator and relevant stakeholders—is key to rebuilding trust between the population and the state in post-fragile contexts. However, several barriers prevent information from reaching its intended audience. As mentioned throughout this guide, gov- ernment institutions in these contexts often lack capacity, and this can affect their ability to ability engage with citizens. There may also be physical barriers— like destroyed communications infrastructure or pockets of lingering insecurity. On the receiving end, citizens are limited in their ability to receive and react to information from state institutions. Furthermore, when the space for participation and engagement exists, the resulting interaction might not be meaningful or could even risk exacerbating existing forms of inequality or exclusion. While these dynamics are challenging, finding a way to provide relevant information to stakeholders is, in general terms, fundamental in improving the quality of the feedback received. In the low-income/post-fragile context, where citizen and consumer organizations are less developed, paying attention to pro- viding this background information in simple, easily understood form, is partic- ularly important. It may also be important to keep the country’s current context central to any engagement design. For example, does information need to be pro- vided in multiple languages so as not to stoke existing social tensions? Or does reaching the most vulnerable infrastructure customers require an approach dif- ferent from the standard one? Providing adequate time for developing responses is also likely to be a key factor. Where citizen or consumer groups are yet to arise, it may be appropriate for the regulator or the minister responsible to help establish such bodies. While care should be taken that this does not lead to the creation of “dependent” groups, such initiatives may sometimes offer the only opportunity of obtaining real consumer feedback. CONCLUSION The aim of this chapter was to outline the value of effective engagement, with a focus on how to ensure that a good-quality engagement policy and process is put in place. A desk review of engagement should address key questions such as those listed in box 9.3. Engagement | 81 BOX 9.3 Key questions for a desk review of engagement 1. Does the regulator have an explicit, written 5. Is the information provided in a timely fashion, engagement policy? enabling those interested to respond? 2. Is engagement open to all interested parties? Is 6. Is feedback characterized by a formal acknowl- the regulator able to engage effectively with all edgement, with an explicit indication of whether interested parties (i.e., in terms of language, mode or not it was used? of engagement—not all places experiencing fragil- 7. Is engagement sustained throughout the stages of ity will have access to internet or phones). the policy cycle? 3. Likewise, does the regulator know who it needs to 8. Are the engagement policy and associated pro- engage with? cesses regularly evaluated? 4. Is engagement supported by the provision of ade- quate information for those interested? REFERENCE Johns, M., and V. Saltane. 2016. “Citizen Engagement in Rulemaking: Evidence on Regulatory Practices in 185 Countries.” Policy Research Working Paper 7840, World Bank, Washington, DC. 10 Accountability and Transparency ABSTRACT Accountability and transparency are the necessary counterweights to indepen- dence. That is, regulators that enjoy a high degree of independence must be sub- jected to stricter accountability and transparency requirements to ensure that they are carrying out their functions appropriately. Regulators are accountable to the government (i.e., ministers and parliament), to regulated entities and to consumers and the public. Transparency—including publishing policies and guidelines, as well as important decisions, is one key element of accountability. The second key element is the existence of robust appeal mechanisms KEY TAKEAWAYS General takeaways • Accountability implies that the objectives, functions and powers of regulators are clearly established and procedures for carrying them out specified. • Transparency implies that a regulator is open about the way it operates. • Regulators are accountable to multiple groups: Different accountability mechanisms are required for each: –– The supervising ministry or legislature requires annual reports or state- ments of expectations. –– Regulated entities require that the regulator conduct internal and external accountability reviews. –– The public requires that the regulator publish major decisions, policies and procedures so that they can hold the regulator accountable. Takeaways specific for post-fragile contexts • In post-fragile contexts, key challenges include: The fact that regulators and the government itself have limited experience with effective regulation; that any appeals process will not be sufficiently detailed; that they will face capac- ity constraints.  83 84 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS • Nonetheless, systems should seek to ensure that relevant stakeholders have a clear right of appeal and that the process for lodging a complaint is clear and simple. • Regulators should also ensure timely decisions to build confidence in the process. • Appeals mechanisms should be detailed in relevant legislation. • Given state judicial bodies in this context will likely have capacity constraints in handling appeals in good time, they could overcome them by: –– Making legislative lists and expediting a review of the most economically significant cases. They can also facilitate the development of specific expertise within the court or tribunal by enabling judges to specialize in issues related to a regulated sector or sectors. –– Establishing a specialist administrative or quasi-judicial body to oversee regulatory decisions. INTRODUCTION Accountability implies that the objectives, functions and powers of the regulator are clearly established, and the policies and processes it adopts to carry out those functions and exercise those powers are clearly specified. This provides the basis for assessment of its performance by the legislature or other responsible authorities and for action to be taken where it acts inconsistently. It also means that decisions can be challenged by regulated entities and consumers, using appeal mechanisms. Transparency means that the regulator is open about the way in which it operates, publishing the policies, criteria and guidelines that guide its decisions and setting out the reasons for key decisions. Transparency also implies being open about the key results of the regulator’s activities by publishing outcome indicators and other relevant material. Regulators are accountable to the government (i.e., the minister and parlia- ment), to regulated entities and to consumers and the public. Different mecha- nisms are needed to ensure that effective accountability to each of these groups is maintained. ACCOUNTABILITY TO THE MINISTER AND THE LEGISLATURE The regulator’s role is to achieve public-interest objectives identified by the gov- ernment. These objectives are usually identified explicitly in the laws establish- ing the regulator, as are the powers given to the regulator to achieve them. This means that the regulator is accountable to the legislature, either directly or through its minister, and thus should report regularly to these bodies. Accountability mechanisms A key way to hold the regulator accountable is to develop specific annual reporting requirements that clearly indicate what information is needed and when. These annual reports should be tabled in the legislature and made public to enable wider scrutiny and discussion. Also, their contents should demonstrate that the regulator is fulfilling its role efficiently, effectively, impartially and with integrity. Accountability and Transparency | 85 A second, commonly used accountability mechanism is the “statement of expec- tations.” This is typically a formal document sent to the regulator’s governing body, or to the CEO, by the minister. Such a statement is particularly important where the regulator is part of a ministerial agency, rather than an independent entity subject to specific legislation. However, even for independent regulators, a statement of expectations enables additional detail to be provided about the government’s objec- tives for the agency and how it should operate, thus improving accountability. A statement of expectations should identify relevant government policies and clarify the government’s specific objectives for the regulator, including any expec- tations as to how it should do its job. It may be appropriate for the government to involve stakeholders in the development of this statement to ensure greater sup- port and understanding of the regulatory structure. Importantly, however, the statement must be fully consistent with all statements regarding the functions, powers and objectives of the regulator established in the relevant legislation. The regulator should respond formally to the minister, indicating how it will meet the expectations identified. This should include specific commitments and performance indicators, where possible. Where the regulator is required to address competing objectives, it should indicate how it will go about reconciling any conflicts and setting priorities. Statements of expectations, and responses from regulators, should be pub- lished on the regulator’s website, so that all stakeholders can assess the regula- tor’s actions in the light of this information. ACCOUNTABILITY TO REGULATED ENTITIES Accountability to regulated entities involves ensuring that they can understand how the regulator goes about making decisions. Regulators should publish the policies and guidelines that they use to guide decision-making in key areas so that regulated businesses can reasonably anticipate the view that the regulator will take.1 (See chapter 8, which addresses the principle of predictability.) Accountability mechanisms Where regulated businesses or citizens believe the regulator has not exercised its decision-making powers appropriately—that is, in accordance with the rele- vant legislation or its published policies and guidelines—they should have access to robust appeal mechanisms. A strong appeal process is fundamental to the accountability system and key in helping maintain trust. Appeal mechanisms should generally include internal and external elements. Internal accountability mechanisms Internal review often constitutes an appropriate first step in challenging a regu- lator’s decision. Delegated decisions, such as those made by inspectors, can have significant impacts on regulated subjects and should be open to internal review on request. The regulator should inform regulated entities of these internal review mechanisms when they inform them of decisions made. Internal review has the benefit of allowing rapid and low-cost reappraisal of the initial decision and can allow the regulator to self-correct poor decision-­ making. Internal review processes should be conducted by a separate group within the regulator’s management structure that is at arm’s length from those 86 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS that made the original regulatory decision. Appellants should have the opportu- nity to explain, in writing and/or in person, the nature of their objections to the original regulatory decision. The response to the appeal should address these points and, where a decision is upheld, ensure that the basis for the original ­ decision is explained and justified in terms of the relevant regulatory policies, principles and procedures. However, internal review is likely not appropriate for major regulatory deci- sions involving much of the regulator’s workforce. Moreover, where regulated entities are dissatisfied with the results of an internal review, it is important that they have access to an external review process considered to be independent and disinterested. This is essential to maintaining confidence in the robustness of the regulatory decision processes. External accountability mechanisms As a rule, external review of major regulatory decisions should be conducted via the judicial system. Appeals against major decisions should be heard in a senior court, since the issues raised can be highly technical and the financial implications large. A key concern is the need for appeals to be heard in a timely manner, since there may be important economic consequences, for example in terms of delayed investments, or market opening, which may affect wider economic development. ACCOUNTABILITY TO THE PUBLIC Accountability to the broader public is largely underpinned by transparency. In this context, transparency means that the regulator should publish: • policies, procedures and guidelines it uses in regulatory decision-making; and • major decisions made on individual matters, together with clear and detailed reasoning behind those decisions. Some countries have gone further in this regard. For example, as noted above, Georgia’s Law on Electricity and Natural Gas prescribes that the Georgian National Energy and Water Supply Regulatory Commission keep public records of all proceedings, decisions, orders and other documents and that the Commission’s: • sessions be open to the public, including sessions involving the grant, modifi- cation, revocation or suspension of licenses, as well as concerning the estab- lishment, modification or revocation of tariffs; • resolutions and decisions be published according to set rules. ACCOUNTABILITY AND TRANSPARENCY IN THE POST-FRAGILE CONTEXT Limited experience A key issue in establishing appropriate appeals mechanisms in post-fragile con- texts is that, in many cases, there will be little experience with challenging the decisions of government bodies based on clear rules and procedures. The legiti- macy of such challenges may not be widely accepted, and there may also be con- cerns that challenges to government may have negative consequences. In such Accountability and Transparency | 87 BOX 10.1 Finding the right balance between expediting appeals and allowing sufficient time for external review Indonesia allows applications for the court to review competition law cases often involve considering decisions of its Commission for the Supervision of detailed, sometimes conceptually complex matters. Business Competition (KPPU) to the District Court Indeed, such reviews sometimes take 12–18 months within 14 days of the decision being announced. to complete in other jurisdictions. This issue of Appeals must be decided within 30 days of the start of ensuring adequate time is available to hear and a hearing. Similar deadlines are applied where a party determine appeals is made more significant by the wishes to appeal the District Court’s decision to the fact that appeals against KPPU decisions are heard Supreme Court. by generalist courts in Indonesia, rather than the While these time limits enable rapid review, they specialist competition tribunals that some countries risk encouraging poorer findings as key questions in have created. Source: OECD 2012, 120–21. circumstances, it will be important to ensure that the right to appeal is clearly established and that processes for lodging appeals are simple and easy to follow. Timely resolution of appeals—particularly internal appeals—will also help estab- lish confidence in the process, as will the provision of clear, readily understood reasons. That said, the need for timeliness in decision-making must be balanced against the imperative of ensuring that the appeal body has enough time to reach a well-considered decision. Box 10.1 provides an example. Insufficiently detailed appeals process Another key requirement is to ensure that appeals mechanisms are described in the relevant laws in sufficient detail to enable workable systems to be imple- mented. This includes that the grounds on which appeals can be made are clearly identified and the court or tribunal empowered to hear external appeals is spec- ified. It should also include details of the circumstances in which both internal and external appeals can be initiated. Box 10.2 provides an example drawn from Rwanda of inadequate appeals provisions being subsequently strengthened. Capacity constraints A further issue of relevance to the post-fragile context is ensuring that the body nominated to hear appeals has adequate expertise and capacity. As noted in box 10.1, some appeals can turn on highly technical issues and may have major financial implications. This means that having robust institutional arrangements is essential to ensure sound outcomes and the development of confidence in the appeals mech- anism among regulated parties. Achieving this may be difficult in a post-conflict context, where courts are likely to be overburdened and subject to substantial delays. This may suggest the need to create specific “lists” within the court system, an approach with at least two significant benefits. Firstly, it can act as a triage mechanism, expediting review of the most economically significant cases. 88 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS BOX 10.2 The development of an appeals process in Rwanda The multisectoral Rwanda Utilities Regulatory anti-competition activities. If the person or organiza- Agency (RURA) was established in 2001. The only tion making the complaint is not satisfied by RURA’s direct reference to an appeal against RURA was con- response, they may file a case with the competent tained in Article 47 of the relevant legislation, which court. specified that any person or organization aggrieved by The Electricity Law (No. 21/2011) includes a simi- a decision of its Board could appeal to the court. lar generic appeals provision, with Article 15 stating However, the legislation failed to specify to which that any applicant not satisfied with the regulatory court the appeal should be made or the procedures agency’s decision to refuse to issue a license may, after involved. Moreover, there was no specific mention of unsuccessfully attempting an out-of-court settlement, any internal review of the appeal process in the appeal before the competent court. Despite more legislation. robust appeals mechanisms, the new legislation fails In 2013 the RURA was reestablished by Law to specify the court to which the appeal should be No.  09/2013 and the subject of appeals received made, and the procedures involved. Moreover, there is greater attention. The Board was empowered by no mention of any internal review or appeals process, Article 20 to take decisions on any disputes referred other than that implied in Article 20. While such to it and, upon request from the parties to a dispute, details are also absent from RURA’s website, it pro- to conciliate. Article 47 empowers the Board to inves- vides details on how to lodge a complaint against the tigate any complaint made to RURA in relation to provider of a utility such as energy or gas. Second, it can facilitate the development of specific expertise within the court or tribunal by enabling judges to specialize in issues related to a regulated sector or sectors. One alternative to this model is to establish a specialist administrative or quasi-judicial tribunal to provide independent review of regulatory decisions. ­ For example, decisions of the Australian competition regulator are appealed to the Australian Competition Tribunal.2 A key benefit of this model is that mem- bership of this and similar bodies typically includes a mixture of judges and expert lay people, which, combined with the specialized nature of the tribunal, helps ensure sound and rapid decisions in respect of highly technical matters. There are likely to be challenges in establishing such tribunals in the imme- diate post-fragile context, given both resource and capacity constraints. One solution is to establish a single tribunal with jurisdiction to hear appeals in respect of regulatory decisions across a wide range of infrastructure sectors, as well as competition issues and other economically significant regulatory appeals. It may be possible to coopt expert lay members on a part-time basis from domes- tic academic institutions or foreign governments or universities to help ensure such tribunals are adequately resourced. A further alternative is to establish an arbitration mechanism whereby an independent person can hear the parties to a dispute on a largely informal basis and make a binding decision. However, it should be noted that arbitration sys- tems generally require both parties to agree to be bound by decisions, while some measure of appeal to the courts is also typically provided for. Thus, while arbitration may make for a timely decision in the first instance, it may not ­provide finality for the parties. Accountability and Transparency | 89 At a fundamental level, having an effective appeals process requires minimiz- ing the number of appeals that need to be heard. This highlights the importance of predictability, and decisions being made in accordance with clear, published policies, principles and guidelines, so that appeals with limited prospects of suc- cess are less likely to be initiated. It also requires that initial regulatory decisions may only be overturned on appeal on limited, clearly specified grounds, princi- pally when the regulator: • acted outside the scope of its lawful authority; • failed to follow proper procedures; • acted arbitrarily or unreasonably; or • acted against the clear weight of available evidence. CONCLUSION This chapter examined the importance of accountability in regulatory gover- nance. It outlined accountability and mechanisms for its achievement in relation to ministers and the legislature, regulated entities and the public. ­ A checklist of key questions for a desk review of accountability is contained in box 10.3 below. BOX 10.3 Checklist for applying the principles Applying the principles—accountabilit y and assessment of the regulator’s performance in transparency meeting its responsibilities? 7. Do the performance indicators help the Accountability to minister and the legislature government and the legislature to monitor and assess the performance of the overall regulatory 1. Has the minister or other oversight body framework? published a written statement of expectations to 8. Is there a legislative requirement for all major the regulator? If not, how have the expectations of measures and decisions to be published in a timely the regulator been provided? manner? 2. Has the regulator published a formal response to this statement, explaining how it intends to Accountability to regulated entities respond to the priorities set out in it? 3. Is there a mechanism to make sure that the statement 1. Does the regulator provide easily accessible of expectations is renewed or updated regularly? and understood guidance material on appeals 4. Is there a legal requirement for the independent processes and systems to regulated entities? regulator to produce an annual report to the 2. Does the regulator have a clearly established legislature? process for internal review of significant delegated 5. Does this requirement set out the major regulatory decisions? performance indicators and other information 3. Are regulated entities advised that internal review required to be included in the report? of significant delegated regulatory decisions is 6. Do the agreed performance indicators provide available when they are informed of the outcome sufficient information to enable meaningful of the decision? continued 90 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS Box 10.3, continued 4. Is the internal review unit as operationally separate Accountability to the public from the decision-making body as possible? 1. Has the regulator published its main operational 5. Is the right of appeal through judicial process policies, principles and processes? available for regulated entities? Under what 2. Is information on reviews and appeals processes circumstances? easily accessible and readily understood? 6. Can a successful appeal result in the original 3. Are all major decisions made by the regulator decision being reversed? published, together with a clear account of the 7. Is the appeal process transparent, timely and underlying reasoning? conducted at arm’s length? NOTES 1. An exception to this general principle is that in circumstances where publication would allow regulated businesses to game the regulatory system, limiting transparency is justified in order to avoid such gaming. 2. Canada also has a Competition Tribunal, which similarly has a mix of judicial and expert lay officers. REFERENCE OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). 2012. Indonesia: Strengthening Co-ordination and Connecting Markets. OECD Reviews of Regulatory Reform. Paris: OECD Publishing. http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264173637-en. 11 Performance Evaluation ABSTRACT Evaluation is an essential part of the policy cycle. Evaluations of the performance of regulators should consider both their effectiveness in carrying out the func- tions assigned to them both in legislation and through other directives, and the fitness for purpose of the regulatory structures that are in place. That is, the results should distinguish where changes to the way a regulator carries out its responsibilities are required and where more fundamental change may be needed to the governance arrangements under which the regulator operates as well as the market rules it administers KEY TAKEAWAYS General takeaways • Regulator performance evaluations should be carried out internally (to determine how successfully it is meeting its objectives) as well as exter- nally (to assess whether its strategic goals are being met). • Key characteristics of a good performance evaluation include: –– pre-scheduling them –– having a review body –– developing a good review process and methodology. • A regulator’s performance should be evaluated against a set of indicators directly linked to the regulator’s objectives and functions. Takeaways specific for fragile contexts • Performance evaluation is very important in the post-fragile context where new institutions and market structures dominate infrastructure industries. This may require refinements to initial arrangements.  91 92 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS • However, developing a robust performance evaluation system takes time. It is advised that regulators in these contexts start with internal evaluations; external evaluations conducted by an Auditor-General should be prioritized so that capacity constraints are managed. INTRODUCTION: PERFORMANCE EVALUATION IN THE FRAGILE CONTEXT Performance evaluation is particularly important in the post-fragile environment, where new institutions and market structures are likely to dominate the infrastruc- ture industries and it is very likely that refinements to the initial arrangements made will be needed. Even where new institutions are working well, evaluation is import- ant to help determine whether it is feasible to move to the next stages of reform. Performance evaluation is an essential feedback mechanism that provides information on what is being done well or badly. This can reinforce positive behaviors and provide incentives to address problems. Performance measure- ment also enables the regulator and the government to demonstrate the benefits of reform to stakeholders and helps validate the regulatory model chosen. SCOPE OF PERFORMANCE EVALUATION Performance evaluations should be carried out internally and externally. Those carried out within an organization form part of good internal governance prac- tices, as they provide key information to underpin changes in management strat- egy and approach. These evaluations should focus on how well the regulator is performing its functions and how well the specific systems, processes and pro- cedures it has adopted for this purpose are contributing to its performance. While internal evaluation is a core activity for a well-functioning organization, the strategic importance of infrastructure regulators means that independent, external evaluation is also needed. External reviews should have a broader focus and aim primarily to assess the extent to which the regulator’s strategic goals, such as increasing competition and service reliability, are being met. Where there are shortcomings, these reviews should where and how they originate. This implies that external reviews should primarily address systemic issues, identifying any problems with governance arrangements, the regulator’s integrity and the broader regulatory environment for the industry in question. This can also include exam- ining key decisions by the regulator that have strategic significance. In addition, a key focus of reviews should be to evaluate the practical impact of recent changes to the legislative framework or other key elements of the reg- ulator’s operating environment. KEY CHARACTERISTICS OF A GOOD EXTERNAL REVIEW PROCESS External reviews should, in general, be initiated by a body other than the regulator itself—typically the minister or cabinet, or the legislature. The regulator’s govern- ing body may determine it is appropriate to initiate an external review itself in certain circumstances, such as where no external review has been conducted for a long time. An external review is likely to be more widely perceived as credible and independent. Performance Evaluation | 93 The key characteristics of a high-quality independent review process 1. Pre-scheduling of reviews There is often opposition to conducting performance reviews within the public sector. This may be due to concern that negative conclusions will cre- ate political problems. In addition, reviews of an independent ­ regulator by the supervisory ministry may be seen—​or at least presented—as amounting to political interference. These factors suggest that pre-scheduling reviews to be conducted at specified future times can help ensure that they are undertaken. Review clauses are fre- quently included in the legislation that establishes, or governs the operation of, the regulator. A legislated review requirement, typically stating that a review must be completed by a certain date (or that reviews should be conducted at specified, minimum intervals), arguably provides the highest level of assurance that a review will proceed. Alternative approaches include having government pre-announce future reviews as part of major policy statements in respect of the relevant sector; and assigning responsibility for developing a program of performance reviews of key public bodies to an appropriate body with the requisite skills, experience and independence, typically the Auditor-General’s department. Reviews should be conducted more frequently in the early stages of reform implementation, when significant changes to regulatory governance or other matters affecting the regulator’s operations will more likely occur. Addressing such changes and issues in a timely way is important for successful reform. Reviews can be scheduled for specific dates (e.g., 3 or 4 years after a new regula- tory agency starts operations, or after it takes on responsibility for regulating a new sector) or can be triggered by specific events (e.g., a review may be required within, say, 2 years after a mobile phone spectrum auction has occurred). 