Policy Research Working Paper 8784 Why Do Fiscal Multipliers Depend on Fiscal Positions? Raju Huidrom M. Ayhan Kose Jamus J. Lim Franziska L. Ohnsorge Macroeconomics, Trade and Investment Global Practice March 2019 Policy Research Working Paper 8784 Abstract The fiscal position can affect fiscal multipliers through two concerns about sovereign credit risk, raises economy-wide channels. Through the Ricardian channel, households borrowing cost, and reduces private domestic demand. The reduce consumption in anticipation of future fiscal adjust- paper documents empirically the relevance of these two ments when fiscal stimulus is implemented from a weak channels using an Interactive Panel Vector Auto Regression fiscal position. Through the interest rate channel, fiscal model. It finds that fiscal multipliers tend to be smaller stimulus from a weak fiscal position heightens investors’ when fiscal positions are weak than strong. This paper is a product of the Macroeconomics, Trade and Investment Global Practice. It is part of a larger effort by the World Bank to provide open access to its research and make a contribution to development policy discussions around the world. Policy Research Working Papers are also posted on the Web at http://www.worldbank.org/research. The authors may be contacted at rhuidrom@imf.org, akose@worldbank.org, jamus.lim@essec.edu, and fohnsorge@worldbank.org. The Policy Research Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange of ideas about development issues. An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished. The papers carry the names of the authors and should be cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the views of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/World Bank and its affiliated organizations, or those of the Executive Directors of the World Bank or the governments they represent. Produced by the Research Support Team Why Do Fiscal Multipliers Depend on Fiscal Positions? ∗ Raju Huidrom, M. Ayhan Kose, Jamus J. Lim, and Franziska L. Ohnsorge Key Words: Fiscal multipliers, fiscal position, state-dependency, Ricardian channel, interest rate channel, business cycle. JEL Codes: E62, H50, H60 ∗ Huidrom: International Monetary Fund; rhuidrom@imf.org. Kose: World Bank, Prospects Group; Brookings Institution; CEPR; and CAMA; akose@worldbank.org. Lim: Essec Business School; jamus.lim@essec.edu. Ohnsorge: World Bank, Prospects Group; and CAMA; fohnsorge@worldbank.org. We greatly appreciate Ricardo Reis (editor) for his detailed comments that significantly improved the paper. We also would like to thank referees for many useful suggestions. Earlier drafts benefited from comments by S. Amer Ahmed, Jean-Louis Arcand, Raphael Espinoza, Alejandro Izquierdo, Aart Kraay, Sergio Kurlat, Jaime Marquez, Rahul Mukherjee, Ugo Panizza, Assaf Razin, Naotaka Sugawara, Luis Serven, Cedric Tille, Carlos Vegh, Guillermo Vuletin, Sebastian Weber, Kei-Mu Yi, Hakan Yilmazkuday, Charles Wyplosz, and seminar participants at the Graduate Institute-Geneva, the 2015 Midwest Macro Conference, and the 2016 Conference on Fiscal Policy and the Macroeconomy at Johns Hopkins SAIS. We thank Kiwako Sakamoto for excellent research assistance. Ethan Ilzetski kindly shared data. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are those of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the views of the institutions they are affiliated with. 1. Introduction During the Great Recession of 2008-09, many countries deployed fiscal policy to support activity. As a result, government debt increased in a number of countries, and it remains elevated (Kose et al., 2017). There is mounting empirical evidence that weak fiscal positions erode the effectiveness of fiscal policy in stimulating the economy, although the channels through which this mechanism operates have not yet been systematically explored. The objective of this paper is to fill this gap in the literature by answering the question: why do fiscal multipliers depend on fiscal positions? In theory, the fiscal position can affect the size of fiscal multipliers through two specific channels. First, a Ricardian channel: when a government with a weak fiscal position implements fiscal stimulus, households expect tax increases sooner than in an economy with a strong fiscal position (Blanchard 1990a and 1990b; Sutherland 1997). The perceived negative wealth effect leads households to cut consumption and save more, thereby weakening the impact of the stimulus on output. Thus, the net effect of fiscal policy on output—the size of the fiscal multiplier—may be smaller in an economy with a weaker fiscal position. Second, an interest rate channel: when the fiscal position is weak, fiscal stimulus can increase lenders’ concerns about sovereign credit risk. This raises sovereign bond yields and hence, borrowing costs across the whole economy (Corsetti et al. 2013). This, in turn, crowds out private investment and consumption, reducing the size of the fiscal multiplier. Therefore, in theory, both channels imply that fiscal policy is less effective when fiscal stimulus is implemented from a weak initial fiscal position. 1 To analyze the relevance of the channels through which the fiscal position affects fiscal multipliers, we use an Interacted Panel Vector Autoregressive (IPVAR) model. The model is essentially an extension of an otherwise standard panel structural VAR (SVAR), with the distinction that the VAR coefficients interact with (observable) state variables. Consequently, these coefficients become time-varying, and evolve endogenously according to these states. This results in a framework where the VAR dynamics and hence, the fiscal multipliers are conditional on the state variables which we take to be the fiscal position. 2 Since the state-dependency is captured by making use of the full sample, the model allows us to maintain sufficient degrees of freedom to draw sharp inferences. It also allows us to trace out the fiscal multipliers as a function of a continuum of government debt, rather than relative to ad hoc debt thresholds. In addition, our framework extends the suite of models – from Smooth Transition Regressions (Auerbach and Gorodnichenko 2012) or local projections (Auerbach and Gorodnichenko 2013, Riera-Crichton, Vegh and Vuletin 2015) – that are used in the literature to estimate state-dependent multipliers. Applying our empirical methodology to a large dataset that covers 34 countries (19 advanced and 15 developing), at the quarterly frequency over the period 1980:1 to 2014:1, we first establish that the fiscal position helps determine the size of the fiscal multipliers: estimated multipliers are systematically smaller when the fiscal position is weak (i.e. government debt is high). We then 1 In a theoretical model, Sutherland (1997) formalizes the Ricardian channel by postulating that there exists a debt threshold at which the government makes fiscal adjustments, via increasing taxes, to remain solvent. Thus, households expect higher taxes to be more imminent when the government conducts an expansionary fiscal policy from a high initial level of debt. In Perotti (1999), such expectations of higher taxes can also result in increased tax distortions which are an additional source of negative wealth effects. With regard to the interest rate channel, Bi, Shen, and Yang (2014) theoretically establish that sovereign risk premia can increase nonlinearly as government indebtedness rises. Corsetti et al. (2013) highlight that the interest rate is particularly relevant for the effectiveness of fiscal policy when monetary policy is constrained, for instance during a zero lower bound episode. 