2. A Review Body The key characteristics required of the review body are that it should be inde- pendent and have sufficient technical expertise. Reviews should be undertaken by a body that is (and is seen to be) independent of both the regulator and other major interests in the industry, particularly those of the main regulated entities. Some possible models include: • Review by an independent expert body. Responsibility for developing a program of performance reviews can be given to an independent body, such as an auditor-general, not subject to government direction. • Review by expert consultants. This approach may be attractive in low-­ capacity environments, due to its potential to bring high-level expertise to bear. Having international consultants conduct the review will minimize any per- ceived problems of conflict of interest. However, care will be needed to ensure that the consultants understand the low-income (or post-fragile) environment and the key issues arising from it. Cost may also be prohibitive, although sup- port may potentially be available from donor bodies. • Review by ministerial panel. The Minister responsible for the regulator may appoint an ad hoc review panel. In this case, the composition of the panel is particularly important. At a minimum, there should be representation from central agencies (i.e., Finance department, Chief Minister’s department) to ensure a “whole-of-government” perspective is taken. Independent regula- tory experts (e.g., academics) and those from international agencies should 94 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS also be considered. Box 11.1 provides an example of a performance evaluation by a ministerial committee in Nepal. • Review by a parliamentary committee. This model is likely to be used where the prescheduled review requirement is included in legislation. A par- liamentary committee can second experts to work with it during the inquiry and can take evidence from sector experts as part of public hearings. Reviews conducted by an independent expert body, such as an auditor-­ general, are likely to have high levels of credibility among stakeholders, as they are usually free from political influence. Conversely, where a supervising minister appoints expert consultants or a review panel to conduct reviews, transparency in the appointment process and in the setting of terms of refer- BOX 11.1 ence for the review will be important to ensure credibil- ity. Box 11.2 exemplifies how different models for review of a regulator were used at different points in time. Performance evaluation at the Nepal Review by a parliamentary committee may give Telecommunications Authority rise to concerns regarding independence, especially in The Nepal Telecommunications Authority recently circumstances in which the government has a sub- reappointed its CEO for a second, 5-year term. Prior to stantial parliamentary majority. In addition, there that, the Ministry of Information and Communications may be problems in ensuring that adequate technical formed a committee to review his performance during expertise is available, particularly if budget constraints his initial term. While this review appears to prevent the appointment of external experts to assist have been an ad hoc decision, scheduling performance the process. Care is thus needed in assessing whether reviews prior to discrete, major events affecting the such a model is likely to yield credible results. regulator, such as the appointment of a new CEO, can help ensure that such reviews occur with appropriate 3. Good review process and methodology frequency. Following a good review process is essential to ensure that the outcome both identifies key issues BOX 11.2 Australia’s Essential Services Commission Act develops review mechanism and timing of review, which lead to mandate changes for the regulator The Essential Services Commission (ESC) is a multi- Section 66 also requires the minister to table the sectoral infrastructure regulator established under review report and the government’s response to it in the Essential Services Commission Act (ESCA). parliament within a set time. A review was con- Section 66 of the ESCA. requires the responsible ducted in 2006–07 by a retired civil service depart- minister to ensure that the Act was reviewed within ­ ment head, assisted by a group of Ministry of Finance 5 years of it coming into operation. Specific review officials. objectives identified were: The ESC was given progressively broader func- tions by government and its operating environment 1. to determine whether the objectives of the Act changed in many ways. While no subsequent review and of the Commission are being achieved and are requirement is contained in the Act, the government still appropriate; and commissioned a second review, which reported 2. whether the Act is effective or whether it required approximately 10 years after the first. This review was amendment to “further facilitate” the objectives conducted by a Ministry of Finance team, assisted by or to insert new objectives. specialist consultants. Performance Evaluation | 95 and potential solutions and is seen as credible by stakeholders. A fundamental requirement is that the review body has sufficient time to undertake a thor- ough assessment. Also, in a rapidly evolving market and regulatory environ- ment, conclusions and recommendations need to be delivered in a  timely manner. Where major reviews are undertaken, a review period of 6–12 months is quite likely appropriate. The review should be open to stakeholders and the public. This means the review body should seek written submissions from stakeholders and the public and that enough time should be allowed for these to be developed. Participation through public hearings is also a key good process element, since it: • enables the reviewers to question interested parties and engage in dialogue on key matters; • provides opportunities for those who may not be well-placed to make written submissions to participate. This can include community organizations, small local government bodies and the general public. To enable interested parties to participate effectively, the review body should publish a discussion paper which briefly describes the main issues to be addressed in the review and identifies key questions on which stakeholder input is invited. This can include requests for quantitative data as well as qualitative information and opinions. Finally, the review should identify the criteria according to which it will assess the performance of the regulator and (where relevant) the regulated sector. These criteria should be derived directly from the objectives, functions ­ and responsibilities of the regulator, as identified by the government and often, by legislation. These should be supported by the development of relevant indica- tors, discussed below. DEVELOPING INDICATORS Regulators should develop performance indicators, directly linked to their objectives and functions, as part of their ongoing performance management function. These indicators should avoid creating perverse incentives—that is, encourage staff to act in a certain way to achieve a high score on an indicator— when this is not necessarily consistent with achieving the underlying objectives of the regulator. Identifying indicators early in the regulator’s development helps ensure that data collection starts early, thus maximizing data availability. However, it will usually be necessary to refine the indicators, or add new indicators over time, as weaknesses or gaps in existing indicators are identified. Public bodies frequently pursue multiple, conflicting objectives, (e.g., affordable electricity, self-funding sector and an attractive investment environment). This implies that a range of indicators is needed to ensure performance is measured against all relevant objectives, and conclusions can be drawn about which trade-offs to make. The indicators developed should include those that relate to: • final outcomes sought; and • matters over which the regulator has direct control. 96 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS That is, both the regulator and the external reviewers should have informa- tion to allow good assessments to be made of both the extent to which the gov- ernment’s reform objectives for the sector are being met and the extent to which the regulator is helping to achieve them. Over the long term, and where possible, the analysis of indicators should draw on time series and cross-sectional data, including international compari- sons. Expert interpretation of indicators may be helpful, particularly where per- formance is being assessed against multiple indicators. However, this level of analysis may not be feasible in the post-conflict stage. The regulator should publish indicator data as part of its annual reporting cycle, in addition to using them as part of the review process. This helps stake- holders scrutinize the regulator’s performance and to advocate for review or change where they identify significant problems. A regulator’s performance should be assessed by quantifiable indicators of activities. For example, a key indicator for many regulators may be processing times for regulatory approval or other decisions. These are important because undue delays in regulatory processes impose additional costs on business and the community, so regulators should measure their processing times for key decisions against specified benchmarks (Victorian Competition and Efficiency Commission 2012). Changes in the size of the regulator’s budget over time should also be monitored and assessed in the context of changes in the extent of its regulatory responsibilities. Indicators of the final outcomes sought are likely to include increases in investment and output in the regulated industry, as well as average prices. The regulator can clearly not be held fully accountable for these outcomes. However, reporting on these indicators can focus on key elements of the regulator’s perfor- mance influencing them. For example, the time taken to assess and approve license applications is one partial measure of the attractiveness of the business environment. BOX 11.3 USING PERFORMANCE EVALUATION Evaluation of the Rwanda Utilities Performance evaluation is a tool that enables perfor- Regulatory Authority mance improvements to be achieved progressively over time, enhancing governance and individual In common with all Rwandan public institutions, capacity. Publishing reviews contributes to this out- RURA is subject to regular external performance come, since making available assessments of existing evaluation, as required by Organic Law No. 06/2009 performance to all stakeholders will put pressure on OL, Article 5. RURA’s performance is evaluated under the government to adopt review recommendations. a performance contract agreed between its Board and A requirement for government to respond formally the Ministry of Infrastructure, its supervising to the review, including in legislation, can contribute ministry. These performance contracts have specified toward the executive taking ownership of review durations, but are renegotiated on expiry. recommendations and acting on them. This is a fre- In addition to this external review requirement, quently overlooked element of a performance evalu- RURA has, since 2013, been required by its Board to ation system. For example, while the statutory develop an annual action plan that is, among other requirement for all Rwandan public bodies to be things, used by the governing body as the basis of an subject to regular performance evaluations against internal performance evaluation. the terms of an agreed performance contract (dis- cussed in box 11.3) represented an important step Performance Evaluation | 97 forward in the post-fragile context, the system does not yet require making public the results of the evaluation. This means the performance evaluation system is not backed up by an effective public accountability and feedback mechanism. In the long term, the criteria used in performance evaluations should form the basis of individual performance assessments of key regulator staff, helping to ensure that their performance is aligned as closely as possible with the regula- tor’s overall performance objectives. DEVELOPING PERFORMANCE EVALUATION OVER TIME IN POST-FRAGILE COUNTRIES A fully developed performance evaluation system as described above requires significant expertise and resources and is unlikely to be feasible in the immediate post-fragile context, although governments such as those in Rwanda have made impressive progress. Thus, an important consideration is how to implement a set of feasible but useful requirements in the short term and build progressively on them over time. One aspect of this issue is the scope of evaluation. Starting by requiring regu- lators to conduct internal evaluations will help to instill a culture of performance assessment into these organizations from an early stage. In the short term, expert resources to conduct external assessments are likely to be in short supply. Hence, if an independent agency such as an auditor-general is tasked with conducting external evaluations, the range of regulatory bodies it can evaluate is likely to be limited due to capacity constraints. Thus, government must identify priority reg- ulators based on their strategic importance to the wider economy and society, and focus external evaluations on them. Early performance evaluation systems should be restricted to a relatively nar- row range of indicators, with the initial focus being on assessing the regulator’s effectiveness and efficiency in carrying out its specific functions, rather than seeking to measure its larger strategic impact. Such indicators can typically be measured more easily, while it should be possible to obtain inputs from regulated entities to assist in developing assessments. Finally, publication of the results of performance evaluations can be under- taken from the outset and are likely to add significant value by enabling discus- sion and critique of these reports by stakeholders and experts, both domestically and, potentially, internationally. CONCLUSION This chapter has outlined the importance of performance evaluation as an essen- tial feedback mechanism that provides information on what is being done well and or badly. It argues that it can reinforce positive behaviors and provide incen- tives to address problems. Further, it enables the regulator and the government to demonstrate the benefits of reform to stakeholders and helps to validate the regulatory model chosen. Box 11.4 contains several aspects to consider with regards to instituting performance evaluations for regulators. 98 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS BOX 11.4 Applying the principles for performance evaluation 1. All major regulators should be subject to regular, 5. Substantial regulatory changes should be a independent external reviews, in addition to any priority matter for assessment as part of the internal review activity. review process. 2. External reviews should be prescheduled—the 6. Regulators should be required to establish internal dates for the completion of future reviews should review processes at an early stage and embed a be fixed in advance. These review schedules culture of feedback and self-improvement. These should be set out in legislation or in a substantial, processes should continue even where regular publicly available policy document. external reviews are undertaken. 3. In a fully functioning review process, the scope  7. Regulators should identify indicators that can be used of the review should cover both the effectiveness to assess key elements of their performance within and efficiency with which the regulator carries the context of the review process. These should out its functions and meets its objectives and the include both “input” indicators, relating specifically regulator’s impact on the broader infrastructure to the regulator’s actions, and “outcome” indicators, sector. However, in early post-fragile contexts, which focus on the government’s key objectives for the scope of these reviews should be limited to the the sector (e.g., growth in infrastructure investment). former.  8. Time series and cross-sectional (i.e., international) 4. Where capacity constraints limit the number comparisons and peer expertise and evaluation of reviews that can be undertaken, the most should be used as part of the review process. economically significant regulators and  9. The performance evaluation criteria and results of those believed to be experiencing significant the reviews should be published. performance problems should be given priority. 10. The performance evaluation criteria should be reflected in performance assessments of regulator staff, where possible. REFERENCE Victorian Competition and Efficiency Commission. 2012. Annual Report 2011–12. Melbourne: Victorian Competition and Efficiency Commission. C Implementing Reforms to Regulatory Systems and Governance Part B identified and explained the importance of applying a set of principles in designing and assessing systems of gover- nance for regulators and examined some key elements related to their practical implementation, particularly in post-fragile contexts. Part C provides more strategic advice on adopting and maintaining a program of regulatory reform in one or more infrastructure sectors, including the estab- lishment of a regulatory agency in accordance with the prin- ciples set out in Part B. It is not possible to address the whole range of implemen- tation issues in a manual this length. However, the following chapters discuss some of the most common and significant: • Chapter 12 examines the need to gain and mobilize sup- port for reform, how to engage stakeholders in the devel- opment of regulatory policy, and the importance of transparency in the consultation process. 100 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS • Chapter 13 points out the value of, and need for, coordinating reform at  the  center of government and the merits of developing a broader, government-wide regulatory policy. ­ • Chapter 14 discusses capacity requirements for successful reform. • Chapter 15 indicates how to develop a reform strategy and the challenges faced. And • Chapter 16 concludes by highlighting how to ensure that the reform strategy is sustained over time, including ongoing commitment, continuity and policy stability. 12 Mobilizing and Engaging Pro-Reform Forces INTRODUCTION This chapter aims to explain the importance of mobilizing and engaging pro-­ reform forces to support planned and actual reform projects and to provide strategies for achieving this goal. The Public Utility Research Center (PURC) at  the University of Florida and the World Bank’s Body of Knowledge on Infrastructure Regulation notes: It is commonly understood that 75 percent of people in authority need to “buy into” a change for it to be successful. Furthermore, any significant change needs a critical mass of supporters who formulate and guide the strategy from beginning to end. (BoKIR 2019) Plans for major reform to the market structure and regulation of major infra- structure industries almost always face substantial opposition from different groups: • Citizens and civil society groups may object to reform due because of the possible consequences on consumers (particularly vulnerable ones) when government monopolies are broken up and/or competition from private companies is introduced. • Government monopoly providers also typically oppose reform. The estab- lishment of a competitive market creates substantial new challenges for them and diminishes their political and economic influence. • Several political actors will also likely oppose reform, since appointments to major state-owned infrastructure enterprises are often important sources of patronage, and revenues from regulatory taxes can be used to fund activities unrelated to infrastructure. The lengthy periods required to fully implement major reforms create ample opportunities for opponents to frustrate the process. Their actions can lead to government reform plans being delayed, in design changes that compromise underlying reform objectives, and even in the abandonment of reforms alto- gether. This dynamic is present in virtually all countries, but is particularly acute in the post-fragile context due to weaker institutions, less transparent politics and more pervasive networks of patronage and corruption.  101 102 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS Consequently, working to address concerns about the potential negative impacts of reform, as well as mobilizing groups and organizations to support reform, is a key strategy in improving its prospects of success. Engagement should be undertaken on a sustained basis with a wide range of officials and stakeholders, including NGOs and community service organizations, as outlined in chapter 9. This should aim to identify and discuss implementation issues and consider options for achieving the required goals more effectively and at least cost. The process should include ministers, relevant senior officials, civil society organizations and interested donor agencies. Importantly, this process should involve consumers from the sectors affected, including both businesses and households. Mobilizing support within the public sector Gaining the support of the boards and senior managers of state-owned enter- prises for major reform in the infrastructure sector is typically a major challenge. Indeed, these groups often actively oppose reform. Moves to introduce competi- tion and the privatization of state enterprises are typically seen as threats by the boards and senior managers affected, particularly if they have benefitted illegally from their positions. Box 12.1 illustrates this problem with the case of Georgia’s electricity sector after independence. It is therefore important that reform include, as far as possible, incumbent infrastructure providers as a key part of the reform process. In many cases, sup- port can only be gained with the replacement of opposing board members and managers—politically challenging where board members or senior managers were appointed as a reward for political support. For example, in Nepal, the gov- ernment responded to long-standing opposition to reform by the Nepal Electricity Authority by appointing a new, reformist CEO and removing two Board members who were seen as particularly obstructive. However, this then obliged the government to defend its actions in the Supreme Court. This case highlights both the need for governments to be willing to take strong action to address systematic attempts to frustrate reform and to ensure that such actions BOX 12.1 The power sector in Georgia after independence The centrally planned economy of the USSR was impaired by widespread theft of power, equipment, largely integrated with the economies of the and materials. An extremely low (5 percent) collection constituent republics. Georgia’s power sector was rate of fees led to a lack of revenue and resulted in an thus not designed for independent operation. Private absence of capital for investment and for the repair enterprise was not allowed and state management and maintenance of infrastructure. The system inefficient. The power system was run by Sakenergo, became unstable, further damaging plant and a state-owned monopoly roiled in economic crisis, equipment, and planned reforms were often political unrest, internal conflict, and corruption. delayed because of the opposition of board members Political upheavals frequently disrupted the and senior officials (Lampietti, Banerjee, and generation and supply of power, which was further Branczik 2007). Mobilizing and Engaging Pro-Reform Forces | 103 have a legal basis strong enough to withstand powerful challenges from vested interests. Box 12.2 illustrates the point. While governments can and do take strong action against state-owned enter- prises seeking to undermine reform, questions about the durability of these changes inevitably arise. The problem is that in the absence of systemic changes to the management of these SOEs, the underlying incentives to oppose reform remain and the possibility of the changes being reversed is real. Infrastructure reform measures should thus target not only the agencies involved but also the underlying governance issues in respect of these organizations. Replacing indi- vidual CEOs and/or Board members with appointees more favorable to reform is not enough. Only by addressing the governance of these organizations will enduring, systemic change become feasible. This involves assessing the gover- nance arrangements of the key SOEs in the sectors undergoing reform against principles similar to the ones set out in Part B. BOX 12.2 Reform in the Malagasy electricity industry When, after 5 years of political instability and declin- Deputy Director-General for Jirama via competitive ing economic performance, Madagascar returned to and transparent processes. New board members were stability in 2014, the electricity system was in a poor appointed, and a new Chairman elected in May 2017. state. Jirama, a vertically integrated state-owned util- Jirama’s new Board of Directors has developed ity governing Madagascar’s electricity sector faced a detailed job descriptions for all senior management deteriorating operational and financial situation. The positions, forming the basis of a competitive recruit- utility was unable to collect sufficient revenues to ment process launched in 2018 for all positions report- meet expenses and faced rising input costs, primarily ing directly to the Director-General. for imported fuel. Customers suffered frequent load Nonetheless, the reform’s success will depend shedding. upon continuing Government commitment. In the The country needed better sector management and short to medium term, this will largely involve sup- more investment. Political interference and an absence porting the new Board of Directors and senior man- of accountability, combined with a lack of sector plan- agement in overcoming the resistance of most existing ning, led to non-transparent, inefficient, and costly private-sector operators (who fear the loss of unduly decisions. For example, in responding to private com- profitable power purchase agreements) and address- panies offering to generate power, Jirama frequently ing excessive staffing levels while assuaging the unem- agreed to buy electricity at a price higher than what it ployment fears of union members. could sell it for. In the longer term, success will depend substan- To resolve these issues and promote private invest- tially on the Government’s ability to pass legislative ment in power generation, the Government, with sub- changes that can both improve Jirama’s governance stantial World Bank support, embarked on a major and strengthen the hand of the industry regulator, reform program in 2015–16. In the short term, the pro- ORE. More broadly, strengthening ORE’s authority gram aims to improve Jirama’s performance. The and financial resources will help, as it will underpin the Government appointed a new Energy Minister in development of a more open and competitive industry April 2017 and recruited a new Director-General and and spur Jirama to be effectively managed. Source: World Bank 2016. 104 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS Mobilizing consumers as pro-reform forces The beneficiaries of reform include many domestic consumers and businesses to whom telecommunications and electricity services, for example, are production inputs. Such clients typically stand to benefit from lower prices, greater reliabil- ity of supply and more innovative service offerings. Hence, it should be possible to mobilize significant support for reform from both these groups, although low-income customers typically fail to benefit in the short term and may require continuing subsidies for the purchase of electricity. A key requirement here is to communicate how and how much stakeholders will benefit from reform in ways that are readily understandable to them. These messages are likely to have greater credibility if it is explained to them why the reform process will lead to better outcomes. Attempts to mobilize stakeholder support should ideally commence as early as possible—that is, after a proposed reform program has been announced and prior to detailed reform design being undertaken. This is important because successful efforts to mobilize stakeholder support in these early stages will help change the political dynamics of reform, increasing the actual and expected benefits and reducing the costs. This will increase the likelihood that systematic reforms will be adopted in practice, rather than being abandoned or diluted as opposition is mounted by vested interests. The larger the pro-reform constituency mustered, the greater the political cost to governments of failing to carry through their reform proposals. One major complicating factor must be highlighted. This is that in post-­fragile contexts, reforms in some sectors often lead to significant price rises in the short to medium term. This usually happens if prices in a given sector have been set at artificially low levels for political reasons and price regulation is removed. For low-income consumers the prospect of significant price rises is a major concern, which can be used by vested interests to stir up feeling against reform. This can make the task of gathering support for the reform agenda from consum- ers challenging. However, given that during conflict many users may have paid more for intermittent, suboptimal services from informal service providers, they could well be more amenable to reforms than assumed. Potential strategies to engage these consumers include: • focusing on the benefits expected from reform, including reliability of service; • adopting measures to protect the interests of low-income consumers. In some cases, it may also be necessary to correct distorted regulated prices before the reform process begins in order to prevent reform being seen as the cause of the price rises and consequently being opposed by key groups. ENGAGING STAKEHOLDERS IN THE EVOLUTION OF REGULATORY POLICY In addition to seeking to enlist key stakeholders, including consumers and busi- ness users, as supporters of the reform process, it is essential to engage them in the design and development of the reforms. Ongoing stakeholder engagement, as outlined in chapter 9, is a key element in regulatory review and reform. However, the need for adequate stakeholder interaction is particularly acute in post-fragile countries. This is because a key Mobilizing and Engaging Pro-Reform Forces | 105 objective here is to obtain private (and largely foreign) investment to underpin the development of the system. Concerns about the quality of the regulatory environment often deter such investments. Thus, engaging with stakeholders to ensure their concerns are understood and that proposed reforms are supported is all-important in improving investment prospects. Stakeholder engagement should therefore start at an early stage in the devel- opment of the proposed reform program. This will help to ensure that its design reflects their priorities and concerns and will help create an attractive invest- ment environment. Such engagement should be sustained over time, with addi- tional opportunities for stakeholder input as the proposed regulatory scheme is developed in more detail. Engagement should also be a significant part of the ongoing policy review and revision process. For major regulatory reforms are rarely “one-off” pro- cesses. Instead, it is typically necessary to closely monitor and review the per- formance of the reforms to identify blockages and design further reforms to address these. Stakeholder engagement is likely to be at least as valuable in this “ex-post” context, in which investments have already been made and market participants can speak credibly about the conditions they face, the unantici- pated impacts of government policies as they relate to their investments, com- petition issues and other factors bearing on the ability of the reform to achieve its objectives. However, as in any consultation process, it is necessary to guard against spe- cific voices becoming unduly influential, potentially leading to capture. Developing formal mechanisms to undertake consultations and ensuring that the stakeholder engagement process is as open and transparent as possible con- stitute significant safeguards, as examined in chapter 9. In principle, stakeholder engagement during the policy review and revision process should be simply one element of a larger, continuing process. Box 12.3, BOX 12.3 Stakeholder engagement by the Georgian National Energy and Water Supply Regulatory Commission Georgia’s Law on Electricity and Natural Gas reduces the potential for regulatory capture and con- (LENG), requires a high degree of transparency in flicts of interest. GNEWSRC’s activities, as well as continuous stake- The LENG also establishes rules for meetings of holder engagement in relation to a wide range of the Commissioners and their employees with inter- GNEWSRC activities. The legislation requires that ested parties, with a Commissioner being required to GNEWSRC’s sessions, decisions, resolutions, orders, notify stakeholders in advance, and in writing, of con- minutes and documents are all available to the public sultations, and to provide them with an opportunity to and interested parties. This provides the basis for a take part. The LENG and the Law of Georgia on the very full engagement between the Commission, Conflict of Interest and Corruption in Public Service stakeholders and the public, since they have access also ban Commissioners and their staff from having not only to substantial information on the work of the any direct or indirect stake or economic interest in any Commission but also to the reasoning behind it. The licensee, importer, exporter, supplier or market oper- high level of transparency provided also greatly ation, or hold any positions in such enterprises. 106 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS below, highlights the approach taken to stakeholder engagement by the Georgian National Energy and Water Supply Regulatory Commission. Ensuring adequate stakeholder representation As suggested above, effective and credible stakeholder engagement requires consulting a wide range of interests and weighing their opinions. This is essen- tial to avoid regulatory capture by major stakeholders, and to assure that poli- cymakers benefit from all relevant inputs. Making certain that the consultation process is open to all interested parties is a basic requirement for credible engagement. However, a significant issue in many post-fragile contexts is that there may not be groups organized to repre- sent stakeholder interests or, where such groups exist, their membership and resources may be very limited. This implies a need for governments to consider providing active support for such groups, with the aim of encouraging their growth and ability to engage on policy and reform issues. It also underlines the importance of providing key information on reform plans and options in a clear, easy-to-understand form. Using the principles as the basis for stakeholder engagement The principles for the governance of regulators set out in chapter 9 can be a useful basis for structuring stakeholder engagement. The principles constitute a framework for reform proposals that clearly identify the underlying logic and purpose of the reform program. By receiving clear information about a reform’s rationale, stakeholders will be better able to assess the appropriateness and effectiveness of key reform elements and offer alternatives where needed. Transparency of the consultation process In addition to being open to the views of all parties, consultation processes must be transparent. Effective consultations provide complete information about which institutions and individuals have engaged and what opinions they have put forward. Wherever possible, submissions made during consultations should be published, as should summaries of meetings with stakeholders and the public. CONCLUSION Consultations provide a cost-effective way of identifying the strengths and weaknesses of reform proposals as well as of gathering any further information needed. They also help identify faulty reasoning and those parts of the pro- posal (and in some cases the entire proposal) that are likely to fail because unacceptable to major stakeholders. Any changes made can be incorporated in the final reform proposal. This chapter stressed the importance of mobilizing and engaging with pro-­ reform forces. It focused on the need to secure support in the public sector as well as from existing infrastructure providers and the public, emphasizing the need to guarantee adequate and effective representation from all major stake- holders at all stages. Mobilizing and Engaging Pro-Reform Forces | 107 REFERENCES BoKIR (Body of Knowledge on Infrastructure Regulation). 2019. “A Narrative: Developing and Improving Infrastructure Regulation in Fragile and Conflict-Affected States: Revitalizing and Reforming Regulatory Governance for Infrastructure in post-FCV Environments.” http://regulationbodyofknowledge.org/a-narrative-developing-and-improving​ -­infrastructure​-regulation-in-fragile-and-conflict-affected-states/. Lampietti, J. A., S. G. Banerjee, and A. Branczik. 