2 The model was originally used to estimate the impact of exchange rate fluctuations on output conditioning on foreign currency debt and import structure (Towbin and Weber 2013) or to estimate the impact of capital flows on OECD housing markets conditioning on mortgage market characteristics (Sa, Towbin, and Wieladek 2014). 1 employ a model that includes both the Ricardian and interest rate channels to provide evidence that such state-dependent effects operate through these two channels. In particular, we show that when a government with weak public finances conducts expansionary fiscal policy, the private sector scales back on consumption in anticipation of future tax pressures (Ricardian channel) and risk premia rise on mounting concerns about sovereign risk (interest rate channel). Our paper presents the first systematic empirical study on the relevance of the two theoretical channels through which the fiscal position affects the size of fiscal multipliers. It builds on two interrelated branches of the literature. The first branch focuses on the importance of fiscal positions for fiscal multipliers. Ilzetzki, Mendoza, and Vegh (2013), Nickel and Tudyka (2014), and Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2012 and 2013) estimate multipliers that depend on the fiscal position and find that weaker fiscal positions are associated with smaller fiscal multipliers. However, none of these studies examines jointly the two channels through which the fiscal position affects multipliers. The other branch of the literature considers the relevance of the two channels. Blanchard (1990a) sketches out a theoretical model of Ricardian consumers who, after a fiscal stimulus, cut back consumption in anticipation of future tax hikes. Others document empirically that the effect of government spending shocks on private consumption depends on government debt (Perotti 1999, Giavazzi and Pagano 1990 and 1996). However, none of these studies present a systematic empirical assessment of implications for the channels as well as output. Our paper extends the limited set of studies on the Ricardian channel in several dimensions. First, the IPVAR, unlike panel regressions, is a multivariate model that allows us to trace the dynamic effects of fiscal shocks not only on private consumption—as a mechanism for a government’s fiscal position to matter for multipliers—but also on output. Second, we employ a model that allows us to examine the relevance of the Ricardian and interest rate channels together in a much larger sample of countries and longer series. A couple of recent studies examine the interest rate channel. Corsetti et al. (2013) model the role of investor perceptions of sovereign risks and, calibrating their dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model to the United States, illustrate smaller fiscal multipliers when government debt is high. Bocola (2016), using a structural model, estimates that a higher probability of sovereign default raised risk premia for corporate lending and reduced credit to firms in Italy during the sovereign debt crisis. These studies illustrate the workings of the interest rate channel, i.e. how output effects of fiscal stimulus could be eroded during times of high debt. Our reduced-form approach contributes to this literature by providing an empirical assessment of the interest rate channel for a wide range of countries in a model that also includes the Ricardian channel. Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2017) take the first step towards exploring the interest rate channel by estimating the impact of fiscal policy shocks on activity and credit default swap spreads (not on private consumption) in a local projections model for a sample of 20 OECD countries. They report no statistically significant difference between fiscal multipliers depending on government debt. Nor do they find a statistically significant effect of fiscal stimulus on credit risk premia but rather a statistically significant decline in short-term interest rates. They interpret this as evidence that fiscal stimulus remains an effective tool for boosting growth and that the penalty from rising borrowing cost is small. The divergence in the results of Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2017) from those in Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2013) may reflect two factors. First, Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2017) add a number of control variables, such as interest rates, that may reduce degrees of freedom, introduce multicollinearity with credit spreads and lower the statistical significance of the estimated response of credit spreads. Second, they redefine the conditioning 2 variable as demeaned government debt (instead of government debt) and, thus, remove all cross- country variation from a variable that, to begin with, has limited across-time variation. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents the econometric methodology, identification strategy, and database. We present estimates of state-dependent multipliers in Section 3.1 and analyze the roles of the Ricardian and the interest rate channels in Section 3.2. Section 4 discusses a rich menu of robustness exercises. Section 5 concludes. 2. Empirical Methodology and Database Our empirical approach requires several choices that may affect the results. These are explained in this section, together with a discussion of our database. 2.1. Econometric Model: We use an Interacted Panel Vector Autoregressive (IPVAR) model where the main innovation, with respect to a standard panel SVAR, is that the model coefficients vary deterministically according to conditioning (state) variables. By choosing the conditioning variable to be a measure of fiscal position in the IPVAR, we estimate multipliers that depend on the fiscal position. The IPVAR model, in its structural form, is represented by: 11 12 14 1 0 0 0 , , ⋯ , ⎤ − ⎡ 21 ⎡ 1 0 0⎤ 21 ⎢, 22 , ⋯ 24 , ⎥ − ⎢ 0, ⎥ ∑ ⎢031 32 0 1 ⎥ � 0 � = =1 ⎢ ⋮ 34 ⎥ � − � + + , (1) ⎢ 41 , , ⎥ ⋮ ⋱ , ⎥ 42 43 ⎢ − ⎣ 0, 0, 0, 1⎦ 41 ⎣, 42 , ⋯ 44 , ⎦ where for a given country i in period t, gc represents real government consumption, gdp real gross domestic product (GDP), reer the real effective exchange rate, and ca the current account balance (as a share of GDP). We take government consumption as the fiscal instrument and track the effects of fiscal policy in terms of GDP. The real effective exchange rate and the current account are also included in the model to account for open-economy features that characterize most of the countries in our sample. The matrix X captures additional controls, which include time-invariant country fixed effects, and U is a vector of uncorrelated, i.i.d. (structural) shocks. The shock corresponding to government consumption is the fiscal shock. We set the lag length as L = 4 which is standard for VAR models with quarterly data but we also test for robustness to different lag lengths in Section 4. The impact matrix 0 (matrix of coefficients on the left-hand side of Equation (1)) is lower triangular. This, along with the ordering of the variables in the VAR, is related to our identification scheme (discussed below). Both the impact matrix 0 and the coefficient matrices , = 1, … , (on the right-hand side of Equation (1)) comprise time-varying model coefficients that, for any given entry in row and column , evolve deterministically according to: , = 1, + 2, , (2) 3 refers to the fiscal position. 