2007. People and Power: Electricity Sector Reforms and the Poor in Europe and Central Asia. Washington, DC: World Bank. World Bank. 2016. “MG-Electricity Sector Operations and Governance Improvement Project (ESOGIP) (P151785).” Implementation Status and Results Report PAD1147, World Bank, Washington, DC. 13 Central Coordination of Reform INTRODUCTION The previous chapter argued that developing and implementing a robust reform proposal is challenging, with numerous vested interests acting to oppose and/or undermine change. Working to build and maintain coalitions of pro-reform forces can help address this dynamic, while formal engagement processes can help clarify, and apply scrutiny to, the arguments of those opposed to reform, and to counter these arguments effectively. Building support for reform requires communicating, monitoring and build- ing capacity within government as well as working and communicating with stakeholders outside government. Establishing a central coordinating body with cross-sectoral responsibilities related to the reform agenda can help: • consolidate and coordinate support for the reform agenda, including overall responsibility for the continuing engagement process; • promote efficiency, as many challenges to be addressed in implementing reform will be broadly similar across different sectors, or industries; • promote consistency, as the principles underlying the reform program will be similar across sectors. Giving oversight and coordination authority to a single body at the center of government helps to ensure the overall consistency of reform across sectors and to boost the reform agenda. ESTABLISHING A SPECIALIST BODY TO COORDINATE AND MONITOR REFORM Such a body is most appropriately located in a ministry at the center of govern- ment, with broad, “whole-of-government” coordination responsibilities. This is most likely a Prime Minister’s/President’s office or a Ministry of Finance, but could also be a separate Ministry for Infrastructure established for this purpose, as in Georgia, Kosovo, Madagascar and Rwanda (see box 13.1). Locating the reform body in a central ministry increases its authority and helps ensure that a broad view of key issues is taken. Establishing a separate Infrastructure Ministry, if it is provided with the leadership of a senior minister and appropriate resources, can do the same.  109 110 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS BOX 13.1 A ministry for reform coordination In Georgia, one of the most prominent members of following years, Georgia rose substantially in the the Government, the Minister for Economic World Bank’s Doing Business rankings, at 100 in Development, Khaka Bendukidze, was appointed as 2006, 37 in 2007 and 18 in 2008. Unfortunately, State Minister for Reform Coordination in 2004, while a wide-ranging program of regulatory reform with wide-ranging responsibilities embracing was adopted, it was not guided or coordinated by an reform of both the public sector and the regulatory explicit policy on systemic regulatory reform or gov- system. His appointment ensured that reform efforts ernance during this period. Thus, while responsibil- in different sectors were effectively integrated at the ity for reform was handed to a single, powerful political level and exercised by a Minister with minister, the absence of an explicit, overarching strong authority within the government. The reform strategy meant that there was no explicit Minister was supported by a new Office of the State policy to guide the design and implementation of Minister for Reform Coordination. During the consistent reform efforts. Key functions of a central reform body As suggested above, establishing a central reform body helps to promote consis- tent approaches to reform, while also lifting the profile of the reform agenda and strengthening it within government (see the example of Rwanda in box 13.2). The central reform body can contribute to these outcomes by undertaking a range of reform-related activities such as: 1. Advocacy Key to the central reform body’s role is promoting understanding of the benefits of reform, and the ways through which the reform of key infrastructure and other sectors will achieve wider benefits for society. This function should be undertaken both within government and externally. 2. Monitoring and feedback A central body responsible for individual regulators can take an independent view of reform progress and function as a source of unbiased advice to govern- ment about the performance of the reform agenda. This can contribute to more rapid identification of key problems and the development of effective solutions. 3. Capacity development Access to staff with relevant expertise is frequently a problem for newly estab- lished regulatory agencies, and one particularly acute in post-fragile environ- ments. A central coordinating body can help here in at least two ways. First, it can help provide training to ministries and regulatory agency staff and publish relevant materials and resources. Second, it can improve the ability of the civil service to recruit expert staff by undertaking recruitment centrally. DEVELOPING A REGULATORY GOVERNANCE POLICY FOR THE INFRASTRUCTURE SECTOR A key function of a central coordination body is to develop an explicit regulatory governance policy statement covering the entire infrastructure sector. Central Coordination of Reform | 111 BOX 13.2 The Rwanda Development Board—A central reform body to encourage private-sector investment The Rwanda Development Board (RDB) was formed in influential, the RDB reports directly to the President 2008 from the merger of eight different bodies. RDB and is guided by a board that includes all key ministers. brings together all government agencies responsible for RDB has managed to improve several areas related the investment environment, that is: Key agencies to the country’s investment climate. The country was responsible for business registration, investment a top reformer in the World Bank’s Doing Business promotion, environmental clearances, privatization; report in 2010 and 2014, and the country’s ranking and specialist agencies which support information and improved from 158 in 2007 to 41 in 2018. At the same communications technologies and tourism as well as time, the number of registered firms increased by small and medium enterprises and human capacity 24  percent between 2011 and 2014 and employed development in the private sector. Independent and 24 percent more workers. Sources: Rwanda Development Board Website (https://rdb.rw/); World Bank 2016, 2018. Infrastructure investments are typically characterized by large sunk costs, low mobility of assets, and site specificity, all of which mean they are vulnerable to sovereign risks due to major and unexpected changes in government policies. Hence, infrastructure investors assess the effectiveness and integrity of a coun- try’s legal and regulatory institutions as a vital part of their due diligence process. They are looking for governments and agencies that have a clear infrastructure strategy and that operate within a well-designed and effective legal and regula- tory system. This poses a major challenge for most fragile and post-fragile coun- tries, as they typically do not possess, or are only beginning to develop, clear infrastructure strategies and well-developed regulatory systems. In addition, major infrastructure assets have often been destroyed, badly damaged or neglected during the conflict, making the task of restarting investment urgent. Explicit policy statements that provide a broader framework for understand- ing the focus and priorities of the regulatory reform agendas being adopted are relatively common in developing countries. In some cases, such as that of Rwanda1 and Mauritius (Government of Mauritius 2007) the focus has been on elaborating sectoral plans. A still broader approach, addressing all infrastructure industries in a single policy statement, can potentially yield significantly greater benefits in terms of consistent, strategic ­ policy orientation and consequent increases in investor confidence. Such policies and plans are typically examined in detail by domestic and international investors considering buying into a country’s infrastructure net- works. In particular, such investors pay attention to a government’s expressed intentions in respect of private participation and the policy elements that sup- port them (or, conversely, which fail to do so, as, for example, in Tanzania [OECD 2013]). A well-developed policy and/or plan, maintained over the lifespan of sev- eral governments, clearly signals to investors that the country is committed to infrastructure development with private participation. However, many such policy statements fail to focus on the importance of developing and maintaining good regulatory systems for infrastructure 112 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS development. In Rwanda, for example, despite strong policies encouraging for- eign private infrastructure investment, none of the sector plans for infrastruc- ture listed on the Ministry of Infrastructure’s website mention regulatory governance p ­ olicy. Consistent feedback from actual and potential investors in many low-income and post-fragile countries indicates that the quality of the reg- ulatory system helps shape their view of the attractiveness of the investment environment. A regulatory policy within these plans can greatly improve their practical effectiveness and help attract investment. Elements of a regulatory governance policy statement for infrastructure sectors An infrastructure-specific regulatory governance policy statement should: 1. Focus on the organization, processes, tools and norms of interaction, deci- sion-making, monitoring and evaluation used by government organizations and their counterparts in the private sector. 2. Follow a sound strategic approach to infrastructure planning that reflects clear views of how the relevant industries are expected to develop over time and what the key objectives are in the short-, medium- and long-term. 3. Set out in broad terms the basic elements of the regulatory regime for infra- structure, specifying what regulatory agencies will be established and/or modified, with a clear allocation of roles between the institutions involved, providing a high degree of certainty for the various actors, while retaining a degree of flexibility to meet changing circumstances. 4. Encourage development, management and renewal of infrastructure that is sustainable and affordable. The need for flexibility is important if the aim is to make one or several infra- structure sectors more competitive for private investors. Indeed, the regulatory governance policy will have to vary, depending upon the government’s choice of delivery modes for infrastructure. What is appropriate for a system of state own- ership of infrastructure will differ from that needed for one increasingly domi- nated by public-private-partnerships, or one that is entirely privatized. The statement should specify the: • objectives of the regulatory governance policy statement for each infrastruc- ture sector in relation to the government’s infrastructure policy and plans, particularly its choice of delivery modes; • need to establish a small, expert advisory unit in the ministry responsible for infrastructure policy, with a description of its role, responsibilities and authority; • responsibilities and authority of the regulatory agency or agencies responsi- ble for infrastructure regulation; • principles of regulatory governance that will be applied to the infrastructure sector, including those examined in Part B of this manual; • requirement for periodic assessments of the performance of infrastructure sectors by the expert advisory unit where regulation has been recently reformed, and any recommendations for change. In addition, there should be a less frequent requirement for a regular, major report on the regulatory governance policy statement and the system put in place to implement that policy. Central Coordination of Reform | 113 A LONGER-TERM PERSPECTIVE—DEVELOPING A GOVERNMENT-WIDE REGULATORY POLICY A key medium-term benefit of an explicit infrastructure sector policy, ­ supported by a central coordinating body, is that it fosters a view of regulatory reform as a strategic activity taken across government, rather than a series of sector-specific initiatives. This broader view of regulation can help to pave the way for the development of a whole-of-government regulatory policy in the medium term. While such policies are rarely adopted in the post-fragile context, and are often not feasible in the short term, moving in this direction provides the basis for broadening and deepening the reform process and achieving significantly greater benefits. Adopting the above architecture in the context of infrastructure reform will cement several important steps that can form the foundations for a whole-of-­ government policy. In particular: • Developing a policy statement and coordinating approaches to regulatory reform on the basis of guiding principles (such as those elaborated in Part B), introduces key regulatory policy principles to major stakeholders, facilitating their acceptance. • A coordinated approach to infrastructure reform can help develop essential capacities within ministries and regulatory agencies. • Developing a track record of effective reform in the infrastructure sector, based on principles and approaches consistently applied by a central body, can help demonstrate the benefits of applying such pathways to the reform of govern- ment regulation more broadly. Thus, it will assist in helping to develop a con- stituency in favor of adopting a whole-of-government regulatory policy. The elaboration and implementation of a whole-of-government regulatory policy is largely beyond the scope of the current manual. However, given the importance of regulatory policy and the clear links with the subject of this chap- ter, an outline of some key considerations is provided in appendix C. CONCLUSION This chapter has argued the need for, and value of, a reform monitoring body at the center of government, guided by the development of a regulatory governance policy statement for the infrastructure sector. The next chapter examines the governance and individual capacity needed for successful reform. NOTE 1. http://www.mininfra.gov.rw/index.php?id=188. REFERENCES Government of Mauritius. 2007. Outline of Energy Policy 2007–2025: Towards A Coherent Strategy for the Development of the Energy Sector in Mauritius. Port-Louis: Ministry of Public 114 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS Utilities. http://publicutilities.govmu.org/English/publications/Documents/OUTLINE​ %20ENERGY%20POLICY.PDF. OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). 2013. OECD Investment Policy Reviews: Tanzania 2013. Paris: OECD Publishing. http://www.keepeek.com/Digital​ -Asset-Management/oecd/finance-and-investment/oecd-investment-policy-reviews​ -­tanzania-2013_9789264204348-en#.WjMXU1WWZIw#page151. World Bank. 2016. Rwanda Economic Update: Rwanda at Work. February 2016, Issue 9. Kigali: World Bank. ———. 2018. “Institutional Mechanisms for Business Environment Reforms.” Unpublished note. Indicator-Based Reform Advisory, World Bank, Washington, DC. 14 The Capacity for Reform of Regulatory Governance INTRODUCTION Chapter 13 described the value of establishing a reform monitoring body at the center of government, together with a regulatory policy for the infrastructure sector. Both constitute a valuable, ongoing resource to ensure maintenance of a high level of regulatory performance, providing an important part of the gover- nance capacity of the state. This chapter continues the emphasis on the need to establish or develop a capacity for reform and, with it, improved regulatory governance. The effective reform of any regulatory system requires that there is the capac- ity to undertake the work involved in the following four stages of the reform process: 1. Identifying and assessing strengths and weaknesses in the existing system or part of the system based on the use of the 10 principles discussed in Part B of this manual, or similar instruments. 2. Designing a strategy for reform, including an implementation plan, such as outlined in Part C. 3. Implementing the strategy for reform. 4. Monitoring and assessing ongoing regulatory performance. This chapter discusses the governance capacity needed in the enabling envi- ronment supporting the regulatory reform process as well as the capacity needed inside the regulator itself. The governance capacity needed at the level of the enabling environment relates to the quality of the roles, relationships and distribution of powers and responsibilities between the legislature, the minister, the ministry, the judiciary, the regulator and the regulated entities. Internal governance dimensions include the regulator’s organizational structures, standards of behavior, compliance and accountability, oversight of business processes, financial reporting and perfor- mance management. When an infrastructure sector or several infrastructure sectors undergo reform, both the external dimensions governing the process as well as the inter- nal dimensions must have sufficient capacity to ensure that the reform proceeds. This chapter evaluates the “external” and “internal” capacities needed.  115 116 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS WHOLE-OF-GOVERNMENT CAPACITY REQUIREMENTS FOR REGULATORY REFORM This section discusses “external” governance capacity requirements for regulatory reform, identifying what is needed from the government, including ­ regulatory agencies, supervising ministries and key actors in the infrastructure sector, representatives from regulated entities and consumers. The discussion of these requirements is laid out against the steps in the reform cycle. To ensure that there is sufficient external governance capacity to handle infrastructure reforms, different parts of government should be mobilized and involved in the process. Establishing a set of committees like those outlined below, together with an initial schedule of meetings (a major task, given the number and seniority of the persons involved), can help facilitate this process. Possible committees include: • Ministerial Coordination Committee (MCC). Could help ensure continuing political authority for the reforms and effective coordination. It could be chaired by the Prime Minister or President, or by the Treasurer/Minister of Finance. The Minister of Economic Development/Business Affairs and the Minister of Justice should also be members, as well as the supervising ministries and the Environment Ministry. Such a committee could help vet and approve the reform, providing a powerful focal point to drive assessment, strategy design and imple- mentation. The committee could also resolve ­differences between ministers and ministries and review any progress reports pertaining to the reform. • Reform Steering Committee (RSC). Could help coordinate the activities, expertise and support of numerous ministries and agencies involved in the reform process. This type of whole-of-government coordination is helpful in the entire reform process, but especially in the strategy design and implementation stages. Such a committee should be chaired by a very senior official, with a rep- resentative from each relevant ministry and agency who will also be responsible for liaising with their ministry or agency. The RSC would be the key body within the governance structure for the reform project. The functions of the committee would include approving the budgetary strategy, defining and realizing out- comes, monitoring risks, quality and timelines, making policy and resourcing decisions, and assessing requests for changes to the scope of the project. • Project Advisory Committee (PAC). Is helpful for large, multisector reforms with expert members drawn from top business associations, consumer associ- ations, universities and, where relevant, project donors. It would report to the RSC, acting as a conduit for expert advice and a feedback mechanism in rela- tion to progress, results and key problems arising. The Committee could also be useful in helping develop continuing support for, and commitment to, the reform project and wider regulatory reform in general. • Reform Unit (RU). A small RU led by an experienced manager, with admin- istrative support staff, would be heavily involved in the early stages of the reform—namely identifying any issues with an existing system of regulation and developing a reform strategy. Whole-of-government capacity needed for the first stage of reform The first stage of a reform process includes a detailed assessment of existing weaknesses in the system of regulatory governance. To conduct this assessment The Capacity for Reform of Regulatory Governance | 117 adequately, it is helpful to have a reform (or similar) unit, or a small team of indi- viduals with: • a thorough understanding of regulatory governance involves; • a thorough understanding of the infrastructure sector’s place in the national economy; • familiarity with the existing system of regulatory governance in the infra- structure sector; • the ability to use the 10 principles or similar instruments to assess strengths and weaknesses in the regulatory governance of the infrastructure sector, gained through training and previous experience in the application of the principles; • substantial experience in both desk-based research and field research, includ- ing interview skills. Experience and skill in developing and administering an opinion survey is also often required but can be contracted out to an expert in another government agency, or a private-sector consultant working under the supervision of a member of the unit; • substantial experience in strategy design and implementation planning; • high-level legal, economic, budgeting, accounting and auditing skills and experience; • experience in liaising with a range of ministries, agencies and regulated entities. In addition, the team will require the authority and resources to: • access the relevant records of the supervising ministries and regulatory agencies; • undertake a survey of the senior officials in the ministries, regulatory agen- cies and staff of regulated entities, as well as the general public; • interview a selection of senior officials in the ministries, regulatory agencies and staff of regulated entities. In fragile contexts it is likely that only a few persons will have the necessary qualifications. Where this is the case, one or more consultants should be recruited and major donor agencies such as the World Bank Group can be of assistance. However, it is important that local staff be drawn upon as far as possible and, where necessary, provided with relevant training before project startup. They can later act as a small core of experienced staff that can be drawn upon for a variety of regulatory reform projects, as well as to provide advice and training in regulatory reform for all government bodies. Whole-of-government capacity needed for the second stage of reform Capacity required to design the reform strategy varies according to: • Type and extent of the strengths and weaknesses identified in the first, assess- ment stage of the reform process. Where more weaknesses are identified, then more organizational and individual capacity will be needed to develop a strategy to address them. • Likely support for, and resistance to, reform from key actors in the infrastruc- ture regulatory system. In general, the greater the reform proposed, the greater resistance to the reform strategy. Hence, the latter should include consideration of how to deal with such resistance to ensure successful implementation. 118 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS Fragile countries have limited human and financial resources, so it is import- ant that the reform strategy developed is not overly ambitious and, ideally, is broken down into stages that can be modified in due course as resources become available and opportunities reveal themselves. It is particularly important that the human and financial resources necessary for each of the stages be identified. Where the reform demands human resources that are not available, appropriate training and/or recruitment processes should be outlined and agreed in the strategy. This stage of the reform process requires the active involvement of individu- als with significant strategic planning and budgeting experience, and ideally include people who were involved in the first stage of reform. The strategy should comprise a detailed implementation plan. In large-scale reforms the development of such a plan requires an RU team member with expe- rience of the development of government- sector implementation plans and the capacity to liaise effectively with the ministries and agencies involved. Also, given the need to gain approval from the highest level of government (e.g., at the ministerial level) someone active in the reform strategy development process should have significant, high-level, policy advocacy skills and experi- ence, and have sufficient credibility with ministers and senior officials. Whole-of-government capacity needed for the third stage of reform During reform implementation, the RU steps back and the relevant ministries and regulatory agencies involved take a more prominent role in accordance with the implementation plan. This phase presents three major challenges: 1. coordinating the range of actors and activities involved; 2. ensuring the necessary cooperation between different ministries and agen- cies, especially where substantial change is involved; 3. gaining the necessary, agreed feedback on implementation progress from ministries and regulatory agencies in good time. Capacity required to implement the reform strategy varies according to: • The extent and type of reforms to be implemented. For example, changes requiring significant drafting of existing legislation and regulation, the cre- ation of new legislation, the creation of new regulatory agencies, or the sub- stantial modification of existing agencies, will require considerable capacity spread across the RU, supervising ministries and regulatory agencies. • The number of levels of government involved. Where only one level of gov- ernment, for example, the national government, is involved, the capacity required is less than if individual federal state levels are also affected. • The number of ministries and regulatory agencies involved. • The implementation plan and schedule—a slower schedule, in general, will require less capacity because there is enough time to train members of the RU, ministries and regulatory agencies. At this stage it is vital that appropriate, planned, human and financial resources are available in the ministries and regulatory agencies. Since relatively few of the available staff are likely to have experience in reforming regulatory governance, prior training will be required. The Capacity for Reform of Regulatory Governance | 119 Whole-of-government capacity needed for the fourth stage of reform It is important that after completion of the reform project, the reform process should have the capacity to monitor and assess regulatory performance at the cabinet, ministry and agency levels. Monitoring and assessing a reform process requires: • monitoring the routine administration of the reformed activities at the minis- try and agency levels on the basis of agreed performance indicators; • providing advice and support, particularly training, to individuals and units in the ministries and regulatory agencies; • providing regular reports on regulatory performance to the minister and cab- inet, including proposals for further regulatory reforms. There also needs to be capacity, possibly in a reform or similar unit, to provide: • continuing advice as to the ongoing impact of infrastructure regulation; • a continuing source of external pressure for regulation and the need for reg- ulatory reform, encouraging transparency and accountability. REGULATOR CAPACITY REQUIREMENTS FOR REFORM The regulator is a key component of the system of regulatory governance and needs appropriate capacity to administer (i.e., manage and enforce) regulation effec- tively—and to do so in ways that steer the behavior of target groups, such as busi- nesses, public sector providers, consumers and citizens, that are consistent with public policy purposes. Moving from a situation where key infrastructure services (e.g., electricity, telecoms) are provided by a government monopoly to the estab- lishment of a competitive market necessarily gives rise to substantial challenges. The fact that sectoral reforms are usually implemented progressively, with com- petition spreading progressively through the various parts of the sector, means that the scale of the regulatory capacity challenge will continue to increase as time goes by. This means that a strategic approach is needed to ensure that existing regula- tory capacities are identified and leveraged effectively and that they are developed over time as the size of the regulatory task expands. The development of regulatory capacities is a crucial priority to support improved regulatory governance, while failure to address this issue can have significant negative implications. Identifying relevant capacities A fundamental requirement is that the regulator’s staff should have a clear understanding of the: • Technical realities of the regulated industry. Even in fragile contexts, these capacities are likely to be in reasonable supply, since they are also needed by ministries responsible for the supervision of government monopolies. However, regulating in a developing competitive market requires a range of skills, which go beyond those required in the monopoly context. • Principles of competition and their application in a regulatory context. Such skills are likely to be in short supply in the civil service in post-fragile countries, given that competition policies are often either yet to be adopted or only recently 120 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS implemented and competition authorities are, clearly, not well established, if at all. However, it may be possible to seek access to this expertise via academic institutions or via recruitment from the broader corporate sector. • Technical aspects of regulating a developing, competitive industry. This includes expertise in price regulation (or, in a more developed market, in price monitoring/approvals) and the associated issue of addressing community ser- vice obligations (i.e., ensuring that the poor are protected when undertaking tariff reform). As discussed in the next section, this is likely to be an area where the assistance of external bodies, such as donor organizations, in developing and implementing training programs can help develop the needed skills. The principles set out in Part B also emphasize the importance of establishing and maintaining systems of continuing stakeholder engagement. This is another area in which relevant expertise is needed to ensure effective implementation. Such skills are again likely to be in short supply in the civil service in post-fragile countries, suggesting the need to target other, relevant industries such as mar- keting and advertising to obtain access to the expertise required. Moreover, good organizational design and management are required to ensure that a “critical mass” is achieved. Recruiting and retaining staff A key challenge in many developing countries is that of recruiting and maintain- ing staff with relevant expertise. Particularly in contexts where people with the right skills are likely to be found outside the civil service, rigid recruitment and remunerations policies can be major barriers to regulators recruiting and retain- ing skilled staff. Given the strategic economic importance of ensuring good regulatory perfor- mance, seeking to include agency-specific staffing rules (e.g., offering higher sal- aries) within the governing statute of the regulator can be an effective way to address the capacity issue. For example, at the time of the establishment of Indonesia’s competition authority (the KPPU), agency-specific staffing and remu- neration rules were adopted to enable it to recruit and retain high-​ quality staff. Leveraging existing capacities A second set of capacity issues concerns the need to use scarce human resources effectively. One means of doing so, discussed briefly in Part B, is to favor the devel- opment of one or more multisectoral regulators, rather than sector-specific agen- cies. This option may be attractive where one infrastructure sector has already been reformed and an independent regulator established as part of this process. Where such a regulator has already developed expertise and experience, this can be leveraged by expanding its responsibilities to include a newly reformed sector. While some sector-specific expertise is necessarily required, many of the required regulatory capacities will be broadly transferable between sectors, meaning that regulatory staff who have already developed key skills and experience in one sec- tor can be deployed into the regulation of a newly reformed sector. This can pro- vide a core of expertise around which further staff development can be built. This dynamic will tend to make it more likely that expanding the remit of an existing regulator will yield better regulatory outcomes in the short term than establishing a new regulator. This dynamic is likely to be a key part of the The Capacity for Reform of Regulatory Governance | 121 explanation for the empirical finding, noted in Part B, that expanding the scope of an existing regulator to include a newly reformed sector is a common strategy in many countries (Jordana and Levi-Faur 2010). As suggested above, expanding the scope of an existing regulatory agency can facilitate capacity development by providing greater opportunities for staff with regulatory expertise to conduct internal training and mentoring of new recruits, particularly in a continuous and informal way. However, consideration should also be given to establishing training programs under the auspices of central gov- ernment agencies which use existing regulatory expertise to provide broader training opportunities across other elements of the civil service. The World Bank Body of Knowledge highlights the importance of “knowledge gaps” as con- straints on the implementation of infrastructure sector reforms in post-fragile contexts and argues that these limited professional capacities can be addressed by regulators “…organizing training, speaking at public meetings and via media, and hosting education events” (BoKIR 2019). As noted above, the task of identifying and developing necessary capacities is one which may be greatly facilitated by strategic input from donor organizations. World Bank research highlights the importance of a context-specific approach to regulatory reform in the fragile context in particular, but notes that this approach must be developed within the context of consistent principles: Regulation in FCSs [fragile and conflict-affected situations] is nonstandard, because motivations, specific goals and instruments, and institutional arrange- ments must be peculiar to the unique circumstances of each FCS. No standard model exists for FCS, but clearly laid out principles of how institutions and businesses function, stakeholder engagements, and basic strategies appear to consistently improve outcomes. (BoKir 2019) In this context, a collaborative approach with key international organizations may help to ensure that training is both tailored to the specific needs of the indi- vidual post-fragile context and reflective of sound regulatory principles, such as those outlined in this manual. Importantly, donor bodies can help to identify key capacity gaps and mobilize specialist expertise to address these via targeted training programs. BUILDING GOVERNANCE CAPACITIES FOR REFORM OVER TIME As regulatory reform programs progress, the nature and extent of the regulatory capacities required for successful implementation will continue to change and increase. Thus, the provision of capacity development programs must be a con- tinuing process and should involve both identifying available external sources of training and developing tailored training programs within government. A key source in the former category is that of programs provided by major donor bodies. For example, the World Bank has a well-establish International Training Program on Utility Regulation and Strategy, which provides intensive training aiming at enhancing economic, technical and policy skills for managing regulatory reform in the infrastructure context, as well as providing a forum for international exchange of ideas and experiences.1 Where tailored training is to be developed and provided within government, this should be guided by ongoing monitoring of performance and key capacity 122 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS gaps. Again, external bodies may be able to assist in the diagnosis of major capac- ity issues and the design of appropriate programs to address them. Communities of practice One important mechanism in addressing these capacity development needs is participation in regional “communities of practice,” which bring together infra- structure regulators from a range of similar countries. The broader role of these organizations is discussed in chapter 16. However, a key benefit of participating in them lies in the opportunity they provide to leverage expertise for key capac- ity development initiatives, by delivering seminars and longer-form training pro- grams to regulators from a number of participating countries. This can enhance opportunities to benefit from knowledge transfer from academics, donor organi- zations and the like. For example, since 2007, the East Asia Pacific Infrastructure Regulatory Forum has developed a core training program on the economics of infrastructure regulation, which is aimed at mid-level regulatory staff, as well as training on advanced topics for higher-level staff. Other specific training topics include pub- lic-private partnerships, stakeholder consultation, competition policy, and qual- ity of service. Berg and Horrell (2008) highlight the fact that many regional communities of practice partner with academic institutions to provide struc- tured training tailored to the needs of their member regulators. The authors note that a broader role of regional regulator networks in this regard can be to share information about the cost-effectiveness of different training programs and the quality of support materials. The opportunity to share experiences and lessons through subsequent inter- actions via the communities of practice can also help to consolidate lessons and deepen learning. The community of practice model can also potentially be used to identify mutual assistance opportunities. For example, one member country that has made recent progress in developing expertise in a particular area may agree to provide training assistance to another member facing similar challenges. The community of practice model can also be developed on a domestic basis. This is particularly common in federal countries, where much regulation is undertaken at subnational level, so there are often several regulators covering a particular sector within the same country.2 However, this model can also be adopted in unitary countries. Where there are several, sector-specific regulators with responsibilities for infrastructure regulation, the development of such a forum or association can provide another mechanism for leveraging scarce reg- ulatory capacities, enabling knowledge and experience to be shared, key issues to be discussed and approaches to high-level regulatory issues to be coordinated. Another form of capacity-building program identified by the World Bank focuses on engagement between the regulator and a range of stakeholders to help develop a shared understanding of the views, priorities and objectives of different stakeholders (BoKIR 2019). Initiatives in these areas can help to improve communications between regulators and regulated entities and enhance the predictability of regulatory decisions by providing industry participants with a better understanding of regulators’ priorities and perspectives. The Capacity for Reform of Regulatory Governance | 123 CONCLUSION This chapter highlighted the capacities needed within the system of regulatory governance, or the “external” dimensions of regulatory governance, highlighting the various structures that should be in place to ensure that a reform has the support to proceed. It also highlighted the capacities needed within the regula- tor itself, or the “internal” dimensions of governance to manage a reform pro- cess. It closed with a discussion of the need to adopt strategies to develop and expand regulatory capacities, starting at an early stage of the reform process. These strategies should identify relevant external sources of training and capac- ity development, as well as developing means of leveraging existing capacities as effectively as possible. Capacity development should remain a key concern of reform policy in the longer term, since the role of regulators generally develops and changes over time with reform implementation and the advent of more com- petitive markets. The next chapter addresses the need to develop a reform strategy and key challenges in its implementation. NOTES 1. See, for example: https:// bear.warrington.ufl.edu/centers/purc/docs//PAPERS​ /­TRAINING/ITP/Program_Brochure.pdf. 2. For example, Australia’s Utility Regulators’ Forum was established in 1997 to encourage cooperation between utility regulators. It aims to facilitate information exchange and the development of shared understandings of regulatory issues, promote more consistent reg- ulatory approaches and provide a forum for discussion of new ideas about regulatory prac- tices. See: https://www.accc.gov.au/about-us/consultative-committees/utility​ -regulators​ -forum. REFERENCES Berg, S., and J. Horrell. 2008. ”Networks of Regulatory Agencies as Regional Public Goods: Improving Infrastructure Performance.” Review of International Organizations 3 (2): 179–200. BoKIR (Body of Knowledge on Infrastructure Regulation). 2019. “A Narrative: Developing and Improving Infrastructure Regulation in Fragile and Conflict-Affected States: Revitalizing and Reforming Regulatory Governance for Infrastructure in post-FCV Environments.” h t t p : // r e g u l a t i o n b o d y o f k n o w l e d g e . o r g / a - n a r r a t i v e - d e v e l o p i n g - a n d​ -improving-infrastructure-regulation-in-fragile-and-conflict-affected-states/. Jordana, J., and D. Levi-Faur. 2010. “Exploring Trends and Variations in Agency Scope.” Competition and Regulation in Network Industries 11 (4): 342–60. 15 Developing a Strategy for Reform and Putting It Into Practice INTRODUCTION Part B provided detailed guidance on evaluating the strengths and weaknesses of existing systems of regulatory governance in relation to each of 10 principles. Chapter 12 outlined the need to make the case for reform among stakeholders within and outside government and mobilize support for the reform agenda for infrastructure regulation. Chapter 13 highlighted the potential benefits of establishing a dedicated coordination body at the center of government to pro- ­ mote, facilitate and monitor reform and respond to identified issues in the imple- mentation program. It also discusses the benefits of having an explicit reform policy covering a range of infrastructure sectors. Chapter 14 outlined the need to ensure that the capacity required for effective reform was in place. Each of these factors is an important element in the development of a reform program. This chapter addresses the next step, which is to develop and execute a strat- egy to improve regulatory governance in one or more infrastructure sectors. It draws upon the evaluation advice provided in Part B and provides examples. The development of a strategy is important because it: • Helps ensure that all relevant factors are taken into consideration in an orga- nized and effective fashion when working to implement government policy decisions, especially when they involve substantial institutional and market change. • Enables the relevant minister and/or the cabinet to make an informed judg- ment about whether and how to proceed in light of the risks involved and the resources required. • Helps ensure the desired outputs and outcomes are delivered by making it clear who has responsibility for doing what, when and how. As noted above, constraints such as lack of political support and technical capacities may mean that the scope of the reform program may be limited in the immediate term. However, major reform, leading to the creation of competitive infrastructure sectors that are effectively regulated by a competent, adequately resourced independent regulator must remain the longer-term goal. This means that the strategy should be based on identifying a coherent reform process that takes account of current constraints and provides a sound basis from which to move toward a comprehensive reform outcome.  125 126 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS Any strategy adopted needs flexibility to respond to unforeseen challenges and opportunities. A change of government, for example, might bring with it a president or prime minister strongly committed to regulatory reform, providing an opportunity to deepen and/or accelerate the pace of reform, or again achieve a particular, strategic reform outcome previously blocked. Similarly, sudden eco- nomic crises such as those experienced by several states following the global financial crisis, confront governments with the need to develop and implement new policies. In this type of situation, accelerating a strategy of regulatory reform as one element of crisis response could make sense. Having a long-term, regula- tory governance reform program in place means that there is a clearly defined reform path as well as a set of objectives that can be drawn upon to respond to opportunities and challenges as they arise. STAGING REFORM As the above suggests, a threshold issue is whether reform is most likely to suc- ceed if implemented as a series of distinct stages, or whether an immediate move toward a competitive industry regulated by an independent entity is feasible and appropriate. A “one-off” reform process has the potential benefit of reducing opportuni- ties for reform to be undermined, delayed and/or reversed by opponents. Conversely, legislating to establish a fully disaggregated infrastructure ­sector, with open entry for competitors and an independent regulator, may cause substantial short-term problems in many post-fragile environments. For exam- ­ ple, where the financial position of the incumbent is poor and its ability to invest limited, it may be largely prevented from competing effectively. In practice, varying approaches may be adopted in different infrastructure sec- tors, reflecting the practical differences in the technical and economic environ- ments between sectors. Thus, for example, reform has frequently progressed more quickly in the telecommunications sector than in the electricity sector. This reflects the fact that the size of the investment required is typically s ­ ubstantially smaller, and the time required to develop new assets and infrastructure typically much shorter. The dominance of wireless infrastructure for voice telephony and, increasingly, internet access, has been a significant factor in this regard, enabling competitive markets to develop quickly and favoring rapid reform. Conversely, establishing workable competition in the electricity sector is frequently found to be a longer-term and more challenging process. While a starting point of vertically integrated government monopolists is common in both sectors, an important difference is that electricity tariffs are frequently not cost-reflective in post-fragile (and other low-income country) environ- ments, with incumbent electricity providers often in financially precarious positions and reliant on substantial subsidies from the budget sector. Other distortions also frequently exist, notably including major cross-subsidies between different consumer groups (e.g., households vs. business, or different types of commercial users). These different starting points for reform can have major implications for reform strategy. For example, some key reform elements can have perverse effects where basic problems exist such as pricing which is not cost-reflective. In  Kosovo, vertical separation of the electricity industry has apparently increased the financial pressure on the electricity-generating utility (see box 15.1). Developing a Strategy for Reform and Putting It Into Practice | 127 This reflects the fact that vertical separation has led to cost increases that have not been offset by efficiency gains in downstream sectors, due to a lack of effec- tive competition. At the same time, there is no longer any possibility of cross-­ subsidizing between the different elements of electricity supply. Strategically, a key problem in moving rapidly to reform the electricity sector in such contexts is that price increases are likely to be seen as the product of reform, rather than as reflecting the removal of artificial pricing underpinned by non-transparent subsidies. In such situations, opposition to reform is likely to develop quickly. This implies there may be substantial benefits in staging reform by addressing key governance issues in relation to the incumbent monopolist before undertaking market restructuring. For example, moves to make prices cost-reflective can be combined with the adoption of explicit subsidies to protect the position of priority groups such as low-income households. At the same time, working to improve governance and accountability within the incumbent electricity authority should help to achieve cost reductions due to efficiency gains and reductions in corruption and in eco- nomic losses, thus paring the size of the necessary subsidies. Corporatizing the incumbent, including adopting functional separation of key activities (i.e., gener- ation, transmission, distribution, retail) can also provide a sound basis for future disaggregation and privatization of elements of the system, together with the introduction of market rules to enable competition. BOX 15.1 Electricity reform in Kosovo Kosovo has undertaken a rapid unbundling of its gov- legislation was adopted “partially in compliance with” ernment-owned electricity monopoly. It started in three electricity-related EU directives. The broader 2008 with the separation of generation and distribu- goal of eventual accession to the Energy Community tion functions and was essentially completed by 2016. itself was also a significant factor driving the reform The government continues to own the electricity program. ­ generator, KEK, while the assembly has taken the However, some industry participants have argued ownership interest in the transmission-system opera- that the disaggregation of the electricity sector was tor, KOSTT. The distribution system operator KEDS premature and cost-increasing. They cite limited pros- was unbundled from supply activities in January 2015 pects of short-term entry into the generation and retail and the supply operator KESCO has been privatized. sectors in such a small market, while the substantial A major package of laws including the Law on Energy, financial weakness of the incumbent generation entity Law on Electricity and the Law on the Energy was compounded by this move, particularly in a con- Regulator was adopted in 2016. The early adoption of text in which key retail prices continue to be regulated this reform was driven by a strong determination to while upstream prices are not. Thus, while  the achieve an industry and regulatory structure consis- government adopted a full-scale reform for the sector, ­ tent with the European Union’s Acquis Communautaire ­ complete with unbundling and an independent regula- so as to participate eventually in the Energ y tor, market participants seem to suggest that the scale Community—facilitating regional integration of elec- and scope of the reforms was excessive. Delaying tricity networks, with potentially significant eco- the implementation of these changes and adopting a nomic gains.a This fact is noted explicitly in Article 1 more staggered approach could arguably have avoided of  the Law on Electricity, which states that the placing additional stresses on the sector. a. Energy Community 2017. 128 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS A key consideration is that the role and functions of the regulator, and the legislation under which it operates, are appropriate to the structure and the capacity of the sector at each stage of the process. Box 15.1 highlights a case in which rapid changes in the legislative framework have been undertaken, giving rise to concerns regarding the short- to medium-term impact on the industry. Scanning the environment As part of the development of the reform strategy, conducting a detailed scan of the political, economic, social and legal environments will help to identify phe- nomena that might impact, positively or negatively, on the implementation of the program. This information can then be used to help design the reform program itself. The self-assessment tool available at the World Bank’s Body of Knowledge on Infrastructure Regulation,1 portal provides a useful checklist for scanning the environment and identifying relevant factors. These can be assessed for their likely impact on each of the core principles of regulation examined in Part B of the manual, as illustrated in box 15.2. This environmental scan should be repeated periodically, as key elements are likely to change over time, requiring reconsideration of aspects of the reform program in order to respond to new opportunities or address key threats. The concept of the “policy cycle” implies that, as a general rule, major policy initia- tives should be subject to regular review and reassessment. This is particularly important in the context of infrastructure sector reform, which constitutes a major paradigm shift in government policy in most post-fragile contexts. As the aforementioned discussion on mobilizing stakeholder support under- lines, it is important to engage key partners in the scanning process, especially where those developing the implementation plan lack expertise as regards one or more of the infrastructure sectors. The above checklist can function as a use- ful vehicle for this engagement: stakeholder group representatives can be asked to complete the self-assessment checklist and the environment scanning/princi- ples of regulation matrix, the responses compared and analyzed, and follow-up meetings with groups of stakeholder representatives used to explore the find- ings and develop an overall perspective. This is particularly important where the process reveals significant differences in stakeholder views. BOX 15.2 Scanning and principles of regulation matrix THE CORE PRINCIPLES OF REGULATION FACTORS IDENTIFIED IN THE SCANNING PROCESS P1 P2 P3 P4 P5 P6 P7 P8 P9 P10 Economic + 0 0 − + − − − − + Political + − − − + 0 0 0 + 0 Social 0 − − − 0 − + 0 + 0 Law and Justice − − + + + 0 0 − + − Governance 0 − + + + 0 0 0 + − Other − 0 + + + 0 0 0 + + Note: P = principle of regulation; + = supportive of reform; 0 = neutral; − = challenge to reform. Developing a Strategy for Reform and Putting It Into Practice | 129 As well as helping improve the performance of the plan by drawing on avail- able expertise, this engagement process can: • help ensure a continuing awareness of the progress of the reforms embodied in the plan among all stakeholders; • provide an opportunity to enhance consensus on the need for the reforms among those likely to be affected, helping to legitimize the government’s plan; • promote “ownership” of the plan and its reforms. Selecting and training the implementation team A major reform program requires a small implementation team of persons with experience in regulatory policy, infrastructure operations and/or regulation and large-scale project implementation. The team should be, or become, an essential part of the reform monitoring unit described above. As expertise in these areas is likely to be in particularly short supply in fragile and post-fragile countries, the selection and the training of officials for the implementation team is a key chal- lenge. Given the strategic importance of this group to the policy’s success, the assistance of experts from major donor agencies such as the World Bank Group should be sought where possible in selecting and training team members and providing continuous advice and assistance. Organization and governance Governance arrangements for the implementation of the policy, including the design and functions of key organizations, should be established in the early stages of the project, in consultation with key stakeholders. The arrangements will provide an essential framework to support those responsible for the imple- mentation of the plan. Given the duration of the project, governance arrange- ments should be reviewed and adjusted at scheduled points, especially where there is a change in senior members of the implementation team. The following section provides examples of the organization of the key units and members of the bodies involved in a reform plan. Substantial, ongoing political commitment is needed to ensure the success of projects of this nature. This suggests, as indicated in chapter 14, the need for a standing Ministerial Coordination Committee to ensure both continuing politi- cal authority for the reforms and effective coordination. The Ministerial Coordination Committee (MCC) could be chaired by the Prime Minister or President, or by the Treasurer/Minister of Finance. The Minister of Economic Development/Business Affairs and the Minister of Justice should also be mem- bers. In a federal state, the MCC might also include the prime ministers of each federal state. In addition, it would be valuable to have a standing “Stakeholder Advisory Group,” reporting to the MCC, acting as a conduit for expert advice and a feedback mechanism in relation to progress, results and key problems arising. Appropriate functions of an MCC include: • vetting and approving major new policy initiatives in relation to regulation, thus providing a powerful focal point to drive implementation and reform; • reviewing progress reports in relation to regulation and regulatory policy; • endorsing ministry action plans to reduce administrative burdens on ­business; and • monitoring progress and assessing the need for modifications to the plan. 130 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS Developing the first draft of the detailed reform plan The content and layout of the detailed plan will vary from country to country, depending on the extent and type of regulatory policy to be established, and the local requirements for major submissions to the cabinet or the equivalent body. However, in all cases the following items should be included: • a summary that clearly relates the regulatory policy to existing government objectives, policies and plans concerning the infrastructure sector, explaining how regulatory policy will contribute to their achievement; • a brief description of the regulatory policy and each of the planned reforms (the deliverables) that it contains. This should focus on the need for a small, expert unit working under a senior minister to drive, coordinate and implement the policy, with an advocacy and training role. It should also examine the role and importance of assessments of proposed regulation; • a statement of the priority to be given to each reform, with an estimate of the expected costs and benefits, and the expected risks involved; • identification of groups that can be expected to support or oppose each key reform; • a list of the major stages, activities and timelines in the reform plan, noting the deliverable(s) to be achieved at each stage and the key milestones; • description of the roles and decision-making responsibilities of each key ­person or group, together with the hierarchy of authority, accompanied by an organigram. Integrating the regulatory policy into established policy processes If the processes associated with the regulatory policy are not integrated with established policy processes, they will tend to be regarded by line departments and agencies as an “add on,” something imposed on them from the center of government. Integration is a long-term process that should begin by ensuring that senior officials have a thorough understanding of what is involved in imple- menting the principles underlying the regulatory policy within their depart- ments and agencies. It is also useful to highlight successes and the benefits this can bring to the departments and agencies involved. PUTTING THE PLAN INTO PRACTICE Assigning authority and responsibilities As discussed above, implementing key reforms is a long-term process, in which monitoring results, identifying possible policy modifications to address key problems and looking for opportunities to expand the breadth and depth of the reforms are key elements. At the same time, opposition to the reform process can be expected from a variety of vested interests. All these factors point to the need for a clear allocation of political and admin- istrative responsibility for the implementation of reform, preferably to a coordi- nating body at the center of government, as discussed in the previous chapter. In addition, it is essential that those with responsibility have adequate resources to support continuing policy implementation and development. Developing a Strategy for Reform and Putting It Into Practice | 131 Designating a senior minister Allocating specific responsibility for the reform program to a senior minister will help to ensure that it is seen as having political support and authority and ensure that the reform policy has an advocate in cabinet and political debate. The likelihood of significant opposition makes it important that a top-ranking minister is given political responsibility. The main risk in making an individual minister responsible is that he or she may be isolated from other cabinet mem- bers in supporting the policy. This can suggest broadening responsibility some- what through the establishment of a cabinet committee or other structure. Conversely, having reform responsibilities split between different ministers can undercut the effectiveness of political advocacy. Establishing a reform monitoring, support and coordination unit within the administration2 As noted above, ensuring that there is a champion of regulatory policy and reform within the administration has several important benefits. At a basic level it helps to ensure consistency. While changes of government (or within government) may mean that the minister responsible for the policy is frequently replaced, the exis- tence of an administrative body with policy coordination functions helps ensure that a body of knowledge and experience can be developed and maintained over time. A model that has been adopted in some countries, like the Business Environment Delivery Unit in Kenya described in box 15.3, involves broadening the scope and expertise of the reform monitoring and oversight body by appoint- ing a board to direct its operations. This can include—and indeed can often be dominated by—appointees from outside government. The approach can be useful in the post-fragile context as a means of both addressing capacity constraints and improving accountability for achievement of reform objectives. Members can be drawn from academic institutions, industry and consumer or citizen groups, etc. The coordination function performed by such a unit can be particularly import- ant in implementing major sectoral reforms in post-fragile contexts, where several ministries often have responsibilities with significant influence on reform imple- mentation. For example, until recently foreigners seeking to invest in hydro-elec- tricity generation in Nepal needed licenses issued by the Ministry of Energy, while many license-related functions were dispensed by the Ministry of Electricity Supply, and water supply fell under the authority of the Ministry for Water Resources. Moreover, the Ministry of Finance had responsibility for the tax treat- ment of investments in the sector and ruled in relation to repatriation of profits. Another approach to coordination, adopted in Nepal’s 2017 National Electricity Regulatory Commission Act, is to require representatives of a range of ministries with key interests (in this case including the Ministry of Finance, the Ministry of Energy and the Ministry of Water resources, as well as the Executive Director of the NEA and key external resources) to be represented on the board of the independent regulator. However, as noted in Part B, there are disadvantages in placing civil servants on boards. Reform units can also help to improve understanding of the reform agenda’s purpose and rationale throughout the administration and improve capacities over time, both by promoting the reform generally and by providing specific training to officials on key issues. Such bodies can also function as internal con- sultancies, helping to provide expertise to ministries engaged in essential reform tasks. Importantly, such bodies ensure that there is a strong and consistent 132 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS BOX 15.3 The Kenyan Business Regulatory Reform Unit Kenya established the Business Regulatory Reform Development. This was a less powerful location in Unit (BRRU) in 2007 as part of a broad regulatory that it was not at the center of government. However, reform that initially focused on reorganizing business the structure of the BEDU included representatives regulations and, in particular, license, permit and certi- from all ministries, as well as private-sector experts. fication systems. The BRRU was located at the Ministry In addition, it was required to develop performance of Finance, ensuring that it had strong authority within indicators to measure the contributions of each minis- the administration and access to senior ministers. It try to regulatory improvement. These measures was given a range of high-level functions, including sought to make the improvement of regulatory “keeping track of all regulatory regimes” and liaising arrangements a shared responsibility across govern- with regulators to conduct Regulatory Impact ment, while also enabling the reform body to benefit Assessments (RIA). The government noted that a key from the knowledge of key experts from outside the reason for creating the BRRU was the need to institu- administration. tionalize these reforms within its wider regulatory Notably, the reform of business licenses and per- reform strategy and ensure that gains were not eroded mits was identified as a key challenge for the new over time by “creeping reregulation.” BEDU—even though license reform had been a central The BRRU was reconstituted in 2014 as the element of BRRU’s remit 7 years earlier. This high- Business Environment Delivery Unit (BEDU), within lights the fact that even quite specific regulatory the Department of Industrialization and Enterprise changes can be challenging and time-consuming. pro-reform voice inside the government. This function is likely to be particularly important during the implementation of major reforms, as these often provokes strong opposition from vested interests. Monitoring and evaluating progress against milestones Because implementing major reform is a medium-/long-term process, progress must be monitored regularly against milestones. These should be established in the implementation plan, early in the reform process, and should reflect a realistic pathway toward the achievement of the ultimate goals of the reform program. The main purpose of undertaking regular monitoring and evaluation of prog- ress is to identify in good time when outcomes are falling short of expectations and to determine why. This includes: • identifying unanticipated impacts of the strategy; • identifying unexpected impediments to the achievement of key goals; and • identifying institutional problems, such as situations in which reforms are consistently blocked by opposition from particular public bodies. It is unlikely that a completely fit-for-purpose reform path can be designed and legislated at the beginning of the reform process. This means policymakers must continuously subject the reform program to critical scrutiny during its implementation and be ready to modify it to ensure it can meet its objectives. That said, frequent, major changes to policies and legislation can have their own costs, particularly as they can give rise to uncertainty and associated plan- ning difficulties on the part of investors. Foreign investors, who are less famil- iar with the government and economic environment in a country, may be most affected. These issues, and the means of minimizing negative impacts, are Developing a Strategy for Reform and Putting It Into Practice | 133 discussed in chapter 16, which addresses the need for policy commitment and stability. As suggested above, a regulatory monitoring unit frequently oversees the pro- cess of monitoring and measuring reform policy performance. Allocating responsibilities to such a body has important benefits. Importantly, it is more likely to take a whole-of-government perspective in assessing progress. This can be important where the reform policy has multiple objectives which entail trade-offs and even conflicts. For example, policy reform in the electricity sector is likely to aim to expand generation and access to electricity on the one hand, while maintaining affordable tariffs on the other. Similarly, a regulatory monitoring unit with broad governance responsibilities is more likely to identify governance problems in key bodies responsible for sectoral reform policies (e.g., independent or arm’s-length regulators). They are also more liable to advocate for needed changes than are the ministries to which these bodies report. This role can be reinforced if a board structure, involving members from a range of non-government backgrounds, is adopted as part of the management. Conducting the review process As suggested above, reviews should be conducted by an appointed body that has sufficient expertise and is, as far as possible, at arm’s length from the reform policy subject to review. As noted, the review should benchmark performance against criteria that were identified and agreed when (or soon after) the reform policy was adopted. The review process should be as open as possible and should, at the very least, require significant consultations with a range of stakeholders. Responding to the conclusions Ensuring that the results of the evaluation are reported widely—ideally, pub- lished for general consumption—can help to mobilize support for needed changes. Thus, governance arrangements in respect of the reform policy should include requirements—possibly legislated—for the publication of progress reports and for formal responses to them to be published by government. Providing for parliamentary scrutiny and debate is also likely to create additional pressure for policy responses to be widely discussed and adopted. External reviews While the above describes a series of good practices in reviewing the ongoing implementation of reform programs, it is clear that policy review is a systemati- cally under-resourced activity in most countries—both developed and develop- ing. There are clear political disincentives to thoroughgoing reviews being undertaken in most contexts, with governments reluctant to be confronted with—and bear the political cost of—the failures of past and present policies. Recognizing this suggests that a key strategic step can be to encourage, or create circumstances, in which external reviews will be conducted. Where sig- nificant resources have been provided by donor organizations to assist in the implementation of reform, formal review of the outcomes achieved will often be a requirement. Inviting engagement with the reform program by such organiza- tions can thus be a useful means of ensuring that reviews are undertaken, as well as making sure that assessments are made by disinterested parties. There may also be opportunities for reform bodies within governments to work with donor organizations to see to it that the timing and focus of such reviews are as favor- able as possible to the long-term development of the reform program. 