3 Our measure of the fiscal position is the government debt-to-GDP ratio. While the literature has used a variety of measures, our choice is in line with theoretical models, where government debt is the modal state variable (as discussed below). 4 Since measures of the fiscal position are endogenous and move in tandem with the business cycle, we take lagged moving averages of our fiscal measures to control for business cycle effects. 5 The matrices , = 1, … , determine the effects of structural shocks on the dynamics of endogenous variables in the VAR system. By conditioning the law of motion of the coefficients in these matrices on the fiscal position, as in Equation (2), we are allowing those effects to depend on the fiscal position. This scheme allows us to calculate impulse responses and hence estimates of fiscal multipliers conditional on a specific fiscal position. As standard in the literature, we compute the cumulative fiscal multiplier at horizon T as the discounted cumulative change in output until horizon , as the discounted cumulative government consumption increases by one unit. That is, ∑ − =0(1+ ) ∆ () = ∑ − , (3) =0(1+ ) ∆ where denotes the interest rate. We utilize the median short-term rate in the sample. From (3), the impact multiplier is obtained by setting = 0 and the long-run multiplier by setting T at an arbitrarily large number, which is taken to be = 20 (5 years). To calculate the fiscal multiplier using the coefficient estimates from the IPVAR, we first cumulate the discounted impulses of output and government consumption at different horizons and compute the ratio of the two impulses. That ratio is then multiplied by the average government consumption-to-GDP ratio in the sample to yield multipliers. Since the conditional multipliers are estimated from the panel of countries, they reflect an average estimate across those countries included in the panel. Thus, we use the average government consumption-to-GDP ratio in the sample to calculate the multipliers rather than country-specific government consumption-to-GDP ratios. Equations (1) and (2) jointly denote the IPVAR system that is estimated with ordinary least squares (OLS) applied separately to each equation. 6 This yields model coefficients that depend on the fiscal position such that a given level of the fiscal position maps out to a set of model coefficients. For presenting the results, we evaluate model coefficients at specific values of the fiscal position which are mostly taken to be the 10th and 90th percentiles within the sample. Confidence bands are calculated by bootstrapping over 300 iterations. We report median estimates, along with the 16 - 84 percent confidence bands. 3 Including the fiscal position in the law of motion in Equation (2) is tantamount to having interaction terms with the fiscal position in the regressors of Equation (1). For this reason, we do not separately include the fiscal position as an endogenous variable in the IPVAR. 4 For instance, while Riera-Crichton, Vegh, and Vuletin (2015) condition multipliers on fiscal balances, Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2013), Ilzetzki, Mendoza, and Vegh (2013), and Nickel and Tudyka (2014) condition on government debt. 5 In particular, we take the 5-quarter moving average of the fiscal position, and then lag it by 2 quarters. Given the average length of the business cycle, this effectively allows us to abstract from changes in the fiscal state that may potentially be contaminated by cyclical movements. We allay any residual endogeneity concerns by jointly conditioning on the fiscal position and the phase of the business cycle below. 6 Because the error terms are uncorrelated across equations by construction, estimating the IPVAR equation by equation does not result in loss of efficiency. See Towbin and Weber (2013) for a discussion. 4 2.2. Choice of Fiscal Instrument and Fiscal Position: Our selection of government consumption as the fiscal instrument reflects several considerations. Government consumption is a subset of the much broader measure of government spending that strips out the automatic stabilizers component, and hence represents discretionary fiscal policy. We recognize, however, that government consumption plays a modest role in large discretionary fiscal stimulus programs, such as those implemented in 2008-10, or discretionary consolidation packages. Such large packages, on the spending side, are often predominantly based on government investment and transfers (OECD 2009). Government investment could be an ideal fiscal instrument, in principle, to model large discretionary policies but, in practice, available quarterly data is insufficient to establish robust results. In addition, in our sample, government investment is relatively small, averaging only about one-quarter of government consumption. Hence, we choose government consumption as a fiscal instrument that is quantitatively large over the full sample period and available for many economies. 7 On the tax side, the ideal measure to represent discretionary fiscal policy would be tax rates. However, consistent measures of tax rates across countries are not readily available. Tax revenues, even though they are easily available, are highly procyclical and less suitable for our study. Our selection of government debt as the conditioning state of fiscal position is motivated by the fact that in theoretical dynamic models that feature a fiscal sector, government debt is a state variable that enters as a lagged variable due to the flow budget constraint of the government (Galí, López-Salido, and Vallés 2007; Forni, Monteforte, and Sessa 2009; Davig and Leeper 2011). Moreover, in these models, nonlinear dynamics would depend on the initial state of government debt (and other state variables in the model). By conditioning on debt, our empirical approach attempts to match this theoretical aspect, and measures the effects of fiscal shocks conditional on the initial level of government debt. The IPVAR model does not allow for endogenous feedback loops after the fiscal shock. Such feedback loops could be an important consideration because debt dynamics can feed into government spending, especially during times of unstable debt (Favero and Giavazzi 2007). Thus, the omission of such endogenous feedback loops could bias multipliers, even though the direction and the size of the bias is hard to pin down since multipliers are a function of both government spending and output. That said, any bias is likely to be larger over longer time horizons because debt stocks move slowly. Hence, we focus our analysis on shorter-run multipliers, i.e. multipliers up to two years. We also conduct a robustness exercise in Section 4 to analyze the impact of debt dynamics on our findings. 2.3. Identification: Given the challenges associated with identification of fiscal shocks, we consider a multi-pronged approach to identification. First, we carefully motivate our baseline identification that follows the standard Blanchard-Perotti scheme. Second, we consider an alternative identification following Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2013) to check the robustness of our headline findings. Third, we consider alternative identifications and explain why we are unable to employ them in our exercise. Baseline identification. Our baseline estimation relies on the standard recursive identification scheme of Blanchard and Perotti (2002). The key timing assumption in this scheme is that discretionary fiscal policy does not respond to macroeconomic conditions within the same quarter. Such a timing assumption can be motivated by implementation lags typically associated with 7 Government consumption is also chosen by Ilzetzki, Mendoza and Vegh (2013), Nickell and Tudyka (2014), and Corsetti et al. (2012) whereas Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2013 and 2017) use the sum of government consumption and investment, but for a smaller sample of countries. 5 discretionary fiscal policy. In the VAR model, this timing assumption is achieved by ordering government consumption first in Equation (1), before GDP. Since the IPVAR model conditions its dynamics on government debt, it is important to understand how debt dynamics could perturb the identifying assumption for government consumption and output. There are two key issues in this context. First, we are implicitly assuming that the lagged response of government consumption to macroeconomic conditions does not depend on the initial level of government debt. 8 Second, debt dynamics, as mentioned earlier, can feed into government consumption and output and hence can affect the timing assumption. However, given the slow-moving nature of debt and given that Blanchard and Perotti (2002) is essentially a short-run identification, concerns about misidentification due to the absence of feedback loops are limited, at least in the short run. The timing assumption for the remaining variables is the following. Output is assumed to be, contemporaneously, independent from real exchange rates and current account balances in the same quarter. We assume that the output impact of current account balances and real effective exchange rates takes at least one quarter to occur. We order current account balances before exchange rates but the relative ordering of these two is immaterial for the results as we show in Section 4. To assess the relevance of the Ricardian and the interest rate channels, we augment the baseline model with private consumption and CDS spreads. In the augmented model, we order private consumption between government consumption and output, and CDS spreads last. This ordering scheme preserves the lagged response of government consumption to output which is the key identifying assumption of Blanchard-Perotti scheme. Ordering private consumption before output assumes that private consumption contemporaneously affects output, while output affects private consumption only with a lag of one quarter. The former is consistent with simple national account identities, and the latter may be justified in terms of households adjusting their consumption gradually to changes in incomes. Regarding CDS spreads, it is standard in the literature to order interest rates and spreads last since they typically respond fastest (e.g. Gilchrist and Zakrajšek 2012). One caveat of the recursive identification scheme is that the fiscal shocks identified using the Blanchard-Perotti scheme may be predicted by private forecasts (Ramey 2011). Born, Juessen, and Muller (2013), in the context of OECD countries, investigate this aspect formally by explicitly controlling for anticipated changes in government spending using a panel VAR identified with a similar timing assumption. While their model does not include interaction terms with government debt, they find that explicitly controlling for anticipation effects has little bearing on fiscal multipliers. Arguably, fiscal policy is particularly erratic in developing economies, which are heavily represented in our sample; hence, our identified fiscal shocks are less likely to be affected by anticipation issues (Ilzetzki, Mendoza, and Vegh 2013). An alternative identification scheme. Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2012 and 2013) proxy exogenous fiscal shocks by forecast errors of government consumption for OECD countries. This alternative identification circumvents some of the caveats associated with recursive identification and one that is available for a broad sample of OECD countries. As a robustness check in Section 4, we use the same approach and find broadly consistent results. 8 Auerbach and Gorodnochenko (2012) make a similar assumption: the lagged response of fiscal policy to macroeconomic conditions, i.e. Blanchard-Perotti identification, holds irrespective of the phase of the business cycle. 6 Other possible identification approaches. For example, Favero and Giavazzi (2010) note that impact estimates of fiscal policy are larger when fiscal shocks are identified in a narrative approach than when they are identified in a VAR framework. Romer and Romer (2010) use a narrative approach to identify exogenous fiscal shocks for the United States. For a broader set of countries, Guajardo, Leigh, and Pescatori (2014) and Gupta et al. (2017) have compiled data for fiscal consolidation episodes. However, we would not necessarily expect the interest rate channel, especially, to operate during a fiscal consolidation if investors remain cautiously risk averse during consolidations, whereas their risk aversion may lead them to respond sharply to fiscal stimulus. Hence, a dataset of fiscal consolidations is less useful for our purposes. 2.4 Database: Our main database comprises an unbalanced panel that covers 34 countries (19 advanced and 15 developing), at the quarterly frequency over the period 1980:1 to 2014:1. Real government consumption and real GDP are based on the quarterly database in Ilzetzki, Mendoza, and Vegh (2013) which are extended to 2014:1 by splicing data from the OECD and Haver Analytics. Real effective exchange rates are from the narrow (wherever available) and broad indices of the BIS, and current account balances are from Haver Analytics. The short-term rate used for discounting the multiplier is drawn mainly from the IMF-IFS database. We obtain quarterly real private consumption and private investment series from the OECD, Haver Analytics, and Eurostat. CDS spreads are in basis points and taken from Kose et al. (2017). We draw the conditioning variable (government debt as percentage of GDP) from the IMF-WEO database. 9 The government consumption, private consumption and GDP series are converted into logarithmic form, and detrended using a linear quadratic trend. The exchange rate is transformed into quarter-on-quarter growth rates, and the current account series is seasonally-adjusted using the X11 routine. All these series are detrended and demeaned on a country-by-country basis, which effectively controls for country fixed effects in the regressions. 3. Results This section presents the results of our empirical exercise. We first document our evidence for the presence of the Ricardian and interest rate channels. We also discuss the implications of these channels for fiscal multipliers that are contingent on the initial fiscal position. 3.1 Fiscal Position-Dependent Multipliers: We first briefly present the set of estimated fiscal multipliers that depend on government debt—our measure of the fiscal position. 