134 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS Modifying the strategy on the basis of regular evaluations Where performance reviews show that little progress is being made toward the goals set for the regulatory reform program, a credible response is needed to maintain (or, arguably, to restore) the confidence of the public and key stake- holders that reform outcome will be achieved. This highlights the importance of a thorough, analytically robust and transparent review process. Stakeholders must be able to understand the key problems responsible for lack of progress and be confident the proposed policy changes can resolve them. At the same time, making substantial change to a previously announced, long- term policy can give rise to perceptions of “sovereign risk” among investors if these changes can potentially damage their interests. Thus, the way in which changes to the policy are developed, announced and implemented must be con- sidered carefully, to minimize such risks. Key issues in this regard include con- sultation, the timing of changes, and the communication of their expected impact. As discussed in chapter 13, governments may, in any case, need to weigh the costs of a perceived lack of policy commitment against the benefits of changes that are expected to improve reform outcomes. Opportunities to advance reform While the above has focused on the issue of unanticipated problems of imple- mentation in reform programs, reformers should also be alert to the possibilities of making significant steps forward in a multi-stage reform process should favor- able opportunities arise. For example, a change of government, or of the minister responsible, may provide the opportunity to move forward more quickly, as was the case in Georgia in 2003–04 (see box 15.4). BOX 15.4 The Rose Revolution as an opportunity for reform As noted by the World Bank, the initial regulatory the Shevardnadze Government, was elected President reforms put in place or proposed by the Georgian in January 2004, during the “Rose Revolution,” on a government of President Eduard Shevardnadze strong anti-corruption platform, with approximately during and after 1995 had, by 2003, sputtered to a 96 percent of the vote. The new Saakashvili halt and Georgia was a near-failed state. Political Government took immediate advantage of the public’s power was increasingly fragmented, corruption and demand for reform and proceeded to rapidly put in crime rampant, there were massive arrears in place a wide range of regulatory reforms, set out in its pension payments and teacher’s salaries, and Economic Development and Poverty Reduction infrastructure was in a state of near collapse. Most of Program (EDPRP), linked to the UN’s Millennium the country lacked power and the road network Declaration. The reforms focused on the creation of a increasingly deteriorated. There was mounting market economy, with rapid deregulation, public opposition to President Shevardnadze and privatization and a dramatic reduction in the size of many reforms stalled in the face of growing the public service (for relevant details see IMF parliamentary opposition to his rule. 2003b). Energy, transport and communications were After a period of increasing civil unrest, Mikhail identified as key sectors for reform (Macfarlane Saakashvili, who had been the Minister of Justice in 2013). Developing a Strategy for Reform and Putting It Into Practice | 135 Another source of opportunities can be the involvement of donor organiza- tions. For example, efforts to create an independent regulator in the electricity sector in Nepal had been unsuccessful for well over a decade prior to the pros- pect of the US-based Millennium Challenge Corporation making a major invest- ment. Millennium Challenge sought the establishment of a credible, independent regulatory body as a prerequisite for its investment, being convinced that this was a key element in ensuring a successful outcome. Pro-reform forces were thus able to develop and implement legislation quickly, due largely to this oppor- tunity arising from abroad. In some situations, the disappointing performance of an initial reform initia- tive may be used as an argument in favor of moving quickly to adopt bolder reforms that were initially seen as belonging to a later stage in the reform process. CONCLUSION This chapter has outlined key issues in developing and putting into practice a strategy to improve regulatory governance in one or more infrastructure sectors. The next chapter examines how to maintain that strategy over time, regularly evaluating its performance and modifying it as circumstances change. NOTES 1. See http://regulationbodyofknowledge.org/self-assessment-tool/#/home for a copy of the self-assessment tool, as developed by the Public-Private Infrastructure Advisory Facility (PPIAF), the World Bank, and the Public Utility Research Center at the University of Florida. 2. Allocating responsibility to a specific Minister and establishing an oversight body for the regulatory policy are consistent with the 2012 OECD Council Recommendation on regula- tory policy, which states the governments should “establish mechanisms and institutions to actively provide oversight of regulatory policy” (OECD 2012). REFERENCES Energy Community. 2017. Annual Implementation Report. Vienna: Energy Community Secretariat. IMF (International Monetary Fund). 2003. “Georgia: Poverty Reduction Strategy Paper.” IMF Country Report 03/265, IMF, Washington, DC. Macfarlane, S. N. 2013. “Georgia and the Political Economy of Statebuilding.” In Political Economy of Statebuilding: Power after Peace, edited by M. Berdal and D. Zaum, 309. London​ /New York: Routledge. OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). 2012. Recommendation of the Council on Regulatory Policy and Governance. Paris: OECD Publishing. 16 Maintaining the Strategy Over Time INTRODUCTION The reform process should seek to develop a credible market and regulatory architecture which enables private, and particularly foreign, investors to develop confidence in the regulatory environment and makes them willing to maintain and expand their investments. The principle of predictability, highlighted in Part B, is an important contributor to this outcome. A significant aspect of predict- ability is that policy positions should be maintained over the medium term and any significant changes made through a proper process involving advance warn- ing and adequate consultation with affected parties. Two closely related con- cepts needed to achieve this type of reform process are policy commitment and stability, which are discussed below. COMMITMENT, CONTINUITY, AND POLICY STABILITY A fundamental principle of good regulation is that of credibility. Stakeholders must be confident that the regulatory system will “honor its commitments”— that is, will function in the expected manner consistently over time. In a post-fragile environment, the establishment and maintenance of credibility poses particular challenges, which must be identified and addressed carefully. Commitment Maintaining credibility requires commitment. Commitment implies that con- tracts and other agreements with investors in regulated sectors continue to be honored and that regulatory frameworks remain stable over time. However, a frequent dynamic in developing countries is that government agencies seek to renegotiate such agreements, or revise regulatory provisions, within relatively short periods. In some cases, renegotiations can be imposed unilaterally, while in others the initial agreements require both parties to accept a renegotiation. However, given the extent to which investors in any country are dependent on government decisions, there may be little difference in practice between these two scenarios.  137 138 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS Such renegotiations inevitably create uncertainty for investors, introducing “sovereign risk” into their investment calculus. In addition, the need to adapt to a new regulatory and/or commercial environment itself causes disruption costs, which can be substantial. Estache and Wren-Lewis (2010) report data which shows that such renegotiations tend to both reduce the amount of investment and increase the risk premium (hence, the total rate of return) required by inves- tors over the medium to long term. Both of these impacts are necessarily wel- fare-reducing, in economic terms. Hence, governments must be cautious when considering a renegotiation of existing agreements. Nonetheless, there are sound reasons for governments to seek renegotiation of such agreements. Particularly in post-fragile countries, a key dynamic is that the original contract may have substantial deficiencies, often because of the rel- ative lack of commercial sophistication of government negotiators and/or draft- ers. Such deficiencies can often mean that agreements do not contain adequate provisions to protect the interests of government entities, taxpayers and/or con- sumers. Where it becomes evident that outcomes unreasonably favor investors over these other groups, whose interests’ government must protect, there may be a strong motive for renegotiation. Alternatively, outcomes that are unfairly weighted toward investors may result from unforeseen, material changes in the economic and/or commercial environment. Such changes are especially likely to occur in the post-fragile con- text, where institutions, industries and other key social infrastructure are being rebuilt, or built anew. Governments in these circumstances have clear responsibilities to safeguard the interests of consumers. The benefits of infrastructure investments must be widely distributed across society to maintain and strengthen support for regula- tory and structural reforms over time. While equity goals are often more effi- ciently pursued via budgetary measures in developed countries, low fiscal efficiency in post-fragile states can mean that the regulatory system is the only feasible/effective means of pursuing distributional goals. Further, the outputs of infrastructure industries provide inputs to production in the great majority of economic sectors. This means that a failure to ensure that consumers of infrastructure services obtain substantial benefits from reform will imply significant welfare losses in other parts of the economy. Box 16.1 summarizes key reasons for govern- BOX 16.1 ments to consider contract renegotiations or to change regulatory provisions. Recap of reasons governments Thus, there are clear and legitimate reasons for may want to pursue contract governments to seek to renegotiate contractual renegotiations or change regulatory arrangements and/or vary regulatory provisions. provisions, despite breaking However, policymakers should approach these ques- “continuity” tions cautiously and adopt a benefit/cost framework to determine when and how to conduct such renego- tiations. Broadly speaking, the costs associated with 1. Original contract may have substantial deficiencies; the sovereign risk that renegotiation introduces to 2. unforeseen, material changes in the economic investors’ views of investment must be weighed and/or commercial environment; carefully against the expected benefits to taxpayers 3. to safeguard the interests of consumers; and consumers from renegotiation. 4. possible substantial welfare losses in other parts The means by which renegotiations are con- of the economy fueled by contract structure or ducted can have a significant impact on this balance regulatory architecture. of benefits and costs. Some key considerations in this regard are: Maintaining the Strategy Over Time | 139 • View the agreement as an outline of commitments. Large-scale and complex agreements involving several parties are common in relation to ­ infrastructure. These agreements should be seen as an outline of commit- ments, detailing the major responsibilities of each party as specified in the contract. When a party has difficulty in servicing the contract due to unfore- seen conditions, it should communicate and share this with the other side as soon as possible. In some cases, a relatively simple modification, such as rescheduling shipments or extending payments, can be enough to ensure implementation without major renegotiations. However, where larger changes with significant impacts on other parties are required, an open and timely approach will help to maintain trust and help achieve an outcome that benefits all parties. • Be aware of cultural differences. Contracts often involve parties from widely different cultures with differing views on the role of negotiation and the content of contracts. American firms, for example, often prefer lengthy, detailed contracts with little flexibility, attempting to identify all possible factors that could influence the contract and incorporating clauses to spec- ify what should be done in each case. In addition, strict penalties for non-compliance are often included. Other cultures, such as the Chinese, often see a contract as only the beginning of a business relationship, consid- ering that negotiations can be reopened. These differences should be taken into consideration in the negotiations and the design of the contract, with negotiators repeatedly asking, “What does this section of the proposed agreement mean to the other party?” and, “To what extent is the other party committed to the agreement?” Where there are clear differences of inter- pretation and commitment, answers should be sought in the negotiations. Sometimes a shorter contract that acknowledges the possibility of eventual renegotiations and amendments may be more appropriate, although penal- ties and other deterrents should always be included to avoid potential abuses. • Predictability. Include, as far as possible, provisions identifying the cir- cumstances in which renegotiation can occur and how it will be conducted to reduce uncertainty and cost. These are often known as “intra-deal” renegotiations and are likely to be smoother if the initial agreement ­contains a clause that permits them, due to unforeseen events. Their accep- tance will often help reduce tensions and misunderstandings. Including in the initial contract some rules or guidance as to how matters to be negoti- ated will be addressed may also reduce opportunities for disagreement and conflict. • Continuously monitor progress and consider incorporating scheduled reviews in the agreement. At the time of signing the contract the parties often assume that the negotiations are over whereas, in practice, bargaining has only completed the first stage. A negotiation is not complete until the resulting agreement is fully implemented and, in reality, unexpected changes are the norm so that a smooth implementation is the exception rather than the rule. When a long-term agreement is put in place, both parties can decide to meet regularly to identify potential problems. This provision of a specific mechanism for addressing issues can reduce conflict due to “unexpected” claims for modifications to the contract. • All parties should build in renegotiation costs. As renegotiations are expen- sive in time and money, the anticipated costs should be incorporated in the agreement as far as possible. 140 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS Continuity A common problem during the implementation of new regulatory systems as part of infrastructure- sector reform is that of a lack of continuity. This problem often arises in relation to the governing bodies of recently established regulators but is also sometimes seen in relation to incumbent public enterprises. Parties that oppose a new regulator’s reform agenda often bring strong pressure to bear on government to appoint more “flexible” board members. At the same time, however, political struggles within government and/or parliament can make it difficult to agree on such appointments. Extended paralysis of this kind can make boards largely unable to take key regulatory decisions, giving rise to sub- stantial blockages in the broader reform process. Box 16.2 highlights an example of this problem drawn from Kosovo. It is important to have an appointments process that minimizes the risk of appointees lacking requisite technical qualifications and experience due to political considerations. The process should also ensure that appointments can effectively be made in a timely manner. Legislation establishing independent regulators frequently seeks to address this issue by including requirements set- ting out the qualifications that individuals must possess in order to be eligible board positions. However, excessively prescriptive provisions can give rise to vexatious challenges, as noted in Part B. For example, in Nepal, following a change of government a challenge was made, in 2012, to the appointment of the new Chairman of the National Telecommunications Authority on the basis that he did not meet the qualifications criteria set out in the Telecoms Act 1997. The Supreme Court stayed the appointment in early 2013, finding that, while a BOX 16.2 Lack of continuity on regulatory boards in Kosovo Recent EU reportsa on Kosovo have highlighted the 2015 ended a long period in which key decisions tendency for appointments to the boards of many reg- regarding the electricity market were blocked, includ- ulatory authorities and state-owned enterprises to be ing the approval of licenses for new suppliers. However, made on political grounds rather than on the basis of May 2017 saw the number of board members again fall professional competence. One consequence is that to two—short of the necessary quorum of three—and there have frequently been very long delays in com- the board was consequently paralyzed again pleting appointment processes as different groups The telecoms regulator (the Regulatory Authority sought to have their candidates nominated and of Electronic and Postal Communications [RAEPC]), approved by parliament. This kind of jockeying often previously faced the same problem. However, this led resulted in major organizations postponing important to a subsequent change in the law on telecommunica- decisions for years. tions, which now provides that existing board mem- For example, the Kosovo Competition Commission bers whose terms have expired continue in office was unable to take major decisions for over 3 years pending the appointment of new members. This until five board members were finally appointed in change has ensured board continuity at RAEPC, mid-2016. Similarly, the appointment of three board enabling key decisions to be made and the regulator to members to the Energy Regulatory Office in November carry out its functions. a. European Commission 2016. Maintaining the Strategy Over Time | 141 mechanical engineer, he did not meet the requirement that the appointee should be “qualified and experienced, as prescribed in the technical and administrative, market management, accounts and auditing or legal field relating to the Telecommunications Service.” The court finally upheld his appointment in October 2014 (Kathmandu Post 2014)—after the regulator had been without a chairman for almost 2 years. A further factor in relation to appointments is the question of the involvement of parliament in the process. In some countries, such as Kosovo, parliament must formally appoint members to the boards of a range of regulatory agencies and public enterprises from names put forward by the government. This process is typically favored as tending to stop governments filling top posts with political appointees. But it has often led to long delays, as in the case of Kosovo, and raises concerns about the ability of parliaments to appointing candidates to often highly technical positions. A potentially preferable alternative is to give parliament a safeguard role, that is, parliament can reject government appointments on limited grounds specified in relevant legislation. This can speed up the filling of high-level posts, while still imposing some official discipline on the process. Policy stability A related issue is that of policy stability. A key risk in recently reformed sectors of the economy is that the often initially disappointing performance of newly created or reconstituted regulators leads to pressure to make further changes to the insti- tutional architecture within relatively short periods. Such short-term changes may then be repeated if the revised architecture fails to deliver improved outcomes in the medium term. An example of this dynamic is illustrated in box 16.3. However, frequent changes in institutional architecture can result in signifi- cant costs. It is important to recognize that the development of regulatory capacity takes time. It involves recruiting and training a critical mass of compe- ­ tent, dedicated staff who need to build expertise in the specific regulatory ­ environment through experience. A key risk arising from major institutional changes is that this process is likely to be disrupted so that a newly appointed regulator is less-equipped to embark on its task than its predecessor. Important considerations are that: • Key staff are likely to be discouraged by the abolition or fundamental restruc- turing of the original regulatory structure, considering it an implicit criticism of their performance. As a result, they may not seek reappointment in the new regulatory body. • Equally, the attractiveness of roles in the new regulator for well-qualified staff can be diminished by the perception of career risk stemming from changes in the regulatory structure. • In any organization, the early years of a new or substantially reformed entity are characterized by large quantities of resources being devoted to the estab- lishment of the new body, including developing standard procedures and pro- cesses, agreeing lines of authority and responsibility and clarifying the nature of the body’s relationships with other key entities in its operating environ- ment. Developing an organizational structure and undertaking major recruit- ment are also significant tasks. What it adds up to is that a new or reconstituted regulator is likely to under-perform for perhaps 2–3 years. 142 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS The importance of these costs should therefore be weighed against the gains expected from implementing major change to regulatory arrangements. Careful consideration should be given to whether problems with the performance of the current regulator can be addressed through smaller, more targeted changes over a period of time. Maintaining the integrity of the reform process—exemptions and exceptions A common problem in post-fragile environments is the creation of exemptions from the newly adopted regulatory processes implemented as part of the reform agenda. Such exemptions are often justified as being needed to meet urgent needs, or address particular issues. They are therefore often framed as “emer- gency exemptions” or as streamlined approvals for “strategically important projects.” However, when such exemptions from the standard processes are granted, there is a clear risk of undermining the integrity of the newly established regula- tory systems. The potential for unfair treatment of different current or potential operators is evident while the mere suspicion of bias has obvious negative impacts on investor confidence. Such exemptions, which typically rely on the approval of a single minister or a small group of ministers, also clearly creates significant opportunities for corruption, further undermining the regulatory system. BOX 16.3 A lack of policy stability in the Rwanda infrastructure sector—2003–10 In 2003, Rwanda’s major state enterprise, Electrogaz, In October 2013, the Rwandan Cabinet, dissatis- was placed under a management contract with fied with the performance of EWSA following a Lahmayer International for 5 years, with the aim of very critical review by the Auditor-General, decided eventual privatization. In 2006 the contract was ter- to terminate the organization and create three new minated when the Rwandan Government became companies, though this time under company law, aware of misconduct in Lahmeyer contracts in rather than by statute. The first was an electricity Lesotho. The World Bank later “sanctioned,” in effect utility, the Electricity Utility Corporation Limited “blacklisting,” or “debarring,” Lahmeyer International (EUCL); the second an energy development for 7 years from World Bank-funded contracts follow- ­ c ompany, the Rwanda Energy Development ing the Lesotho incident. Corporation Limited (EDCL); and the third a The Electricity Law of 2008 was introduced shortly ­ c ompany to be responsible for water supply and thereafter, with Electrogaz split into the Rwanda sanitation services development and operations, Energy Corporation (RECO) and the Rwanda Water the Rwanda Water and Sanitation Corporation and Sewerage Corporation (RWASCO). RECO Limited (WASAC). assumed all Electrogaz’s electricity-related activities, While the aim was to develop increasingly effi- assets, and liabilities. However, the decision to split cient infrastructure sectors, with growing private Electrogaz was not deemed a success and in December involvement, the extent and type of largely unpredict- 2010 Law No. 43/2010 established the Rwanda Energy, able changes also created ongoing, institutional insta- Water and Sanitation Authority (EWSA), with both bility that at times had an adverse impact on staff and RECO and RWASCO reintegrated into the new entity. performance. Maintaining the Strategy Over Time | 143 BOX 16.4 Presidential projects in Madagascar In Madagascar, Law 98-032 provides for electricity Authorizations, or in the absence of the holders. generation licenses to be awarded to private firms To  this end, it may take any urgent measures in by tender, with the criteria used to assess submis- ­accordance with the terms and conditions specified sions and projects subject to the required legislative by decree.” processes (e.g., environmental approval). However, There is no definition of what might constitute an some entries, if given the status of “Presidential “urgent measure,” leaving room for considerable dis- Projects,” need not go to tender or, in some cases, cretion at political level. As a result, the “Presidential undergo feasibility studies. Such exemptions from projects” can contain technical flaws serious enough normal practice is authorized under Article 19 of to endanger public safety. Also present is the risk of Law 98-032, which states that “The State guaran- corruption due to insufficient scrutiny of relevant pro- tees the continuity of the public service of electric- visions such as the prices at which power purchase ity in case of deficiency by holders of Concessions or agreements are concluded. Source: Rafitoson 2017. Consequently, one should be skeptical about allowing such exemptions or exceptions within the regulatory structure. Where they are adopted, several principles should be observed in order to minimize any negative consequences: • The exemption process should be established in law, so that its existence and key features remain transparent. • The purpose and scope of the exemptions from, or exceptions to, normal approval processes should be clearly specified, or the details of any alterna- tive processes should be clarified. • The nature of the decision-making process to be used in “exceptional circum- stances” should also be made explicit, as should the identity of the decision-maker. • Transparent criteria and/or thresholds should be established to determine when the exceptions process can be used: it should be consistent with the stated objectives of the system. • The decision-maker(s) should be required to publish an explanation of why it was decided to use the exceptional process and what results can be expected. In addition, the law should include a provision requiring exempted projects to be independently reviewed (e.g., by an Auditor-General or a parliamentary committee) within a specified period (e.g., within 3 years of coming into opera- tion. The review should assess the value added by projects approved under these alternative arrangements, the probity of the process and any impact on confi- dence in the impartiality of treatment of investors. ADDRESSING THE “IMPLEMENTATION GAP” A key concern in the early years of the implementation of a reform program is that of a major gap emerging between the policy objectives and the outcomes 144 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS of the practices implemented. This is often referred to as the “implementation gap” and is likely to require attention in low-capacity environments. The imple- mentation gap typically arises due a combination of factors, although the relative importance of each can vary. Key contributors to the implementation gap include: • Policy deficiencies. The policy adopted may lack elements that come to be seen as crucial to its success. This can often happen because specific elements of the policy environment are not well understood at the time policy is devel- oped. Recognizing policy deficiencies will help develop and tailor the policy to address context-specific factors and ultimately help achieve policy objectives. • Unanticipated impacts. The implementation of the policy may have import- ant unanticipated effects, particularly where sectoral policies are poorly coordinated with each other or, as above, a lack of understanding of aspects of the policy environment causes problems in policy design. • Lack of resources/capacities. Post-fragile environments will likely lack ade- quate resources or capacities. This can create a significant gap between the ­formal analysis and process requirements established by policy and the content achieved in practice. Recognition of capacity constraints is obviously important at the policy design stage. However, following implementation, a clear focus on key areas in which policy elements are not being delivered in practice, and are significantly compromising the achievement of policy objectives, is needed. Responses should include consideration of whether and how additional resources can be applied in key areas of failure and assess whether changes in the policy are needed to achieve better practical outcomes. For example: –– Overly demanding impact assessment (IA) requirements focusing on quantified analysis could mean that resources are focused on completing a small number of assessments, with the IA requirement not being met in many other cases. Modifying the requirement to establish a more manage- able level of analysis could help ensure that all relevant proposals receive at least a minimum of assessment (e.g., the World Bank’s “RIA Lite” approach, which aims to tailor the Regulatory Impact Assessment discipline to suit the realities of developing country environments [World Bank 2010]). –– Consultation periods that are too short, meaning that effective participa- tion by stakeholders is often very limited, or narrowly based. Possible pol- icy responses could include extending consultation periods, providing additional material to help stakeholders participate effectively and improv- ing the consultation methods used to make it easier to participate. –– Poor coordination. Performance problems may result from gaps in the allocation of responsibility or, alternatively, unclear responsibilities for key program elements, potentially including overlap between different minis- tries, regulators, or other entities. These issues may be addressed by agree- ing and adopting clear protocols setting out the relative roles of the major bodies with responsibilities for the reform program, but legislative change may also be required to establish clear lines of responsibility. –– Governance issues. As discussed elsewhere, deficiencies in the governance arrangements of key institutions can mean that they do not consistently focus on achieving the goals of the reform program. Even where sound gov- ernance principles formed the basis for developing these arrangements, compromises will often have been made. Practical experience in implement- ing the reform policy will often highlight the real impacts of these and indi- cate where change is needed if the policy is to better achieve its goals. Maintaining the Strategy Over Time | 145 Careful and coordinated policy design will help minimize the extent of the implementation gaps that arise. However, significant gaps will most certainly appear during the early stages of major policy reform. Ensuring that efforts are made to identify and address such gaps is therefore a key part of the “policy cycle”1 and essential to making certain that reforms are sustained and expanded over time. The use of the Part B principles in such situations will assist in both identify- ing and clarifying the specific gaps, or issues that arise and developing changes to regulations that will help bridge them. Scheduling review activity on a regular basis and using the principles as the basis for the review will both help to ensure that a systematic and rigorous approach is taken, thus improving the quality of the outcomes achieved. Developing and participating in communities of practice Many regulators and supervising ministries responsible for the reform of infra- structure regulation have found participation in international associations of reg- ulators an important way to address implementation gaps and improve practice over time. These associations can function as “communities of practice,” in which regulators can identify and