10 Figure 1 shows that there is a systematic link between the size of the multiplier and the fiscal position: the median value of the multiplier decreases monotonically in debt, for all horizons reported. That is, the estimated multipliers for all the horizons are positive and significant for low levels of debt, but turn negative or insignificant when debt levels are high. For instance, the two-year multiplier is about 0.6 when debt is low (10th percentile in the sample, i.e. a “strong” fiscal position) and near- zero when debt is high (90th percentile in the sample, i.e. “weak” fiscal position). The difference in the estimated multipliers for low and high levels of debt remains significant at longer horizons. Our empirical results therefore lend support to the theoretical insights of earlier studies which show that a weak fiscal position can result in stronger crowding-out effects, blunting the 9 Details on the sample are provided in Table 1. The sources and definitions of our data are provided in the Supplementary Appendix (Table A.1). 10 We also examine the unconditional multipliers using a standard panel SVAR. We provide details of these results in the Supplementary Appendix Figure A.1 and A.2. The estimates suggest that unconditional multipliers are, on average, insignificantly different from zero. 7 stimulative effects of fiscal policy (Sutherland 1997; Perotti 1999; Corsetti et al. 2013; Bi, Shen, and Yang 2014). We next examine the conditional impulse responses associated with expansionary fiscal policy in Figure 2 to get a better understanding of the intuition behind these results. For the purpose of illustration, we consider impulse responses conditional on two levels of debt: one corresponding to the strong fiscal position and the other corresponds to the weak fiscal position. 11 For comparability, the shock size in each case is normalized such that government consumption rises by 1 percentage point on impact. While output increases on impact and remains significantly positive for around 2 years when the fiscal position is strong, such stimulative effects dissipate after about a year when the fiscal position is weak. In the case of government consumption, the conditional impulses for both strong and weak fiscal positions exhibit some persistence in response to the positive fiscal shock. However, fiscal expansion is more quickly unwound when the fiscal position is strong than weak. In other words, relative to the strong fiscal position, the government in fact spends more, especially initially, when the fiscal position is weak. Despite this, output falls more when the fiscal position is weak. These results are consistent with findings of several other empirical studies. For example, Ilzetzki, Mendoza and Vegh (2013) find that fiscal multipliers are lower in countries with debt levels above 60 percent of GDP. Nickell and Tudyka (2014), using a similar methodology to ours but with annual data, find that fiscal multipliers are larger in advanced economies with lower debt. Using a local projections model for OECD countries, Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2013) also find that, pre-crisis, fiscal multipliers from aggregate government consumption and investment shocks diminished, even in deep recessions, when government debt rose. 12 While these studies document the importance of fiscal positions for fiscal multipliers, they are silent about the empirical relevance of the theoretical channels through which the fiscal position affects multipliers. In the next section, we extend our model to study the relevance of the two channels in a unified framework. 3.2 Why Does The Fiscal Position Matter? Ricardian Channel and Interest Rate Channel We explore the empirical relevance of the two channels through which fiscal positions may impact fiscal multipliers: a Ricardian channel and an interest rate channel. The Ricardian channel has been explored in an older literature on the impact of fiscal policy on private consumption (Giavazzi and Pagano 1990, Blanchard 1990a and 1990b, Bertola and Drazen 1993, Perotti 1999). For example, Giavazzi and Pagano (1990) argue that unexpectedly high consumption in Ireland and Denmark in the late 1980s can partially be attributed to households’ response to government spending cuts that signaled lower future tax burdens. Conversely, the decline in private consumption following the large fiscal expansion in Sweden in the early 1990s may reflect similar Ricardian considerations (Giavazzi and Pagano 1996). Perotti (1999), using a single-equation framework with measures of fiscal position as interaction terms, estimates the impact of government expenditures on private consumption in OECD countries during the three decades ending in the mid-1990s, and finds that the impact varies with the initial level of government debt. Compared to his work, the multivariate framework of the IPVAR allows us to evaluate how fiscal position determines not only the fiscal impact on private consumption but also on output. 11 Figure A.3 in the Supplementary Appendix provides the distribution of government debt-to-GDP ratio in our sample. Table A.2 provides the specific percentile values from the sample. 12 As noted earlier, Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2017) report no statistically significant difference between fiscal multipliers depending on government debt in their sample of OECD countries. Similarly, using annual data, Corsetti, Meier, and Muller (2012) find only statistically insignificant differences between fiscal multipliers depending on different levels of debt (and a number of other conditioning variables). Their generally weak results may reflect the challenges of using the timing assumption of Blanchard and Perotti (2002) for identifying fiscal shocks in annual data as discussed in Perotti (2008). 8 We use the framework to bridge the response of consumption and output to fiscal shocks, thereby explicitly establishing the relevance of Ricardian considerations (i.e. private consumption effects) as a mechanism for a government’s fiscal position to matter for fiscal multipliers (i.e. output effects). Moreover, we use a much broader sample of countries and cover more recent data than Perotti (1999). In theory, the interest rate channel operates through risk premia charged by risk averse investors. For example, Corsetti et al. (2013) employ a DSGE model in which sovereign risk premia rise (i.e. rising CDS spreads), in response to a deteriorating fiscal outlook of an economy (i.e. rising government debt) which then raises the economy’s overall borrowing costs. The closer to sovereign default, the greater the likelihood of tax increases and expenditure cuts that will erode firms’ profitability and households’ incomes. The resulting decline in private sector aggregate demand reduces the size of the multiplier. Given these theoretical insights, our main contribution is to provide an empirical assessment of the interest rate channel. 