discuss key issues, share experiences and lessons learned and provide mutual support. They can also be important mechanisms for knowledge transfer from experts in academia, donor organizations, etc. These associations are often organized on regional lines and offer the advan- tage of enabling regulators to exchange experiences with their counterparts in countries with relatively similar socio-economic systems and levels of develop- ment, thus potentially providing a particularly relevant source of advice and assistance. Box 16.5 provides an example of such a forum for regulators. BOX 16.5 Regional forums for utility regulators The African Forum for Utility Regulators on sector-specific issues. Partnerships with the European (AFUR) Union and the World Bank’s PPIAF program provide opportunities for knowledge transfer and technical sup- AFUR was established as part of the African Union’s port, such as the EU-supported Guidelines for Electricity socio-economic program, the New Partnership for Supply Cost, Tariff Level and Structure (AFUR 2016). Africa’s Development (NEPAD). It focuses on issues AFUR holds regular forums and workshops and hosts a involving the regulation of the energy, telecommunica- web discussion forum. https://www.afurnet​ .org/en/. tions, transport, and water and sanitation industries. Members include 33 regulatory authorities from 21 The East Asia and Pacific Infrastructure African countries, while regulators from four more Regulatory Forum (EAPIRF) African countries are represented among its seven observers. EAPIRF was established in 2003 with support from AFUR emphasizes issues that are common across the the World Bank Group (notably PPIAF). It is intended sectors regulated by its membership, but has also estab- to foster capacity-building and knowledge exchange lished four sectoral committees (for communications, among infrastructure regulators in the region to sup- energy, transport, and water and sanitation) which focus port enhanced regulatory decision-making. It also continued 146 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS Box 16.5, continued seeks to facilitate the development of training and provides a list of regionally based associations of capacity-building opportunities for regulators. energy regulators, including the South Asian Forum EAPIRF covers the energy, water/sanitation, tele- for Utility Regulators, the East Asia and Pacific coms/broadcasting and transport sectors. It has a Infrastructure Regulatory Forum, the Organization two-tier structure, in which regulators are core mem- of Caribbean Energy Regulators and the Regional bers while institutions with related interests, such as Electricity Regulators’ Association of Southern NGOs, donor bodies and universities are able to join as Africa. affiliate members. EAPIRF’s activities include con- Regional associations of telecoms regulators ducting workshops, conferences and training activi- include the Telecoms Regulators’ Association of ties and the publication of a range of materials such as Southern Africa, the West Africa Telecoms Regula- regulator and country profiles and academic papers. tors’ Association, Le Réseau francophone de la régula- http://www.eapirf.org/about-eapirf. tion des télécommunications, Latin American Telecommunications Regulators’ Forum and the South Asian Telecommunications Regulators’ Other regulators’ forums ­Council. a The International Telecommunications The website of the International Confederation of Union also hosts meetings of regional regulators’ Energ y Reg ulators (w w w.icer-reg ulators.net) associations (see www.itu.int). a. For a fuller list of regional regulators’ associations, focussing on the telecoms field, see: http://www.itu.int/ITU-D/treg/Documentation​ /Table_region_reg_assoc.pdf. Training and professional development The importance of investing in structured programs of training and professional development has been noted at various points in this manual, especially in rela- tion to ensuring adequate capacity for reform. Resources must continue to be devoted to this task throughout the implementation of the reform program, as improving technical capacities within regulatory agencies and supervising min- istries constitutes an important means of addressing implementation gaps over time. As noted above, participation in communities of practice at the regional level are one significant way of ensuring knowledge transfer and capacity devel- opment. However, this should be supplemented by internally developed pro- grams, with the central coordination bodies responsible for the reform program taking the lead in identifying needs and ensuring the delivery of relevant and appropriate training. CONCLUSION This final chapter has focused on the work involved in maintaining an appropri- ate strategy for regulatory governance over time and modifying it to suit chang- ing circumstances. It has stressed the need for commitment, continuity and policy stability in helping to ensure good regulatory governance and to address the implementation gap often faced by reformers. Maintaining the Strategy Over Time | 147 NOTE 1. The “policy cycle” refers to a concept of public policy as circular, with the key stages being policy development, implementation, review/outcome assessment, policy analysis and fur- ther policy development. This process of analyzing outcomes and refining and modifying policies is particularly important when major new policies are being implemented. However, the constantly changing policy environment means that the conception of ­ policy-making as a cyclical process has a broader importance and relevance. REFERENCES AFUR (African Forum for Utility Regulators). 2016. Electricity Supply Cost, Tariff Level and Structure, by Alain Doulet. Final Version: December 2016, AFUR Secretariat, Pretoria. Estache, A., and L. Wren-Lewis. 2010. “On the Theory and Evidence on Regulation of Network Industries in Developing Countries.” In The Oxford Handbook of Regulation, edited by Robert Baldwin, Martin Cave, and Martin Lodge, 371–406. Oxford: Oxford University Press. European Commission. 2016. “Kosovo 2016 Report.” Accompanying the document: “Communication from the Commission to the European Parliament, the Council, the European Economic and Social Committee and the Committee of the Regions. 2016 Communication on EU Enlargement Policy.” {COM (2016) 715 final}. Commission Staff Working Document, European Commission, Brussels. https://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal​ -­content/en/TXT/?uri=CELEX:52016SC0363. Kathmandu Post. 2014. “Apex court upholds Jha’s appointment as NTA chief.” Kathmandu Post 2014-10-29. http://kathmandupost.ekantipur.com/printedition/news/2014-10-28/apex​ -court-upholds-jhas-appointment-as-nta-chief.html (accessed June 24, 2019). Rafitoson, K. 2017. La Lente March vers La Transition Energetique A Madagascar: Etat Des Lieux  et Perspectives. Friedrich-Ebert-Stiftung. http://library.fes.de/pdf-files/bueros​ /­madagaskar/15155.pdf. World Bank. 2010. Making It Work: `RIA Light’ For Developing Countries. Better Regulation for Growth: Governance Frameworks and Tools for Effective Regulatory Reform. Washington, DC: World Bank. http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/184141468167049021​ pdf​ /­ /55636-WP-REPLACEMENT-RIALightNov2009.pdf. A Glossary of Key Concepts Used in the Manual The following concepts are used in a variety of sometimes overlapping and/or inconsistent ways by authors from different disciplines. To avoid confusion, the following definitions clarify their meaning as used in this manual. KEY CONCEPTS RELATING TO REGULATION Governance In its broadest sense, governance refers to all processes of governing, whether undertaken by governments, corporations, professional or industry association, etc. It relates to the dynamics whereby actors interact and make decisions, giving rise to institutions and social norms, and change them over time. Policy Policy, in the current context, refers to the objective(s) being pursued by govern- ment and the general approach being adopted to their implementation. In a broader sense, policy can mean similar things in relation to a wide range of orga- nizations—that is, the objectives they seek and the broad means of pursuing them. Public policy Public policy refers to broad courses of action adopted or proposed by a govern- ment in pursuit of public-good objectives. Regulation In its broadest sense, regulation encompasses any exercise of authority intended to modify the behavior of another group. Under this definition, both govern- ments and various private bodies (e.g., industry or professional associations) engage in regulation. However, for present purposes, we are concerned with government regulation.  149 150 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS FIGURE A.1 The regulatory process: A recurrent cycle Problem identification Evaluation and Analysis and review of assessment of regulation options to address Administration and Regulatory design enforcement of and regulation by a implementation regulator Government broadly has three sets of tools available: the first allows it to levy taxes, the second enables it to spend the resulting revenue, while the third con- cerns regulation. In this sense, regulation encompasses all laws, ordinances, decrees and other legal or legislative instruments that either prohibit certain actions or require groups within society to act in certain ways or become subject to certain constraints. Considered in this manner, regulation can also be viewed as a process. The regulatory process involves a recurring cycle of activities, often referred to as the “regulatory cycle” (see figure A.1), which involve: problem identification; analysis and assessment of options to address the problem; regulatory design and implementation; administration and enforcement of regulation by a regula- tor, and evaluation and review of regulation (which, in turn, leads back to a new problem-definition phase). The term regulation can also refer specifically to subordinate legislation— that is, rules (often called “regulations”) made under the authority of an Act of Parliament/Congress. Common types of subordinate legislation are: regulations, ministerial orders, codes of practice and local laws and bylaws. This manual is primarily concerned with the regulatory process carried out within government and with all the different instruments that result from this process. Regulatory capture Regulatory capture refers to a situation in which a regulator or regulatory agency advances the interests of one or more group rather than the broad public Glossary of Key Concepts Used in the Manual | 151 interest. In many cases, regulators act in the interest of one or more regulated party (e.g., industry), rather than the broader interests of consumers, taxpayers and the public. An example is industry persuading the regulator to defend the status quo and thus preventing competitors from entering the market. Regulatory compliance Regulatory compliance refers to an organization’s or individual’s adherence to laws, policies, regulations and guidelines. Compliance strategies may be adopted by government to ensure adequate levels of adherence to new regulations or to maintain or increase levels of compliance with existing or modified regulations. Regulatory governance Regulatory governance refers to the policies, tools, processes and institutions that are primarily concerned with developing, implementing, administering and enforcing new regulations and reviewing and revising regulation over time. To put it another way, regulatory governance is the process of regulating regula- tions and regulators. Regulatory independence Regulatory independence in the context of governance refers to a regulator’s (or regulatory agency’s) ability to act in accordance with the law (usually its founding statute) and without direction from government other than that which is specifically authorized by that law. Regulatory management or regulatory management system A regulatory management system is the set of formal and informal institutions, processes and actors that is responsible for oversight of the development and implementation of government regulation. In most senses it is a synonym for regulatory governance. Regulatory policy Regulatory policy refers to any government policy that is intended to have an impact on the system of regulatory governance. Regulatory quality Regulatory quality refers to the efficiency, effectiveness, transparency, account- ability and, ultimately, the legitimacy of a body of regulation. Regulatory strategy A regulatory strategy is an explicit government policy aimed at maintaining or increasing regulatory quality. In practice it often takes the form of government endorsement of a set of “good practice” or “best practice” regulatory principles. In federal states there may be differing regulatory strategies at the federal and state levels and, less often, at the level of local government. 152 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS KEY CONCEPTS RELATED TO FRAGILE AND CONFLICT-AFFECTED STATES Definition of fragility stages1 Stage 1. Crisis A situation of crisis can refer to a period when there is acute instability in a ­country, with increased levels of violence and the potential for more generalized violent conflict, or when there has been a natural or man-made disaster. Frequently, there are major political divisions in this period and often conflict among communities, leading to widespread mistrust and fear. Security forces may be committing generalized human rights abuses amid endemic corruption so that the public has little confidence in the security apparatus. The security sector is typically fragmented and often being reformed. Rule of law is typically eroded and politicized, and the economic sector is severely constrained. During this phase, justice is only upheld at national, and not at local or regional level, and the country faces many human rights violations that the state fails to address. As a result, violence is used increasingly as a means of settling disputes. Basic gov- ernment services are likely to be weak or nonexistent, and the international humanitarian and aid community may have stepped in to provide emergency relief. International organizations may also be supporting security through police or peacekeeping missions. Government revenues are often low or nonex- istent, and countries often suffer illegal or informal exploitation of natural resources and weak enforcement of regulations governing natural resources. Stage 2. Rebuild and reform During this phase, renewed efforts at engaging in political dialogue to resolve political differences may be made. However, power is often shared inequitably between groups. There may be some progress on disarmament, but security remain a challenge, with a high proliferation of small arms. Institutions are often weak and deliver services sporadically. As compared to the crisis phase, the intensity of conflict and of political disputes is more manageable and efforts are made to establish stronger security institutions and to recruit personnel. However, in this stage, the efficacy of the security apparatus is likely to be lim- ited. Justice institutions start to make their presence felt beyond national capi- tals but are often ineffective so that the rule of law is not enforced. As for the foundations of economic activity, basic infrastructure and an enabling economic environment are beginning to be put in place, but high unemployment rates are still to be found, particularly among young people. During this phase, large potential sources of domestic revenue may have been identified (e.g., natural resources and/or customs), but these are poorly accounted for, benefiting only a small part of the population. While the process of reforming public financial management may have begun, budget execution problems remain and account- ability is weak. Stage 3. Transition This stage is often associated with the signature of agreements and an overall situation of stability. There is more space for formal dialogue between parties, which leads to the creation of institutions, including electoral institutions, to support the talks. While there should be increased stability in the country, there is also likely to be corruption and problems in working with strong Glossary of Key Concepts Used in the Manual | 153 opposition groups. Oversight capacity from the legislature is often weak. In com- parison to the previous phases, there is improved oversight and advocacy from civil society and some initial media freedom. There may be an improvement in security provided by the state. And although lack of resources and capacity may still pose problems, there is also increased confidence in security and justice institutions, with a corresponding reduction in the use of violence for settling disputes. Efforts to decentralize the mechanisms of justice may be made, includ- ing the adoption of alternative dispute resolution mechanisms. During this stage, there may be increased access to basic infrastructure, but mainly in urban areas. While government usually remains the largest employer, there are signs of more jobs being created in the private sector and of an increase in government reve- nue, particularly from natural resources (if they exist), tax collection and other revenue streams. Stronger basic services are provided, with a sturdier but poorly implemented regulatory framework. Stage 4. Transformation In the transformation stage, a country may have increased social resilience, with conflicts more often resolved peacefully. Credible, non-violent and democratic political processes start to make their appearance. Civil society begins to play an active role in political and societal debates, and, increasingly, good governance principles are adhered to. However, in this period there may also be a lack of public understanding of those principles. During this phase, the security situa- tion has typically remained stable for a considerable time, often at least 5 years. One is more likely to encounter security personnel across the territory, albeit in small numbers and with limited capacity. Usually there is also increased public confidence in security institutions, and potential abuses are more frequently sanctioned. Economically, an enabling environment for business may be found, with more job opportunities, including in the private sector. Public institutions may be capable of managing domestic revenues better through improved tax and customs collection. Very often, decentralization is undertaken to extend access to basic services to the whole country. Stage 5. Resilience Resilience may be understood as a society’s capacity to deal with challenges and to absorb shocks without entering into crisis. Every stage in the Fragility Spectrum represents progress toward that end, but at this stage resilience has been institutionalized in its social customs, cultural practices, social contract and formal state institutions to such a degree that a relapse into crisis is so unlikely that the country in question can no longer be considered a post-con- flict nation. The focus thus shifts away from socio-political consolidation to long-term social and economic development. During this period, political sta- bility has existed for a long time, typically more than 20 years, and the country should have created a strong culture of democracy and good governance. The country may also have made it possible for its citizens to gain a better under- standing of the political process. The government should be active in combat- ing corruption with transparent and inclusive processes. Fundamental rights are more likely to be upheld, and the role of civil society should have been defined. There should be sufficient security personnel throughout the country and a high level of confidence among the population. There is evident political will to fight elite impunity, and widespread awareness of how the formal justice system operates. Good infrastructure now connects different parts of the 154 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS country and the private sector represents a large share of the labor market. Systems are likely to be in place for properly managing natural resources while enough revenue is generated to provide essential services to citizens. Public institutions function both at national and subnational level, and the state increasingly becomes the main service provider for basic needs. NOTE 1. Source: g7+ 2013. REFERENCE g7+. 2013. Note on the Fragility Spectrum. Dili: g7+ Secretariat. https://www.pbsbdialogue.org​ /media/filer_public/17/43/17434d29-eb70-425b-8367-7ccef13bfb0b/g7fragility​ _­spectrum_2013.pdf. B A Review of the Literature Related to Regulatory Governance The following summarizes the state of knowledge regarding regulatory gover- nance as it relates to the objectives of the manual. It deals primarily with the following areas: • regulatory governance, including the governance of regulators; • governance relating specifically to infrastructure regulation, particularly in fragile countries; • regulatory management capacity; and • instruments and strategies for improving and maintaining good regulatory practice. There is an extensive and rapidly growing literature on regulation and gover- nance in the developed and developing world and the material covered in this review can only cover part of it. Readers are encouraged to seek out this broader literature, as it contains much that is of value to the practice of regulatory governance. The material discussed below is relevant to evaluating and strengthening reg- ulatory governance and largely excludes the much more extensive literature on the development, implementation and review of specific regulations, except where the focus of the regulation in question is to improve regulatory gover- nance or regulatory management capacity. The literature review examines mul- tiple themes or issues and several of the references are relevant to more than one. Why study the literature? There are three major reasons for providing a short review of the relevant liter- ature in a manual such as this. First, it underpins the analysis and recommenda- tions made in the manual. Second, it helps provide context for the manual by identifying and briefly discussing relevant material that has not been included. Third, a literature review provides references that can be followed up by readers who wish to learn more about a topic.  155 156 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS THE LITERATURE EXAMINING THE IMPACT OF REGULATORY GOVERNANCE ON DEVELOPMENT Why should regulatory governance be examined? Fundamentally, because regula- tory governance has a significant, measurable impact on economic development. A rapidly growing body of empirical and theoretical research shows that poor reg- ulatory governance impedes economic development. Stern and Holder (1999), for example, studied 12 infrastructure industries in six developing Asian countries and found that “structural liberalization” (that is, the opening of these industries to competition), was an important catalyst for developing good practice regulation. The authors also highlight the importance of transparency for effective regulation. Most importantly, they found that the clarity of roles and objectives, autonomy, participation, accountability, transparency, decision-making and predictability of regulatory governance were important determinants of industry performance. Similar conclusions have been reached by Andrés, Guasch, and Staub (2007), Stern and Cubbin (2005), Jacobzone et al. (2010), Cordova-Novion and Jacobzone (2011), Gutiérrez and Berg (2000), Gutiérrez (2003), Ros (2003), Cubbin and Stern (2006), Maiorano and Stern (2007), Andrés, Guasch, and Lopez Azumendi (2008) and Estache, Goicoechea, and Trujillo (2009). Laffont (2005) was among the first to address regulatory governance in devel- oping countries. He stressed that regulatory institutions and policies cannot be simply transferred from developed to developing countries, as has often been done. Minogue and Cariño (2006), similarly, found that existing policy models of regulatory reform were inappropriate, ineffectual, and too narrowly conceived to address the requirements of developing countries. They proposed that these models should be evaluated and reshaped within the broader context of poverty reduction and developmental programs. Kirkpatrick (2014) reviewed the empirical evidence on the impact of regulatory reform in developing countries and found that there was a positive ­ relationship between regulatory reform and improved economic performance. However, he qualified this finding by pointing to various methodological and data problems that limited the robustness of his conclusions and pointed to the need to broaden the range of designs and methods for evaluating the results of regulatory reforms in developing countries. IFC (2010) found that while effec- tive regulatory governance was important for development, and was much needed, its implementation was often ineffective. In summary, while each of the studies have weaknesses, most find that ­ regulatory governance matters when it comes to economic development. However, the limited evidence available suggests that many attempts to improve regulatory governance have had limited impact, often because they draw too heavily on the experience of reforms in more developed countries. This latter conclusion necessarily underlines the importance of careful design and imple- mentation of such reform programs in developing country contexts generally, and fragile states in particular. THE LITERATURE EVALUATING SPECIFIC ASPECTS OF REGULATORY GOVERNANCE Regulatory governance encompasses a variety of policies, tools, institutions and processes and raises numerous issues and challenges. Reflecting this, there is a A Review of the Literature Related to Regulatory Governance | 157 growing literature that focuses on individual elements of the regulatory gover- nance matrix, rather than the whole picture. Elements that have received the bulk of attention include: • sequencing of regulatory reforms • regulatory capacity • regulatory independence and capture • roles, functions and relationships • decision-making bodies and decision processes • appeals and reviews of decisions • accountability and transparency • engagement and credibility • funding, and • measuring and evaluating performance. Sequencing regulatory reforms Which regulatory reforms should be implemented, and when, are two of the most difficult questions to be addressed and have long been discussed by bodies such as the World Bank and the IMF, particularly in relation to the financing of planned reforms in developing countries (see Rihani 2002). A significant litera- ture attempts to provide practical answers to these questions. It is characterized by a lively debate as to appropriate sequencing for reforms, although few doubt its importance (see, for example Branch and Cheeseman 2009; Carment, Samy and Landry 2013; Carothers 2007; Herbert 2014; Rao 2014; Wallsten 2002). Diamond (2012), for example, believes firmly in the value of appropriate sequenc- ing and provides a set of “good practice” guidelines for the sequencing of reforms to public-sector financial management, though he stresses that such reforms should always be tailored to meet the unique circumstances of each country. He further argues that “leapfrogging” can be dangerous: for example, attempting to improve service delivery by introducing results-based budgeting reforms when adequate financial control is lacking, or there is undue instability in resource availability, is unlikely to be successful and could prove counterproductive. Painter (2014), however, takes a contrary view, arguing that the good gover- nance orthodoxy that proposes a particular sequence of reforms as a necessary component of development is misguided. He cites the examples of China and Vietnam, two authoritarian one-party states that have disregarded this ortho- doxy in favor of “leapfrogging” and “retrofitting.” His article examines the case of the rapid marketization of public service delivery to illustrate his arguments and concludes that the lesson from these two countries is that good governance can be addressed later in the development process. Historically, most studies of sequencing have focused on proposing or assess- ing reform sequences for macroeconomic reform. More recently, reform sequences for public-sector management, and public- sector financial manage- ment reforms, have been the focus of this literature. However, to date, few, if any, published studies deal with the actual or ideal sequence of reforms to systems of regulatory governance, and more research is needed. Importantly, sequencing can be a sensitive political and administrative issue in relation to the reform of regulatory governance. Given that the literature strongly suggests that the restoration of essential infrastructure is a precondition for transition out of fra- ­ gility, reforms of regulatory governance for infrastructure must be a priority. 158 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS Decisions regarding the sequencing of reforms must take the strengths and weaknesses of the current arrangements into account, as well as the type and amount of resources available to implement reform. However, they must also take account of broader local circumstances, including any specific impediments to reforms. Regulatory capacity The extensive literature that discusses the improvement of capacities in fragile states has been usefully reviewed by Christoplos, Engstrand, and Hedqvist (2014). The authors point out the key limitations in the various approaches to identifying gaps and strengthening capacity, noting that the literature predomi- nantly addresses the capacity of governments and public administrations. There is no discussion of regulatory governance as such, a fact that reflects the limited amount of research conducted in this area. However, the authors do make a number of points relevant to those attempting reforms to regulatory gov- ernance. They stress the need to be aware that prevailing systems of incentives in governments are often skewed against genuine reform. Systems of patronage and bureaucratic fiefdoms can make introducing formal norms and principles of regulatory governance extremely difficult as they involve a loss of power and control over incentives for those in authority. In such situations, “least bad solu- tions” are often the best available and for fragile countries experiencing high levels of violence and civil strife, reform to regulatory governance is very diffi- cult. Indeed, the authors go so far as to suggest such reform efforts should be confined largely to countries that have developed more stable systems of public administration and focus on those elements with a greater capacity for change. Barma, Huybens, and Viñuela (2014), reach more positive conclusions. In a recent study of state capacity-building in fragile states, they find that successful institutions share and deploy a common set of internal and external operational strategies, leading along three “pathways” to institutional success. First, some succeed on the basis of strong elite commitment. Second, others seize a window of opportunity to lock in reforms. Third, yet others succeed by more actively cultivating broad support from clients and key stakeholders. The pathways con- stitute the strategies and practices that are pursued to link largely internal, “micro-organizational” changes with the broader, or “macro” socio-political fragile context. While the study was based on a small sample1 and did not focus on regulatory governance, its findings are of considerable relevance. It identifies the shared causal mechanisms underpinning institutional success in fragile states, focusing on both internal and external factors. Roll’s study of “pockets of excellence” in state capacity (Roll 2013) (areas of government that work relatively efficiently) focuses on the reasons such pockets form and suggests that there might be potential for such pockets to be built upon by those pursuing reforms to regulatory governance. While the need to assess and develop regulatory capacity is fundamental to achieving successful regulatory governance reform, the literature addressing this specific issue is quite limited. However, the broader literature on state capacity provides relevant lessons that can be adapted to the regulatory gover- nance context. In particular, regulatory governance reformers can draw on the literature addressing capacity, particularly as regards undue influence, decision processes and organizational structure in relation to regulatory independence, accountability, funding and performance evaluation. A Review of the Literature Related to Regulatory Governance | 159 Regulatory independence and capture The literature on regulatory independence is perhaps the largest single body of writing related to regulatory governance and is too broad to summarize in detail in this review. Hence, only a short overview of selected studies is provided here, and readers should take the opportunity to explore the wider literature. A key reason for the extensive development of this field of study lies in the findings of numerous works, concluding that lower levels of independence are closely asso- ciated with poorly performing systems of regulatory governance, and vice versa (see, for example, to list only few, Andrés, Schwartz and Guasch 2013; Cubbin and Stern 2006; Gilardi 2002, 2008; Johannsen 2003; OECD 2015, 2016a; Trillas and Montoya 2013). This has promoted a literature focusing on the question of how to promote regulatory independence. There is also a distinct literature related to regulatory independence and infrastructure, particularly as regards telecommunications and water (see, for example, Bartle and Vass 2007; Baudrier 2001; Estache 1997; Estache and Wren-Lewis 2010; Johannsen 2003; Smith 1997; Stern 1997; Tenenbaum 1995; Waverman and Koutroumpis 2011; OECD 2000). A series of often similar principles and recommendations on how to achieve and sustain regulatory independence has been developed from this literature (see, for example, Brown et al. 2006; Estache 1997; Johannsen 2003; OECD 2000, 2013, 2014a, 2015, 2016b, 2016c, 2017a, 2017b; Smith 1997; Tenenbaum 1995), bringing together many of the findings in the form of advice for regulators and is drawn on significantly in this manual. The OECD’s 2015 study Being an Independent Regulator (OECD 2016b), which combines a literature review with the results of a survey of 48 regulators, identifies the key points where undue influence can be exercised and suggests ways of developing a culture of independence. Key strategies proposed include expanding interactions with stakeholders, addressing staffing issues, and ensur- ing adequate and independent financing sources. The OECD study (2017a), as noted above, draws heavily upon OECD (2015), which provided the analytical background for the guidance offered and