13 To show the relevance of the Ricardian and interest rate channels, we augment the baseline model with private consumption and CDS spreads. As discussed in Section 2, we order private consumption between government consumption and output, and CDS spreads last in the model. Including both variables allows us to assess the relevance of the two channels together in a “joint” model. However, the inclusion of CDS spreads significantly limits the sample: it removes observations before 2003 and those for 5 countries. To assess the relevance of the Ricardian channel, which can be studied using a larger sample, we also estimate the model with each channel separately. In fact, the model with only the Ricardian channel results in about twice the number of observations from the joint model that includes both channels. For these “separate” models, we retain the respective ordering of private consumption and CDS spreads as in the joint model. We find statistically significant evidence that both channels operate in our sample. The upper two panels of Figure 3 show the impulse responses of private consumption and CDS spreads in response to a positive government consumption shock. Again, economies with weak fiscal positions are those with government debt in the 90th percentile in the sample; those with strong fiscal positions are economies with government debt in the 10th percentile. A fiscal stimulus in an economy with weak fiscal positions is associated with significantly lower private consumption for up to four years whereas a stimulus in an economy with strong fiscal positions significantly lifts private consumption for up to two years. The difference in the responses of private consumption is statistically significant, in the second and third year after the fiscal stimulus. A fiscal stimulus also raises CDS spreads significantly in an economy with weak fiscal positions for several years after the stimulus. In contrast, in economies with strong fiscal positions, CDS spreads typically do not respond statistically significantly to fiscal stimulus. Again, the difference between the responses of CDS spreads across two fiscal positions is statistically significant. The lower two panels of Figure 3 illustrate fiscal multipliers, on impact and after two years, conditional on government debt. Impact fiscal multipliers range from about 0.2 for low government debt to virtually nil when government debt is high. Over time, after two years, these multipliers rise to 0.9 when government debt is low (in the 10th percentile) but about half as large (0.5) when debt is high (in the 90th percentile). Allowing for feedback loops with government consumption and CDS spreads has resulted in slightly larger fiscal multipliers when debt is low compared to the model that does not include them (Figure 1). This reflects the boost to private consumption that fiscal stimulus provides: when debt is low, there is limited need for precautionary household 13 There is a rich literature on the link between sovereign defaults and fiscal position, i.e. the level of debt (e.g. Arellano 2008; Mendoza and Yue 2012). Our paper studies how such linkages matter for the transmission of fiscal policy. 9 savings (the Ricardian channel) and for rising sovereign risk premia (the interest rate channel). The differential impulse responses of private consumption and CDS spreads during times of high and low debt, and the corresponding multiplier estimates together highlight the relevance of the Ricardian and interest rate channels in explaining why government debt matters for the magnitude of fiscal multipliers. We then analyze the relevance of the Ricardian and the interest rate channels in models that are separately estimated. The left panel of Figure 4 shows the impulse responses of private consumption to a positive fiscal shock in a model that only includes private consumption (in addition to the baseline variables). The right panel shows the corresponding impact on CDS spreads in the model that only includes CDS spreads (in addition to the baseline variables). The responses of private consumption and CDS spreads from separate models are strikingly similar to those from the joint model (Figure 3). Private consumption falls when fiscal stimulus is implemented amid weak fiscal positions and rises otherwise; CDS spreads rise following stimulus amid weak fiscal positions and remain broadly constant otherwise. Compared with the response from the joint model (in Figure 3), the response of CDS spreads to a fiscal shock is almost identical in the separate model that excludes private consumption. In the broader sample that is unconstrained by data requirements for CDS spreads, the responses of private consumption are somewhat more muted but still statistically significantly different between strong and weak fiscal positions. 14 4. Robustness Exercises We consider a number of exercises to check the robustness of our headline findings about the empirical relevance of the Ricardian and the interest rate channels: (i) alternative samples of countries and time periods; (ii) changes in lag length; (iii) alternative ordering of some variables in the IPVAR; (iv) alternative definition of fiscal position; (v) alternative identification scheme; (vi) controlling for the phases of business cycles, financial crises, and exchange rate regimes; and (vii) controlling for debt dynamics. As mentioned earlier, data for CDS spreads are sparse and inclusion of CDS spreads in the joint model results in a significant loss of degrees of freedom. For the subsamples, we employ the joint model but restrict our analysis to the advanced economies and the post-crisis period. In some other robustness exercises, we employ the model with only the Ricardian channel because of data limitations. 4.1. Alternative samples and changes in lag length: Figure 5 present the impulse responses of private consumption and CDS spreads for weak and strong fiscal positions in different samples and lag structures using the joint model that includes both private consumption and CDS spreads. 15 Like before, weak and strong fiscal positions are taken to be government debt corresponding to the 10th (strong) and 90th (weak) percentiles from the sample. 16 By and large, our baseline results are qualitatively similar when the sample is restricted to advanced economies, the post-crisis years from 2009 onwards, and when shorter or longer lags are considered. That is, 14 The corresponding impacts on output, i.e. fiscal multipliers, as estimated separately from the Ricardian model and the interest rate model are also quite similar to the ones estimated from the joint model (Figure 3, panel (B)). More importantly, fiscal multipliers remain dependent on government debt. See Figure A.4 in the Supplementary Appendix. 15 Figure A.5 in the Supplementary Appendix present additional findings. 16 To ensure that we are not reporting outliers, we also present results (in Figure A.5 in the Supplementary Appendix) for alternative cut-offs: 25th percentile for low debt and 75th percentile for high debt. 10 impulse responses of private consumption are systematically weaker and those of CDS spreads stronger for weak fiscal positions than for strong fiscal positions. 17 4.2. Alternative ordering of variables and definition of fiscal position: The ordering of government consumption before output is key to the Blanchard and Perotti (2002) identification we used in Section 3. Ordering CDS spreads last in VAR models is standard as well. Keeping these orderings intact, we report results for alternative orderings among the rest of the model variables: ordering private consumption after output, and current accounts after exchange rates. In addition, we redefine the fiscal position of a country as the deviation of its government debt from the respective group-specific or country-specific average which reflects a notion of fiscal position that is relative to its peers or its historical average. The headline results hold for alternative orderings of model variables or when the alternative measure of fiscal position is used. That said, in some instances (except when restricting the sample to advanced economies and focusing on the post-crisis period), the statistical significance of the difference between fiscal multipliers across different fiscal positions naturally diminishes as degrees of freedom shrink. 18 4.3. Alternative identification scheme: We consider an alternative identification scheme based on forecast errors as in Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2013) and using the local projections model to trace the effects of fiscal shocks. Fiscal shocks are based on the one-year ahead forecast errors from the OECD’s semi-annual Economic Outlook, available for 19 advanced and emerging market economies at semi-annual frequency during 2004H1-2011H2. We then trace the effects of these shocks on key model variables using the local projections framework as in Jorda (2005). Specifically, we estimate a single-equation model, using ordinary least squares, each for output, private consumption, and CDS spreads. The model for output is: Yi,t+h = αih + Πh(L) Yi,t-1 + Ψh(L) Gi,t-1 + Φ h(L) FEitG + Ηh (L)FEitG Qit-1 + µh Qit-1 + Ωh(L) Ci,t-1 + Θh(L) CDSi,t-1 + uit (5) where Y is log real output, G is log real government consumption, C is real private consumption, CDS is CDS spreads, FE is the unpredicted forecast error from OECD, and Q is government debt. The model includes 2 lags (i.e. one year, since the data is semi-annual). The coefficients (Φ + Ξ ∗ Q) represents an impulse response that traces out the impact of fiscal shocks on output over the horizon h, conditional on government debt. As in Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2013), the forecast errors are defined as the unpredicted portion of the actual OECD forecast errors, i.e. the residuals from a regression of OECD forecast errors on the other independent variables of equation (5). Figure 6 shows the impact of fiscal shocks on fiscal multipliers and on private consumption conditional on fiscal positions, when fiscal shocks are identified as forecast errors of government consumption. A weak fiscal position is defined as government debt in the 90th percentile of the sample while a strong fiscal position is defined as government debt in the 10th percentile. As before, the output response of fiscal shocks is smaller when fiscal positions are weaker. This is partly attributable to a contraction in private consumption when a fiscal shock is implemented in a country with a weak fiscal position. Our results also indicate that impulse responses of CDS spreads are not meaningfully different when fiscal positions are weak or strong. 17 Figure A.6 in the Supplementary Appendix summarizes the estimates of fiscal multipliers that correspond to Figure 5 and Figure A.5 of the Supplementary Appendix. Again, the multipliers are systematically larger for low government debt (strong fiscal position) than high government debt (weak fiscal position). 18 Results are shown in Figure A.7 of the Supplementary Appendix. 11 4.4. Business cycle phases, financial crises, and exchange rate regimes: Given theoretical and empirical grounds that multipliers can be different across the phases of business cycles, during financial crises, and across exchange rate regimes, we conduct additional exercises to check whether our results are robust to controlling for these aspects. The fiscal position could be systematically weaker during recessions than expansions. In that case, the effects we attribute to the fiscal position would merely reflect well-established effects of business cycles on fiscal multipliers (Auerbach and Gorodnichenko 2012 and 2013). For financial crises, specifically, previous studies suggest that the correlation between financial crises and high debt episodes could strengthen or weaken our results. The presence of credit constrained households and firms, caused by disruptions in access to credit during crises, could be expected to raise fiscal multipliers. 19 In this case, prima facie, financial crisis episodes should be episodes of large fiscal multipliers. On the other hand, the presence of highly risk averse households that build precautionary savings in financial crises could reduce fiscal multipliers (de Paoli and Zabcyk 2013). This would argue for financial crises episodes being episodes of smaller fiscal multipliers. In flexible exchange rate regimes, the exchange rate may act as a buffer to dampen output effects of fiscal shocks compared with fixed exchange rate regimes. The sparse data for CDS spreads—delaying the sample’s start to around 2003 (a period during which exchange rate regimes were largely unchanged), and the recessions and financial crises to the financial crisis and global recession of 2008-09—restricts our ability to conduct these additional robustness exercises using the joint model. To relieve these degrees-of-freedom constraints, the additional robustness tests were carried out by dropping CDS spreads from the model and including only private consumption—i.e. we focus only on the Ricardian channel. To estimate fiscal multipliers conditional on the fiscal position while controlling for business cycle effects, we replace Equation (2) by the following expression that jointly conditions the model coefficients on both the fiscal position and the business cycle state as follows: , = 1, + 2, + 3, , (6) where bc is an indicator variable that equals 1 for recessions and 0 for expansions as determined by the Harding-Pagan (2002) dating algorithm. 20 We undertake a similar approach to control for financial crises and exchange rate regimes, and include the respective dummies in the equation above. Financial crises are defined as in Laeven and Valencia (2013). The fixed exchange rate regime is defined as in Ilzetzki, Mendoza and Vegh (2013), extended using the IMF’s de facto exchange rate classification. Figure 7 shows the impulse responses of private consumption in response to fiscal shocks in these exercises. Private consumption responds more negatively to positive fiscal shocks when fiscal positions are weak than when they are strong. The difference in private consumption response between strong and weak fiscal positions is statistically significant at some intermediate horizons. This suggests that the fiscal position genuinely represents a different conditioning state that determines fiscal multipliers rather than capturing other correlates such as business cycle effects, 19 See Spilimbergo, Symanski, and Schindler (2009); Zubairy (2014); and Eggertsson and Krugman (2012). 20 In our sample, there is little overlap between recessions and high debt episodes. Recessions and weak fiscal positions coincide in only 2 percent of observations (Table A.3 of Supplementary Appendix). On average, debt ratios also do not differ meaningfully between economic expansions and recessions: The average debt-to-GDP ratio during economic expansion is 52 percent, compared to 54 percent during recessions. 12 financial crises, and exchange rate regimes. 21 We also study the corresponding fiscal multipliers on impact and after two years, depending on fiscal positions, in these exercises. 