should be referred to for more in-depth analysis of the rationale for, and evidence of, the benefits of ensuring the inde- pendence of regulators. The regulatory capture literature has its origins in the economic theory of reg- ulation. Capture can be thought of as an extreme version of the loss of regulatory independence. Dal Bó’s 2006 survey of the literature regarding capture has been particularly influential. Of special relevance to this manual is Dal Bó’s highlighting of the very high cost of regulatory capture in developing countries. Carpenter and Moss (2014), focus on how to reduce or prevent capture with a series of case stud- ies. Key strategies highlighted include: encouraging the media to inform the public and hold policymakers accountable; developing rules of administrative procedure; using cost-benefit analysis to help query the supposed costs and benefits of pro- posals put forward; drawing upon the expertise and involvement of subnational officials; creating consumer empowerment programs linked to regulators; culti- vating the development of diverse and independent experts and institutionalizing “devil’s advocates,” within regulatory agencies. Roles, functions, and relationships Much of the work on the roles, functions and relationships of regulatory institu- tions is included in works that focus on particular themes and challenges, such as regulatory capacity, independence and capture, decision-making bodies and 160 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS decision processes, and accountability and transparency. However, a number of studies have focused specifically on roles, functions and relationships. One of the most influential is Smith’s 1997 study of the roles of utility regulators, which focuses on defining their responsibilities, particularly in developing countries, and considers the scope of agencies’ industry coverage and their relationship to ministers and to other regulatory bodies and objectives. Smith proposes a “tran- sition path” of organizational forms leading, eventually, to a truly independent agency. The key steps are 1) establishing a dedicated regulatory unit within a department; 2) creating an agency with many of the attributes of an independent agency, but with one or more ministers taking part in its decision-making; and 3) empowering a more truly independent agency, though with some or all of its powers limited to making recommendations to a minister. Groom, Halpern, and Ehrhardt (2006) outline a set of principles and prac- tices to guide the design of a system of regulation in the developing world. Their specific focus is on water supply and sanitation, although their content is largely applicable to other infrastructure industries. They cover the selection and design of organizations and instruments, the use of contracts and public-private part- nerships, prices and tariffs, and the major issues and challenges faced. A very recent OECD study (2017c) examines the role of economic regulators in encouraging the efficient delivery of infrastructure services and considers whether the approach that economic regulators take to applying tariff and access regulation has implications for the governance of infrastructure more generally. As well as looking at the roles and functions of economic regulators, the report examines how economic regulators are involved in the infrastructure life cycle; the infrastructure needs of the industries they regulate; how they use data to support the delivery of their mandate; the extent to which their roles and func- tions have changed; the involvement of economic regulators in the policy pro- cess; and the challenges that economic regulators are currently facing in fulfilling their mandate. The study concludes that since economic regulators in different sectors face similar challenges, there is scope for them to work together to address them. Other findings include: flexibility can help economic regulators adapt to change; and the knowledge and experience of economic regulators should be used to develop and refine legislative frameworks for the regulation of infrastructure. Decision-making bodies and decision processes In many respects the literature on regulatory governance in relation to deci- sion-making bodies and decision processes overlaps with that on roles, functions and relationships, but with a greater emphasis on the design and evaluation of organizations and their internal decision processes. It varies in content from studies of whole-of-system bodies and processes to narrower, more in-depth studies of specific issues and challenges. Recuero Virto, Gasmi, and Noumba Um (2008) discuss the relationship between the quality of political and economic institutions and the performance of the reform process for infrastructure industries in developing countries. They examine the impact of the quality of institutions on the performance of regula- tion, finding that the political accountability of institutional systems is a key determinant of regulatory performance. Secondly, they examine the factors that shape sectoral reforms and the impact of these reforms on the development of the infrastructure industry. Their main conclusion is that countries’ institutional A Review of the Literature Related to Regulatory Governance | 161 environment and the cost of public funds are among the major factors that explain which reforms are actually implemented. Berg, Memon, and Skelton (2000) discuss the design and reform of independent regulatory commissions, setting out general guidelines and ­ ­ recommendations framed as a series of nine principles: communication, consul- tation, consistency, predictability, flexibility, independence, effectiveness/­ efficiency, accountability and transparency. It is argued that these principles can guide decisions on the basic design and structure of an independent commission, its jurisdiction and its key regulatory functions. The paper focuses on the elec- tricity sector, highlighting the ongoing nature of reform and the consequent need for adaptive regulatory agency structures to underpin long-term good practice. It draws on a wide range of country examples. The OECD’s study of regulatory enforcement and inspections (2014c) is part of a developing body of literature addressing the administration and enforcement stages of the regulatory cycle. It seeks to develop a framework to support improved regulatory enforcement, arguing that better-designed and targeted inspections processes make them more effective and efficient, less burdensome and less resource-demanding. It includes 11 principles to guide the design of the policies, institutions and tools to promote effective compliance and the process of reforming inspection services to achieve results. The principles are: evidence-based enforce- ment; selectivity; risk-focus and proportionality; responsive regulation; long-term vision; coordination and consolidation; transparent governance; information inte- gration; clear and fair process; compliance promotion; and professionalism. A second OECD study (2014b) has a broader scope, aiming to develop general governance principles applicable to a wide variety of regulators, whatever the breadth of their responsibilities. The focus of the study is on the effect of external governance arrangements on the performance of regulators, but some issues of internal governance are also addressed as the two aspects necessarily overlap. The study identifies seven principles of good governance: role clarity; preventing undue influence and maintaining trust; the structure of decision-making and governing bodies; accountability and transparency; engagement; funding; ­ and performance evaluation. These principles have been widely accepted and adopted and are used as a core element informing Parts B and C of this manual. Appeals and reviews of decisions Much of the research related to appeals and reviews of regulatory decisions is found in the legal literature, rather than that specifically addressing regulatory governance. It springs from the view that, while the independence of regulatory agencies is important to their credibility and performance, there is a clear need for a process of appeal from their decisions which is itself independent, to ensure they act lawfully and appropriately and within their legal mandate. This litera- ture argues that regulation is more credible where political and legal institutions are seen to be able to oversee and control the regulator’s exercise of discretion. Baldwin and Cave (1999) conduct a wide-ranging examination of the roles of legislative bodies, courts, central government departments, and local authorities in this regard, while Albon and Decker (2015), describe and assess the major issues related to the design of appeal and review processes, drawing on a litera- ture relating to 15 OECD members and their infrastructure industries. In partic- ular, they consider types of appeal mechanisms and forms of appeal. They find that rights to appeal regulatory decisions are common but that the design of such 162 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS arrangements varies widely. While neither Baldwin and Cave (1999), nor Albon and Decker (2015) provide much in the way of direct advice and recommenda- tions, the OECD (2014b) study noted above provides useful recommendations, drawn upon in the manual, regarding appeals and reviews. Accountability, transparency, credibility, and engagement The literature bearing on the four closely related topics of accountability, transpar- ency, credibility, and engagement often also addresses regulatory appeal and review mechanisms. A small but growing element examines these issues in the regulatory governance context. In essence, accountability and transparency is the obverse of regulatory independence, so that greater independence for regulators calls for more robust accountability and transparency mechanisms. Several studies argue for comprehensive accountability and transparency measures that enable the regulator’s performance to be assessed by the legislature or some other body, thus providing incentives for better regulatory performance. It is also argued that transparent accountability processes help boost regulated entities’ confidence in the regulatory regime, thereby leading to greater voluntary compliance. Greater trust and confidence in the regulatory environment can also reduce administrative costs for regulators and compliance costs for regulated entities. This literature also suggests several means for achieving and sustaining accountability, including: • publishing annual reports on performance, provided to the legislature; • publication of clear operational policies covering compliance, enforcement and decision reviews and guidance material; • disclosure by the regulator of what rules, data and other inputs are used to make decisions (other than where disclosure might lead to the “gaming” of the regulatory system by regulated entities); and • publication of the reasons for regulatory decisions in a timely, accessible manner. The OECD’s study of accountability and transparency (2016c) incorporates detailed case studies of four regulatory agencies. It recommends that govern- ments should be clear and transparent about what they expect of regulators, and what the latter can do to meet these expectations. Similarly, clarity as to the respective roles of ministries, other government agencies and regulators can help avoid coordination issues. Importantly, management must be committed to ensure that accountability and transparency are accepted throughout the orga- nization and to make coordination arrangements work in practice. The report concludes with nine “guiding lessons” for reformers. Deighton-Smith (2004) considers transparency as a core governance value and highlights the increasing recognition of its importance in OECD countries. However, the article concludes that, despite many new initiatives intended to enhance transparency, results have often fallen short of expectations. It exam- ines the reasons for the poor performance and suggests some solutions. These include focusing on the quality of individual transparency initiatives as well as on the level of integration of the different moves pursued, and the links between transparency initiatives and the regulatory process more broadly. In addition, attention must be paid to potential conflicts between transparency and other regulatory quality values, such as timely and responsive regulation, and any such conflicts should be managed to achieve a balanced outcome. A Review of the Literature Related to Regulatory Governance | 163 There is a rapidly growing literature related to credibility and engagement, though little relates directly to countries in fragility (see, for example, Alemanno 2014; Balla and Daniels 2007; Balla and Dudley 2014; Bertot et al. 2010; Cass 2006; Coglianese 2006; Grimmelikhuijsen and Meijer 2014; Lavrijssen and Vitez 2015; OECD 2001, 2009). Nash and Walters (2015) provide a useful review of much of that literature and the options available to regulators. The main conclu- sion reached is that there are no fixed formulae for success, as public engage- ment and transparency depend not just on the intrinsic characteristics of the methods used but also on external and internal factors that shape the context in which regulators act. Nonetheless, the authors propose five key principles: 1. Regulators can maximize the benefits and minimize the costs of public engagement and transparency if they apply these principles at the earliest stages of their decision-making, including the priority-setting stage. 2. Regulators can enhance the public’s perception of their legitimacy by actively listening to the public’s voice, showing respect, and providing reasons for their actions. 3. Regulators should be attentive to disparities in participation, and always strive to achieve a diversity of viewpoints and experience. 4. Regulators should be purpose-driven in choosing from among the options available to them, seeking to find the option that best suits those purposes and fits the context in which they will be applied; and 5. Regulators should seek to learn from their use of public engagement and transparency, investing in evaluation of their practices so as to facilitate an ongoing project of pragmatic experimentalism. In sum, there is a large literature related to accountability, transparency, credi- bility, engagement and the relationship between them. Most is general in nature, but there is a growing focus on the regulatory governance context, especially as regards the use of internet. The extent of the literature in relation to fragile states is far more limited and care has to be taken in drawing lessons for such situations. Funding Little research addresses the interaction between funding and regulatory gover- nance. What does exist is largely based on the assumption that inadequate fund- ing will lead to greater dependence on the few available funding sources, leading to undue influence being exercised and poorer regulatory governance. The Academy for Educational Development (2003), for example, summarizes essen- tial elements of the relationship between fiscal autonomy and the decision-­ making and planning independence of an energy regulatory authority. It makes several practical recommendations to promote fiscal autonomy, including: the use of a hybrid mechanism for funding; ensuring a correlation between the fund- ing mechanism and future plans; ensuring the hybrid mechanism has a sound legal basis; allocating funds to the agency on a predictable and stable basis and ensuring funding levels are free from outcome-based decision-making to ensure funding levels do not fluctuate. Kelley and Tenenbaum (2004) studied eight new regulatory commissions in the energy sector that were intended to encourage private investment in previ- ously largely state-owned infrastructure entities. It found the objectives of inde- pendence and accountability proved difficult to achieve in practice, leading the 164 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS authors to recommend a number of principles for the funding of such commis- sions, including: the level of funding should allow commissions to perform their assigned tasks; commissions should receive their funding from fees, charges and specific utility taxes rather than from general government budget allocations; the executive and legislative branches of the government must have the right to review the funding levels of commissions, which must be protected from political budget cuts motivated by unpopular commission decisions; commissions should have the legal right to impose penalties on regulated power enterprises, but should not be allowed to use penalties to augment their own budgets; and, in return for receiving greater financial independence than a normal government agency, commissions must be held accountable for their expenditures and performance. The OECD’s 2014b report provides a summary of the major issues related to the funding of regulatory governance and a detailed list of principles for estab- lishing a sound funding model, derived from a survey of regulators. The proposed principles provide a basis for evaluating existing funding structures ­ and, importantly, provide guidance on how to remedy identified deficiencies. In summary, they are that: funding levels should be sufficient to enable the regula- tor, operating efficiently, to fulfill the objectives set by government, including obligations imposed by other legislation; they should be transparent, efficient and as simple as possible; regulators should not set the level of their fees with- out arm’s-length oversight; and regulators should follow a defined process to obtain funding for major unanticipated court actions. Measuring and evaluating performance In this manual the terms evaluate, review and appraise are used as synonyms to refer to both ex ante and ex post examinations of systems of regulatory gover- nance. Such systems should be evaluated to see if they achieve their objectives effectively and efficiently. Performance evaluations can be conducted on a sys- tem-wide basis, or at a more targeted level. System-wide evaluations are costly and demanding, as well as time-consuming. They are also politically sensitive as, if successful, they provide detailed information, both positive and negative, on the performance of organizations and systems for which ministers and senior officials are responsible and accountable. Conversely, they can provide strategic insights and understanding of the interaction of different system elements that more piecemeal, or targeted, reviews are less likely to identify. The choice as to which type of review is required must take account of these characteristics. There is an extensive general literature on performance evaluation, but much of it focuses on the performance of employees, rather less on organizations and still less on system-wide regulatory governance. However, the assumptions underlying any form of performance evaluation are similar, regardless of the spe- cific focus of the evaluation. The literature on measuring regulatory governance performance has grown rapidly over the last 20 years, in part due to growing dissatisfaction with the increasingly market-based regulatory reform efforts introduced in the 1980s and 1990s, and has a particular focus on regulatory governance in relation to infra- structure industries. Stern and Holder (1999) discuss the main issues affecting the regulatory governance of infrastructure industries and their implications for regulatory practice. They derive six criteria for appraising performance. Among the main conclusions are the importance of structural liberalization as a catalyst for developing effective regulation as well as of transparency. The authors also A Review of the Literature Related to Regulatory Governance | 165 identify six core elements which, they argue, affect the governance properties of regulatory frameworks: clarity of roles and objectives; autonomy; participation; accountability; transparency; and predictability. The authors further provide a list of questions to be used to evaluate whether or not a regulatory system dis- plays the six core elements. Brown et al. (2006) produced a detailed and widely cited World Bank hand- book on evaluation for regulators with responsibility for infrastructure. They authors argue that regulatory systems require effective performance evaluation and the handbook provides detailed, step-by-step, practical guidance as to how to conduct basic, mid-level and in-depth evaluations of processes, institutions and regulatory content. Chapter 6 examines regulatory governance, with a major focus on the development and use of the independent regulator model to provide a set of criteria to guide evaluation. It notes, however, that the model is not nec- essarily the best in all situations. In common with Stern and Holder (1999) and Stern and Cubbin (2005), they also argue that any model adopted should closely align with the three “meta-principles” of credibility, legitimacy and transparency. Minogue and Cariño (2006) review regulatory reforms in developing coun- tries and argue that existing policy models of regulatory reform are inappropri- ate, ineffectual, and too narrowly conceived. Similarly, IFC (2010) reviewed the evidence for the impact of regulatory governance initiatives, and how regulatory governance tools had been applied in developing countries. They find that, for the most part, there is a lack of convincing evidence as to the impact of regula- tory governance reforms in developing countries. Effective systems of evaluation depend upon the development, implementa- tion and monitoring of appropriate performance indicators. The challenges of developing such indicators are considerable, but usefully reviewed by Kaufmann and Kraay (2008). OECD (2014c) also outlines a framework for regulatory policy evaluation, providing an overview of evaluation practices in OECD countries and a variety of examples. It is similar in its aims to Stern and Cubbin (2005), forming a part of the OECD program on Measuring Regulatory Performance, which aims to help countries demonstrate how improvements to regulatory gov- ernance deliver actual benefits to businesses and citizens. It describes how dif- ferent types of indicators can be used to create a broad measure of regulatory policy performance. CONCLUSIONS What can be learned from the literature in relation to regulatory governance? This review finds, first, that the empirical literature on the subject is limited, far smaller than that on governance in general, though rapidly growing. There is currently relatively little cross-fertilization between the more general gover- nance literature and that more specifically related to regulatory aspects. Second, the conceptual and theoretical literature on regulatory governance is also lim- ited, though growing and, while initially dominated by the economics of regula- tion, has grown to include a variety of inter-disciplinary perspectives. A great deal of the literature has been developed by the World Bank and the OECD. The third finding is that the literature on regulatory governance in fragile states and conflict-affected states is very limited, with the literature on regula- tory governance and infrastructure being the major focus of attention, 166 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS particularly in World Bank studies. Fourth, the literature on what are appropri- ate systems of regulatory governance for fragile and conflict-affected states is largely nonexistent, and there is also relatively little detailed work on the impor- tance of socio-economic, political and security issues in this context. Fifth, there is a small but growing, and highly interdependent literature that offers guidance principles for regulatory governance, notably from the OECD and World Bank. Sixth, for the most part, the guidance principles offered in the literature are based on independent regulator models of regulatory governance operating in market-based economies. Seventh, the guidance principles for regulatory gover- nance found in the literature are suggested for use, primarily, as a set of criteria against which to measure regulatory governance practice. However, they can also be used to help guide the implementation of reforms to regulatory gover- nance systems. Finally, and of particular importance to this manual, there is significant evi- dence that effective systems of regulatory governance have a positive impact on economic development. A growing number of sets of principles for improving regulatory governance is being developed, and although there is currently a lim- ited empirical base for this work, it is largely emerging in particular from the experiences of more developed states, notably OECD members. There have been very few evaluations of the impact or usefulness of the various principles found in the literature, yet there is a high degree of convergence in the advice provided and a clear congruence between that advice and the features of regulatory gov- ernance systems found in the most successful economies. While care is needed in translating this material into advice that is relevant to developing countries— and particularly to the fragile context—it provides a sound basis for assessing the reform experience of countries that have had success in exiting situations of fra- gility and are seeking to develop more specifically tailored advice that will meet needs of fragile countries more effectively. NOTE 1. The study was based on mixed-method empirical research carried out on nine public agen- cies in Lao People’s Democratic Republic, Sierra Leone, The Gambia, and Timor-Leste. REFERENCES Academy for Educational Development. 2003. Fiscal Autonomy Review: Comparative Study of Regulatory Fiscal Autonomy Around the World. Prepared for the Philippine Energy Regulatory Commission. http://regulationbodyofknowledge.org/wp-content​ /­uploads/2013/03/AcademyforEducationalDevelopment_Fiscal_Autonomy_Review.pdf. Albon, R., and C. Decker. 2015. “International Insights for the Better Economic Regulation of Infrastructure.” Australian Competition and Consumer Commission (ACCC)/Australian Energy Regulator (AER) Working Paper Series, Working Paper 10. https://www.accc.gov .au/system/files/International%20Insights%20for%20the%20Better%20Economic%20 Regulation%20of%20Infrastructure.pdf. Alemanno, A. 2014. “Stakeholder Engagement in Regulatory Policy.” Prepared for the 11th Meeting of the Regulatory Policy Committee, OECD Conference Centre, Paris, 3–4 November. Andrés, L. A., J. L. Guasch, and S. Lopez Azumendi. 2008. “Regulatory Governance and Sector Performance: Methodology and Evaluation for Electricity Distribution in Latin America.” Policy Research Working Paper 4494, World Bank, Washington, DC. A Review of the Literature Related to Regulatory Governance | 167 Andrés, L. A., J. L. Guasch, and S. Straub. 2007. “Do Regulation and Institutional Design Matter for Infrastructure Sector Performance?” Policy Research Working Paper, World Bank, Washington, DC. Andrés, L. A., J. Schwartz, and J. L. Guasch. 2013. Uncovering the Drivers of Utility Performance: Lessons from Latin America and the Caribbean on the Role of the Private Sector, Regulation, and Governance in the Power, Water, and Telecommunication Sectors. Washington, DC: World Bank. Baldwin, R., and M. Cave. 1999. Understanding Regulation: Theory, Strategy and Practice. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Balla, S. J., and B. M. Daniels. 2007. “Information Technology and Public Commenting on Agency Regulations.” Regulation & Governance 1 (1)1: 46–67. Balla, S. J., and S. E. Dudley. 2014. Stakeholder Participation and Regulatory Policymaking in the United States. Report for the OECD. Washington, DC: The George Washington University Regulatory Studies Center. Barma, N. H., E. Huybens, and L. Viñuela, eds. 2014. Institutions Taking Root: Building State Capacity in Challenging Contexts. Washington, DC: World Bank. Bartle, I., and P. Vass. 2007. “Independent Economic Regulation: A Reassessment of its Role in Sustainable Development.” Utilities Policy 15 (4): 261–69. Baudrier, A. 2001. “Independent Regulation and Telecommunications Performance in Developing Countries.” Paper prepared for the Annual ISNIE Conference: Institutions and Governance, Berkeley, California, USA, September 13–15. Berg, S. V., A. N. Memon, and R. Skelton. 2000. “Designing an Independent Regulatory Commission.” Working Paper 00-17, Public Utility Research Center, University of Florida. Bertot, J. C., P. T. Jaeger, S. Munson, and T. Glaisyer. 2010. “Engaging the Public in Open Government: Social Media Technology and Policy for Government Transparency.” http:// tmsp.umd.edu/TMSPreports_files/6.IEEE-Computer-TMSP-Government-Bertot​ -100817pdf.pdf. Branch, D., and N. Cheeseman. 2009. “Democratising, Sequencing and State Failure in Africa: Lessons from Kenya.” African Affairs 108 (430): 1–26. Brown, A. C., J. Stern, B. Tenenbaum, and D. Gencer. 2006. Handbook for Evaluating Infrastructure Regulatory Systems. Washington, DC: World Bank. http://documents​ .­worldbank.org/curated/en/428111468177849284/pdf/364990Handbook101OFFICIAL0U​ SE0ONLY1.pdf. Carment, D., Y. Samy, and J. Landry. 2013. “Transitioning Fragile States: A Sequencing Approach.” Fletcher Forum of World Affairs 37 (2): 125–51. Carothers, T. 2007. “How Democracies Emerge: The ‘Sequencing’ Fallacy.” Journal of Democracy 18 (1): 12–27. Carpenter, D., and D. A. Moss, eds. 2014. Preventing Regulatory Capture: Special Interest Influence and How to Limit It. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Cass, N. 2006. “Participatory-Deliberative Engagement: A Literature Review.” Working Paper 1.2, School of Environment and Development, Manchester University, Manchester. https:// core.ac.uk/download/pdf/16285075.pdf. Christoplos, I., K. Engstrand, and A. L. Hedqvist. 2014. “Capacity Development Literature Review.” UTV Working Paper 2014:1, Sida, Stockholm. http://www.sida.se/contentassets​ /­e152ed3b81ab4b9ebaf51362cc2721ea/capacity-development-literature-review_3761.pdf. Coglianese, C. 2006. “Citizen Participation in Rulemaking: Past, Present, and Future.” Duke Law Journal 55: 943–68. Cordova-Novion, C., and S. Jacobzone. 2011. “Strengthening the Institutional Setting for Regulatory Reform: The Experience from OECD Countries.” OECD Working Papers on Public Governance 19, OECD Publishing, Paris. Cubbin, J., and J. Stern. 2006. “The Impact of Regulatory Governance and Privatization on Electricity Industry Generation Capacity in Developing Economies.” World Bank Economic Review 20 (1): 115–41. Dal Bó, E. 2006. “Regulatory Capture: A Review.” Oxford Review of Economic Policy 22 (2): 203–25. 168 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS Deighton-Smith, R. 2004. “Regulatory Transparency in OECD Countries: Overview, Trends and Challenges.” Australian Journal of Public Administration 63 (1): 66–73. Diamond, J. 2012. “Guidance Note on Sequencing PFM Reforms.” EC (European Commission), IMF (International Monetary Fund), PEFA (Public Expenditure and Financial Accountability). PFM (Public Financial Management Blog). https://blog-pfm.imf.org/files​ /­guidance-note-on-sequencing-pfm-reforms.docx. Estache, A. 1997. “Designing Regulatory Institutions for Infrastructure: Lessons from Argentina.” In Public Policy for the Private Sector, Note 114. World Bank, Washington, DC. Estache, A., A. Goicoechea, and L. Trujillo. 2009. “Utilities Reforms and Corruption in Developing Countries.” Utilities Policy, 17 (2): 191–202. Estache, A., and L. Wren-Lewis. 2010. “On the Theory and Evidence on Regulation of Network Industries in Developing Countries.” In The Oxford Handbook of Regulation, edited by Robert Baldwin, Martin Cave, and Martin Lodge, 371–406. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Gilardi, F. 2002. “Policy Credibility and Delegation to Independent Regulatory Agencies: A Comparative Empirical Analysis.” Journal of European Public Policy 9 (6): 873–93. ———. 2008. Delegation in the Regulatory State: Independent Regulatory Agencies in Western Europe. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing. Grimmelikhuijsen, S., and A. Meijer. 2014. “Effects of Transparency on the Perceived Trustworthiness of a Government Organization: Evidence from an Online Experiment.” Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 24 (1): 137–57. Groom, E, J. Halpern, and D. Ehrhardt. 2006. “Explanatory Notes on Key Topics in the Regulation of Water and Sanitation Services.” Water Supply and Sanitation Sector Board Discussion Paper Series, Paper No. 6, World Bank, Washington, DC. Gutiérrez, L. H. 2003. “The Effect of Endogenous Regulation on Telecommunications Expansion and Efficiency in Latin America.” Journal of Regulatory Economics 23 (3): 257–86. Gutiérrez, L. H., and S. V. Berg. 2000. “Telecommunications Liberalization and Regulatory Governance: Lessons from Latin America.” Telecommunications Policy 24 (10–11): 865–84. Herbert, S. 2014. Sequencing Reforms in Fragile States: Topic Guide. Birmingham, UK: GSDRC, University of Birmingham. IFC (International Finance Corporation). 2010. Regulatory Governance in Developing Countries. Better Regulation for Growth: Governance Frameworks and Tools for Effective Regulatory Reform. Washington, DC: IFC. https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/bitstream/han- dle/10986/27881/556450WP0Box0349461B0GovReg01PUBLIC1. pdf?sequence=1&isAllowed=y. Jacobzone, S., F. Steiner, E. L. Ponton, and E. Job. 2010. “Assessing the Impact of Regulatory Management Systems: Preliminiary Statistical and Econometric Estimates.” OECD Working Papers on Public Governance 17, OECD Publishing, Paris. Johannsen, K. S. 2003. Regulatory Independence in Theory and Practice–A Survey of Independent Energy Regulators in Eight European Countries. Copenhagen: AKF Forgalet. Kaufmann, D., and A. Kraay. 2008. “Governance Indicators: Where Are We, Where Should We Be Going?” Policy Research Working Paper 4370, World Bank, Washington, DC. Kelley, E., and B. Tenenbaum. 2004. “Funding of Energy Regulatory Commissions.” Energy and Mining Sector Board Working Notes 30525, World Bank, Washington, DC. Kirkpatrick, C. 2014. “Assessing the Impact of Regulatory Reform in Developing Countries.” Public Administration and Development 34 (3): 162–68. Laffont, J.-J. 2005. Regulation and Development. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Lavrijssen, S., and B. Vitez. 2015. “The Principles of Good Regulation in the Water Sector.” TILEC Discussion Paper 2015-002. Tilburg Law and Economics Center (TILEC), Tilburg. Maiorano, F., and J. Stern. 2007. “Institutions and Telecommunications Infrastructure in Low and Middle-Income Countries: The Case of Mobile Telephony.” Utilities Policy 15 (3): 165–81. Minogue, M. and L. Cariño. 2006. “Introduction: Regulatory Governance in Developing Countries.” In Regulatory Governance in Developing Countries, edited by M. Minogue and L. Cariño. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing. A Review of the Literature Related to Regulatory Governance | 169 Nash, J., and D. E. Walters. 2015. “Public Engagement and Transparency in Regulation: A Field Guide to Regulatory Excellence.” Research Paper Prepared for the Penn Program on Regulation’s Best-in-Class Regulator Initiative, University of Pennsylvania Law School, Philadelphia. https://www.law.upenn.edu/live/files/4709-nashwalters-ppr-researchpaper​ 062015.pdf. OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). 2000. “Telecommunications Regulations: Institutional Structures and Responsibilities.” OECD Digital Economy Papers 48, OECD Publishing, Paris. ———. 2001. Citizens as Partners: Information, Consultation and Public Participation in Policy​ -Making. Paris: OECD Publishing. ———. 2009. Focus on Citizens: Public Engagement for Better Policy and Services. OECD Studies on Public Engagement. Paris: OECD Publishing. ———. 2013. “OECD Principles on Transparency and Integrity in Lobbying.” OECD, Paris. http:// www.oecd.org/gov/ethics/oecdprinciplesfortransparencyandintegrityinlobbying.htm. ———. 2014a. The Governance of Regulators. OECD Best Practice Principles for Regulatory Policy. Paris: OECD Publishing. http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264209015-en. ———. 2014b. OECD Framework for Regulatory Policy Evaluation. Paris: OECD Publishing. http:// dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264214453-en. ———. 2014c. Regulatory Enforcement and Inspections . OECD Best Practice Principles for /­ Regulatory Policy. Paris: OECD Publishing. https://www.oecd-ilibrary.org/governance​ reg ulatory-enforcement-and-inspections_9789264208117-en. ———. 2015. Policy Framework for Investment. Paris: OECD Publishing. http://dx.doi​ .org/10.1787/9789264208667-en. ———. 2016a. Driving Performance at Latvia’s Public Utilities Commission. The Governance of Regulators. Paris: OECD Publishing. http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264257962-en. ———. 2016b. Being an Independent Regulator. The Governance of Regulators. Paris: OECD Publishing. http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264255401-en. ———. 2016c. Governance of Regulators’ Practices: Accountability, Transparency and Co-ordination. The Governance of Regulators. Paris: OECD Publishing. http://dx.doi​ .org/10.1787/9789264255388-en. ———. 2017a. OECD Integrity Review of Mexico: Taking a Stronger Stance Against Corruption. OECD Public Governance Reviews. Paris: OECD Publishing. https://www.oecd-ilibrary​ .org/governance/oecd-integrity-review-of-mexico_9789264273207-en. ———. 2017b. Creating a Culture of Independence: Practical Guidance against Undue Influence. The Governance of Regulators. Paris: OECD Publishing. https://www.oecd-ilibrary.org​ /­governance/creating-a-culture-of-independence_9789264274198-en. ———. 2017c. The Role of Economic Regulators in the Governance of Infrastructure. The Governance of Regulators. Paris: OECD Publishing. http://dx.doi.org ​/ 10.1787​ /9789264272804-en. Painter, M. 2014. “Governance Reforms in China and Vietnam: Marketisation, Leapfrogging and Retro-Fitting.” Journal of Contemporary Asia 44 (2): 204–20. Rao, S. 2014. “Prioritising and Sequencing Public Sector Reform.” Helpdesk Research Report. GSDRC Applied Knowledge Services. http://gsdrc.org/docs/open/hdq1080.pdf. Recuero Virto, L., F. Gasmi, and P. Noumba Um. 2008. “The Role of Institutional Design in the Conduct of Infrastructure Industry Reforms: An Illustration through Telecommunications in Developing Countries.” MPRA Paper 28253. Southern African Journal of Information and Communication 9 (1): 4–16. https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/28253/. Rihani, S. 2002. Complex Systems Theory and Development Practice: Understanding Non-Linear Realities. London/New York: Zed Books. Roll, M. 2013. “Pockets of Effectiveness: Why Do Strong Public Institutions Exist in Weak States?” Paper prepared for the American Political Science Association (APSA) Annual Meeting, Chicago, August 29–September 1. Ros, A. J. 2003. “The Impact of the Regulatory Process and Price Cap Regulation in Latin American Telecommunications Markets.” Review of Network Economics 2 (3):1–17. 170 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS Smith, W. 1997. “Utility Regulators: The Independence Debate.” In Public Policy for the Private Sector, Note 127. World Bank, Washington, DC. Stern, J. 1997. “What Makes an Independent Regulator Independent?” Business Strategy Review 8 (2): 67–74. Stern, J., and J. Cubbin. 2005. “Regulatory Effectiveness: The Impact of Regulation and Regulatory Governance Arrangements on Electricity Industry Outcomes.” Policy Research Working Paper 3536, World Bank, Washington, DC. Stern, J., and S. Holder. 1999. Regulatory Governance: Criteria for Assessing the Performance of Regulatory Systems: An Application to Infrastructure Industries in the Developing Countries of Asia. Utilities Policy, 8 (1): 33–50. Tenenbaum, B. 1995. “The Real World of Power Sector Regulation.” Public Policy for the Private Sector, Note 50. World Bank, Washington, DC. Trillas, F., and M. A. Montoya. 2013. “Independent Regulators: Theory, Evidence and Reform Proposals.” Info 15 (3): 39–53. Wallsten, S. 2002. “Does Sequencing Matter? Regulation and Privatization in Telecommunications Reforms.” Policy Research Working Paper 2817, World Bank, Washington, DC. Waverman, L., and P. Koutroumpis. 2011. “Benchmarking Telecoms Regulation: The Telecommunications Regulatory Governance Index (TRGI).” Telecommunications Policy 35 (5): 450–68. C Developing a Government- Wide Regulatory Policy Gaining investor confidence in key infrastructure sectors requires establishing the credibility of the legal and regulatory system across a number of fields and adopting key reforms to infrastructure regulation. Where reform is needed, it is likely to be required across several infrastructure sectors in which many of the key challenges and priorities will be similar. Accordingly, the reform agenda is likely to be more effectively and rapidly implemented if it is guided by a consis- tent set of principles and approaches—in other words, a government-wide policy for regulatory governance. As well as helping to provide a template for imple- menting a reform agenda in various sectors, such a policy will send a strong sig- nal about the government’s commitment to reform to investors and businesses, particularly if they are given an opportunity to participate in the process of developing and implementing this policy. REGULATORY POLICIES AND INFRASTRUCTURE IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES Regulatory policies have been adopted by all OECD countries in one form or another but are less common in developing countries and are rare in low-income and post-fragile contexts. This likely reflects the fact that developing and imple- menting a fully developed regulatory governance policy requires relatively high- level capacities within government, which are unlikely to be present in an immediate, post-fragile context. However, while capacity constraints are likely to prevent a fully-articulated regulatory governance policy being implemented effectively in these situations, there are strong arguments for countries to adopt at least some of the key elements of regulatory governance policy at an early stage in the process of exiting situations of fragility. Indeed, there are specific elements of the post-fragile context that suggest that the potential benefits of adopting the key principles of a regulatory governance policy may be particu- larly significant. In particular: • A regulatory governance policy provides a template that can be used in the wide-ranging task of regulatory reconstruction/reform required in most post-fragile contexts.  171 172 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS • General agreement on broad principles and approaches to making and assess- ing regulation can support reformers in their attempts to apply these in spe- cific sectors—like infrastructure—in which there is likely to be self-interested opposition. In essence, reformers, if challenged, can refer to the agreement to support their decisions and activities. • Using a regulatory governance policy as a reform template helps promote consistency in regulatory approach between sectors, thus helping to mini- mize economic distortions. • Regulatory governance policy focuses on improving the policy development process, making it more systematic and efficient and minimizing reworking abandoned policy initiatives. As the system begins to become effective, it can often yield net cost savings in ministries, as well as improve policy outcomes. This is likely to be particularly important in an environment of very con- strained government budgets, as noted in box C.1. While relatively rare, as noted above, some post-fragile countries have adopted government-wide policies as the foundation for their regulatory reform activities. While few include a substantial focus on regulatory gover- nance, they do as a rule address the question of how governments will make, assess and revise regulation, usually with an emphasis on Regulatory Impact Assessment (RIA). These policies therefore represent an attempt to establish a policy framework that will systematically ensure high-quality regulation, thus supporting sector-specific reforms and contributing to good economic and social outcomes. Two recent examples are Georgia 1 and Kosovo 2 (see box C.2). BOX C.1 The costs of adopting a regulatory governance policy While regulatory governance policies seek to funda- medium-term outcome can be that regulatory devel- mentally change the way that governments make opment costs in departments actually fall, rather than laws, countries have usually found the direct costs of rise, as suggested above. This stems from the gains in implementing them to be relatively modest. effectiveness and efficiency achieved by the policy. The main direct costs involved are: Specific process requirements, such as the need to prepare written regulatory impact assessments 1. the development of the policy, including the and ensure they meet relevant quality standards do establishment and operation of a small, central unit have resource implications, but these have been to oversee and report on policy implementation; found to be relatively small. For example, one study 2. the work involved in training staff in departments found that, in Australia, the average labor cost to and agencies; departments and agencies preparing RIA for deci- 3. the work in implementing the policy as part of sion-makers averaged around US$3,500 per RIA regulatory development in departments and (World Bank 2010, 9), equivalent to less than 2 weeks agencies. of a policy official’s time. Moreover, these costs are While the first two costs are necessary investments offset by the wider efficiency gains that the RIA pro- in achieving better regulatory outcomes, the cess enables. Developing a Government-Wide Regulatory Policy | 173 BOX C.2 Better policy planning and Regulatory Impact Assessment in Georgia and Kosovo Recognizing the need for more evidence-based pol- 1. adopting a program of continuous reduction of icymaking and improved legislative drafting stan- administrative burdens, using the Standard Cost dards, the Government of Georgia approved the Model (SCM) methodology and the Doing Busi- Policy Planning System Reform Strategy 2015–17. ness indicators; This required the introduction of a more systematic 2. adopting a systematic process to identify priority process of policy and regulatory development, reforms of existing regulation, emphasizing the including Regulatory Impact Assessment into the use of ex post RIA; Georgian legislative process. The Department of 3. introducing RIA by integrating the requirement Policy Analysis, Strategic Planning and Coordination with the established system for developing “con- in the Prime Minister’s Office requested USAID’s cept documents” (or explanatory memoranda), for assistance in designing a national RIA framework. which policy development capacities will be sig- The Government also established the Investors’ nificantly increased; Council, which is expected to help develop a more 4. improving stakeholder consultation through effec- business-friendly regulatory framework over time tive outreach (including internationally) and pro- by acting as a systematic consultation and coopera- viding incentives for stakeholders to participate; tion mechanism, ensuring that private-sector views 5. improving policy communication based on are heard and taken into account in developing in-depth analysis of the current situation, to be reforms. presented in a concept document combined with The Government of Kosovo adopted a Better a specific action plan; Regulation Strategy in 2014 but experienced serious 6. improving incentives for institutional compliance issues with regards to its implementation. Problems with administrative procedures; and were caused by a lack of resources and overly ambi- 7. developing more realistic work planning that tious assumptions as to how the policy should be takes into account the time needed to conduct pol- designed and implemented. After a period of review, icy analysis and stakeholder consultation and is the Government decided to restructure the strategy in based on a concept document in which the design a more realistic fashion by: is elaborated. Sources: Republic of Kosovo 2014; USAID 2015. IMPACT ON INFRASTRUCTURE SECTOR REFORM EFFORTS Thus, a regulatory governance policy can play an important part in supporting national and/or sectoral infrastructure policies and plans, while streamlined versions of regulatory governance policy, such as that outlined in box C.3, can feasibly be implemented in post-fragile contexts, as the examples of Kosovo and Georgia demonstrate. Adopting this approach will: • enhance confidence among investors as to the government’s commitment to regulatory integrity; • promote consistency in regulatory approach between infrastructure sectors, thus helping to minimize economic distortions; and • provide a public statement of principles and approaches to making and assessing regulation that can support reformers in their attempts to apply these in infrastructure sectors. 174 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS BOX C.3 Elements of a basic, national regulatory governance policy statement 1. Adopt a whole-of-government policy on regula- c. Consultation should be undertaken with tion which recognizes that: those likely to be affected. This will both help a. Regulation has numerous unintended and governments obtain a better understanding often negative consequences. Accordingly, of the impacts of regulating and clarify what governments must carefully consider proposals support regulatory intervention would have. to regulate before adopting them. d. Consideration should be given to the use of b. Taking account of this, regulation should international standards and/or policy transfer only be adopted where there is a substantial in areas covered by the regulations and to problem to be addressed and other actions by whether these are appropriate for use in a low- government or private players are unlikely to income country context. address it. e. The expert advisory body should review 2. A small, expert advisory body should be estab- regulatory proposals and provide its opinion lished at the center of government to provide before they are considered for adoption by expert advice on new regulatory proposals, pri- the government. Opinions should address orities for reforming existing regulation and both the specific merits of the proposal and its assessments of regulatory governance. This implications for regulatory governance. body should report to a senior minister with 4. Government should endorse a set of regulatory specific responsibility for regulatory gover- governance principles that apply to all indepen- nance policy. dent and arm’s-length regulators such as those 3. Where regulation is to be used, government outlined in in Part B of this manual. should adopt a systematic approach to identifying 5. The expert advisory body on regulation should and weighing its likely benefits and costs. periodically assess the performance of sectors a. This should take account of environmental and where regulation has been recently reformed. social benefits and costs that cannot easily be 6. Governments should adopt a basic regulatory gov- weighed in cash terms, as well as economic ernance policy in the early post-fragile context costs. and should regularly consider the scope to expand b. The distribution of these costs should also be it to include other relevant elements as circum- considered. stances change. DEVELOPING A REGULATORY GOVERNANCE POLICY STATEMENT FOR THE WHOLE OF GOVERNMENT In fragile or post-fragile countries, reforms to the civil service, financial ­ management, procurement, decentralization and anti-corruption policies and programs are often underway at the same time, so the policy agenda is crowded as governments try to rebuild the economy with very limited resources. Adopting a strategic approach is therefore vital if support for a regulatory governance pol- icy is to be obtained. The following steps can help do that. Gain high level support and formal endorsement for the policy It is vital to gain high-level political and administrative support and formal pol- icy endorsement if reform is to be achieved. It may be more feasible and appro- priate to seek endorsement for the more limited goal of establishing a regulatory Developing a Government-Wide Regulatory Policy | 175 governance policy for the infrastructure sector as a whole, or for specific infra- structure industries, rather than for government as a whole. This support should, if possible, be formalized in legislation. If this is not pos- sible, it should be specified in a Presidential Decree, Prime Ministerial Instruction, Cabinet Handbook or other significant policy document. Whatever form it takes, it should prescribe the core elements of the regulatory governance policy, such as those listed in box C.2, although there should be a degree of flex- ibility so as to allow the policy to be amended if circumstances change. Develop the content of the policy for submission Box C.2 provides an indication of what a basic, national regulatory governance policy suitable for adoption in low-income and post-fragile contexts could include. It is based on the recommendations of the OECD and Asia-Pacific Economic Cooperation (APEC) in relation to regulatory governance policy, and the regula- tory reform policies adopted by countries such as Malaysia, Georgia, Rwanda and Kosovo. Even where agreement to adopt whole-of-government policy cannot be obtained, consideration should be given to adopting a basic set of regulatory ­governance principles, such as those outlined in Part B of this manual, which can function as a source of inputs for reformers in designing regulatory governance models (including governance models for regulators) in specific sectors. At the very least, a regulatory governance policy statement should indicate: • the aims of the policy and its relation to the government’s policy agenda; • which minister is to be responsible for the policy; • the regulatory principles for government; • the establishment of a small, expert unit of government responsible for administering the policy, its governance and reporting arrangements. Ideally it should be placed in the prime minister’s office, or that of another senior minister; • where it is not a fully national policy, which sectors are within scope; • a list of planned reforms with a brief explanation of their relationships to the overall objectives of the policy; • the estimated implementation capacity for each reform with associated costs and benefits; • the expected commitment to, support for, and opposition to, each reform; • the foreseeable risks involved; • a list of the major phases and timelines; • the deliverables to be achieved in each phase; • the major activities necessary for each deliverable; • the key milestones; • a list of who is to be responsible for the delivery of each major activity. As noted, the policy should also include the establishment of a small, expert body at the center of government to guide and support its implementation, par- ticularly by undertaking the following tasks: • provide expert advice to cabinet on new regulatory proposals; • provide advice to cabinet on reforming existing regulation; • provide cabinet with assessments of regulation and regulatory governance, using a prescribed but flexible methodology for estimating costs, benefits and likely environmental impacts, following systematic consultation with all ­relevant parties; 176 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS • have responsibility for gradually integrating the regulatory assessment pro- cess into the established, departmental policy and decision processes, as resources permit. This body should report to the senior minister with specific responsibility for regulatory governance policy. While statements of regulatory governance policy can have significant benefits, even in the low-income country context, it is important to recognize practical con- straints and avoid unrealistic expectations about the benefits of such policies. While broad policy statements can be expected to yield benefits over the medium- and long-term, it will often be difficult to point to major, concrete gains in the short term. Moreover, while these policies provide a sound template for improving the body of regulation and its administration by government over time, these benefits will only be obtained if the broader political and economic environment is characterized by at least basic levels of stability, capacity and government commitment to reform. Develop an implementation plan A broad implementation plan will be required to support any proposal to develop a regulatory governance policy and demonstrate the feasibility of the proposal. It should explain the relationship between the government’s objectives and the proposed regulatory governance policy outcomes, showing how the policy will help achieve the objectives. It should also identify: • the major implementation challenges; • timeframes and broad project phases; • the relationship, if any, between the regulatory governance policy and other policies, regulations and projects; • the likely resources needed; • governance arrangements that indicate who will be responsible for what major decisions; and • the consultations undertaken with stakeholders and their support for the project. Developing and putting into practice an implementation plan is a complex and challenging task that will be examined in more depth in the next chapter. THE ROLE OF A PERMANENT POLICY ADVISORY UNIT A permanent regulatory oversight (or regulatory policy advisory) unit is a key institution underpinning successful regulatory policy. The roles that these bod- ies typically perform, and their importance, were discussed in general terms above and in chapter 12. Such bodies should ideally be established at the earliest stages in the reform process, since their contributions are often particularly sig- nificant then. However, their importance during the policy implementation, review and revision stages is also crucial. A key role of these units is to help to maintain a strategic, whole-of-­government view of the reform agenda’s progress, assessing the performance of sectoral reforms, such as those relating to infrastructure industries, in the light of the government’s overall priorities, including those identified in the general regula- tory policy (if one has been adopted). This focus on the government’s strategic objectives and on coordination between the reforms being adopted in related Developing a Government-Wide Regulatory Policy | 177 sectors should help to establish and maintain consistent policy approaches and prevent distortions arising due to regulatory differences in related sectors (e.g., where gas and electricity are in competition). More generally, regulatory oversight bodies can act as champions of reform and strengthen the influence of pro-reform forces addressing individual-­ sector reform issues. This can include helping to further develop or refine s ­ ectoral reform policies and assist in achieving effective implementation (e.g., by provid- ing training to officials in key organizations), as well as strengthening the author- ity of sectoral regulators in their dealings with government and stakeholders. In a post-fragile environment, where newly adopted reforms may be under- cutting long-established systems of rent extraction, there will often be strong and sustained opposition lobbying. In the early stages of reform, in particular, where widespread benefits are not yet visible, such lobbying risks undermin- ing the reform program. This makes the role of center-of-government over- sight bodies in providing ongoing support for the reform agenda particularly important. Ensuring that these bodies are located at the center of government (e.g., in the President/Prime Minister’s Office or the Ministry of Finance) helps to maximize their effectiveness. Appointing a board with significant non-­ governmental representation and explicitly empowering the oversight body to speak publicly on reform priorities are also key strategies to maximize their influence in this area. In post-fragile contexts in particular, capacity development will be a key determinant of the success of reform programs over time. Capacity development is a primary need, as the progressive expansion of the reform agenda will impose continually increasing requirements in this area. As suggested above, regulatory oversight units typically take a lead role in developing capacity by offering train- ing to officials across government, developing guidance materials and undertak- ing quality control in relation to Regulatory Impact Assessment. NOTES 1. Policy Planning System Reform Strategy 2015–17, which prescribes the introduction of RIA into the Georgian legislative process. Additionally, the Government proposed to establish an Investors Council in 2017, which is expected to serve as a high-level cooperation plat- form for the public and private sectors in shaping a better and more business-friendly reg- ulatory framework. http://gov.ge/files/425_49310_540377_PolicyPlanningSystemReform​ StrategyandActionPlan.pdf. 2. Better Regulation Strategy 2014–2020 , outlining a revised strategy (Republic of Kosovo 2014). REFERENCES Republic of Kosovo. 2014. Better Regulation Strategy 2014–2020: Regulatory Impact  Assessment .  http://kryeministri-ks.net/repository/docs/Better_Regulation​ _­Strategy_2014_-_2020.pdf. USAID (United States Agency for International Development). 2015. Recommendations on RIA National Framework of Georgia. USAID, Governing for Growth (G4G) in Georgia. https://pdf.usaid.gov/pdf_docs/PA00KVD5.pdf. World Bank. 2010. Making It Work: ‘RIA Light’ For Developing Countries. Better Regulation for Growth: Governance Frameworks and Tools for Effective Regulatory Reform. Washington, DC: World Bank. http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/ en/184141468167049021/pdf/55636-WP-REPLACEMENT-RIALightNov2009.pdf. D Checklist of Anti-Corruption Risks1 1. Ambiguity a. Language i. Does the draft law choose the most precise word in all cases? (Word choice). ii. Do sentences and half-sentences relate to each other in a way that leaves no room for ambiguity? (Construction of sentences). b. Legal coherence i. Are there provisions in other laws that might conflict with the draft law? (Conflicting provisions). ii. Does one term have different meanings throughout the draft law or other laws? (Inconsistent terminology). iii. Is any reference to another law or instance possibly unclear to the reader? (Unclear references). iv. Did the drafters “forget” to cover all necessary aspects requiring regulation? (Regulatory gaps). ­ v. Does the draft law deviate from the uniform structure of laws for no reason? (Uniform structural laws). 2. Prevention gaps (public laws) a. Competencies i. Did the draft law “forget” to define a competent body for any of the tasks described? (Unidentified competencies). ii. Did the law “forget” to furnish the government body with any competencies? iii. If the law delegates the identification of the responsible government body to another regulation or instance—is there a clear timeline and is it clear which other official body exercises the tasks until the new body is identified? (Delayed identification). iv. If the draft introduces a new government body or new competencies— is it clear which other body exercises the tasks until the new entity is set up? (Delayed setting up). v. Does the draft delegate the regulation of central points to another body, which should actually be in the draft law itself? (Competency for ­further regulation). vi. Does the law create powers for one state body that overlap with the powers created by another law? (Overlapping competencies).  179 180 | GOVERNING INFRASTRUCTURE REGULATORS IN FRAGILE ENVIRONMENTS vii. If several state bodies have powers in implementing the law, are all competencies fully allocated to one of them and are no competencies “forgotten”? (Split competencies). viii. Does the draft touch on situations where the private interest of a public official may conflict with his/her official duties and, if so, do provisions on managing this conflict of interest apply under this or another law? (Conflict of interest). b. Powers and resource. It is important that a public body should have all the powers and resources needed to carry out its tasks. c. Procedures i. Are all steps of the procedure defined, not leaving their definition to the arbitrariness of a public official? (Undefined steps). ii. Is it unclear to citizens when they can claim their rights or when a pub- lic official has to fulfill his/her obligations? (Unidentified timelines). iii. Are fees undefined or not clearly calculable? (Unidentified fees). iv. Can a public official arbitrarily harass citizens with repeated inspec- tions for no clear reason? (Repetition of inspection). v. Does the law require citizens to seek approval from many different state bodies, thus increasing the chance of facilitation payments being sought? (Multi-stop procedures). vi. Does the law cover the distribution of limited state resources ( jobs, subsidies, etc.) and are the criteria and procedures fully transparent? (Competitions for limited state resources). d. Decisions. Does the law provide for excessive, unnecessary discretion? (Excessive discretion). e. Oversight i. Does the law provide for transparency in procedures and results, allow- ing citizens and the media to scrutinize them? (Transparency and civil society oversight). ii. Does the law avoid unnecessary concentration of power in one govern- ment body, one department or unit, or one public official? (Separation of tasks). iii. Does the law (or another applicable law) foresee rotation of staff in high-risk areas (e.g., procurement)? (Rotation). f. Sanctions. Are effective, proportionate and dissuasive sanctions available? g. Judicial review. Does the draft law make available to citizens clear, ­ comprehensive appeals procedures covering all possible grievances? h. Sector-specific safeguards. What risks specific to the particular sector covered by the draft law might not have been fully mitigated by the draft? 3. Addendum. Corrupted legislation—are there indications that a stakeholder has unfairly distorted free political competition in order to bend the wording of the draft law to his/her advantage? a. Illegal activities i. violation of lobbying rules by interest groups; ii. political finance violations by anybody profiting from a law; iii. procedural violations during the legislative process in particular on transparency; iv. ethical violations of legislators (such as provisions on conflict of interest); v. instances of bribery. Checklist of Anti-Corruption Risks1 | 181 b. Legal activities (that can still point to hidden corruption in the legislative process) i. suspicious privileges contained within a law (for certain interest groups); ii. large (but legal) financial donations by any individual or group profit- ing from a law; iii. extraordinary (legal) lobbying activities by interest groups; iv. lack of transparency of the legislative process (even if formally within legal limits); v. ethical challenges (despite compliance with rules); vi. obvious detriment to, or waste of, public funds. NOTE 1. Source: Hoppe 2017. REFERENCE Hoppe, T. 2017. Methodology for Corruption Proofing in Montenegro. Sarajevo: Regional Anti-Corruption Initiative (RAI). http://www.antikorupcija.me/media/documents/CP​ ­ _­Methodology_ENG.pdf. ECO-AUDIT Environmental Benefits Statement The World Bank Group is committed to reducing its environmental footprint. In support of this commitment, we leverage electronic publishing options and print- on-demand technology, which is located in regional hubs worldwide. Together, these initiatives enable print runs to be lowered and shipping distances decreased, resulting in reduced paper consumption, chemical use, greenhouse gas emissions, and waste. We follow the recommended standards for paper use set by the Green Press Initiative. The majority of our books are printed on Forest Stewardship Council (FSC)–certified paper, with nearly all containing 50–100 percent recycled content. The recycled fiber in our book paper is either unbleached or bleached using totally chlorine-free (TCF), processed chlorine–free (PCF), or enhanced elemental chlorine–free (EECF) processes. ­ More information about the Bank’s environmental philosophy can be found at http://www.worldbank.org/corporateresponsibility. C ountries exiting conflict and fragility face many urgent priorities and almost invariably suffer from substantial infrastructure deficits. There is typically very of governance principles can be less costly and complex for governments to implement and enforce and will provide potential investors with a more consistent and little infrastructure investment during periods of fragility predictable regulatory environment to navigate. The and conflict, and existing installations are often manual also discusses the process of implementing damaged or destroyed. The purpose of this manual is to regulatory governance reforms in fragile contexts. contribute to improvements in the quality of Improvements in governance frameworks for infrastructure regulation. It does so by identifying key infrastructure regulators will support better and principles for the governance of infrastructure regulators accountable regulatory decision-making, as well as and by suggesting how these principles can be increased investment and overall economic introduced successfully and maintained over time. The development. Case studies from relevant country introduction of cross-cutting governance principles for experience complement and ­ provide context to the regulators is based on the assumption that a uniform set discussion on principles. ISBN 978-1-4648-1434-1 SKU 211434