22 Fiscal multipliers, especially at the two-year horizon, are larger in recessions than expansions, in crises than in non- crises, and in flexible exchange rate regimes than in fixed exchange rate regimes. These findings are consistent with others in the literature (Auerbach and Gorodnichenko 2013; Bachmann and Sims 2012; Candelon and Lieb 2013; Ilzetzki, Mendoza and Vegh 2013). The main takeaway from these exercises is that fiscal multipliers remain debt-dependent: they are larger when fiscal positions are strong, although sometimes not statistically significantly so. 4.5. Debt dynamics: As discussed in Section 2, our IPVAR framework considers the state- dependent effects of initial level of government debt, but it does not allow for endogenous feedback loops from government debt to model variables which could then result in biased estimates of multipliers. Such feedback loops are, however, expected to play a significant role during times of unstable debt. Thus, one way to guard against this potential bias is to estimate the model using a sample that exhibits relatively stable debt dynamics. Accordingly, we present estimates for a sub-sample of advanced economies during 1980-2006. 23 Our results indicate that, mitigating concerns about potential biases caused by endogenous debt, multipliers are also larger when fiscal positions are strong in a sample of advanced economies with low and stable debt. 24 In addition, to check for potential nonlinearities in the role of government debt, we also estimate the joint model by including quadratic debt (in place of linear debt) in the law of motion of the coefficients (in Equation 6). Our headline result remains intact: fiscal multipliers are higher when fiscal positions are strong than when positions are weak. 5. Comparison with previously estimated fiscal multipliers Our results from the benchmark model suggest that two-year fiscal multipliers can range from nil when government debt is high (in the 90th percentile, i.e. above 92 percent of GDP) to 0.6 when government debt is low (in the 10th percentile, i.e. below 17 percent of GDP). When controlling for both transmission channels, these multipliers rise somewhat to range from 0.5 when debt is high to 0.9 when debt is low. During recessions, two-year fiscal multipliers in low-debt countries can reach 1.5. The magnitude of our estimated multipliers conditional on government debt is higher than previous estimates, which are typically negative, when government debt is high and somewhat lower when government debt is low (Table 2). Nickell and Tudyka (2014) estimate an impact multiplier around 1.2 that fades gradually to near-zero if government debt remains below 60 percent of GDP. In contrast, at higher levels of government debt, the impact of stimulus on de- trended GDP turns statistically significantly negative over the longer-term. Ilzetzki, Mendoza and Vegh (2013) similarly estimate a negative cumulative longrun multiplier (of -3) when government debt exceeds 60 percent of GDP and insignificantly different from zero when government debt is lower. The findings of Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2017) contrast with these earlier studies that find significantly negative fiscal multipliers if government debt is high. Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2017), while not providing explicit multiplier estimates, find that a 1 percent 21 When the model with the Ricardian channel only is estimated with the restricted sample of the joint model in section 3,2 and Figure 3, the results are broadly robust (see Supplementary Appendix Figure A.4). 22 We present these results in Supplementary Appendix Figures A.8 and A.9. As a benchmark, the first two columns of Figure A.8 show the fiscal multipliers in the full sample, allowing only for Ricardian effects and disregarding the interest rate channel (as in the left chart of Figure 4). 23 During 1980-2006, government debt in most advanced economies was on a broadly low and stable path. We remove we remove Canada, Italy and Belgium that exhibited high debt levels throughout the sample period. 24 We present these results in Figure A.8 in the Supplementary Appendix. 13 increase in government spending raises real GDP statistically significantly over the long term when government debt is at its (country-specific) minimum and has only insignificant effects when government debt is at its (country-specific) maximum. In general, these conditional multipliers suggested by our results as well as previous studies conditioning on government debt are somewhat smaller than those estimated in studies that condition on other factors (Table 2). Especially recent studies that condition on recessions have found at times very large multipliers in advanced economies. Several have estimated peak fiscal multipliers during recessions in the range of 3-4 (Bachmann and Sims 2012, Auerbach and Gorodnichenko 2012 and 2013, Candelon and Lieb 2013). In a literature survey of earlier U.S. evidence, Ramey (2011) puts multipliers during a severe recession “at the upper bound of this [0.8-1.5] range,” notwithstanding considerable uncertainty about the estimates. Much of this evidence rests on U.S. data. However, in Europe as well, during the 2009-11 recessions in the wake of the global financial crisis, fiscal stimulus packages have been attributed with multipliers above 1 (Blanchard and Leigh 2014). 25 When we condition our multiplier estimates on recessions as well as government debt, we also find that multipliers can be above 1, at least for countries in the bottom quintile of government debt. 26 6. Conclusion A growing literature has documented how weaker government finances reduce the effectiveness of fiscal policy, i.e. fiscal multipliers. In this paper, we complement this literature by analyzing the empirical relevance of the two theoretical channels through which the fiscal position impacts the size of fiscal multipliers. Specifically, we study the Ricardian channel where households reduce consumption in anticipation of future fiscal adjustments during times of high debt; and the interest rate channel where increased investors’ perception of credit risks, raises sovereign credit risk and economy-wide borrowing cost, thereby weakening private domestic demand. We deploy an empirical model that allows us to trace the effects of fiscal shocks not only on private consumption and CDS spreads (as a measure of risk premia) but also on output. By bridging the response of consumption, CDS spreads and output to fiscal shocks, we explicitly establish the relevance of Ricardian and interest rate considerations (i.e. private consumption and borrowing cost effects) as the two channels for a government’s fiscal position to matter for fiscal multipliers (i.e. output effects). We also undertake a wide range of exercises to show the robustness of our findings with respect to the relevance of these channels. Future research can usefully focus on three issues. First, while some earlier theoretical studies considered each channel separately, there has been no study exploring how the two channels operate jointly in a general equilibrium framework. This type of work could provide insights about the relative strength of each channel in response to different types of shocks. Second, one could study whether the two channels function differently in open economies in the context of a multi- country DSGE model. Finally, it would be useful to study the relevance of the two channels in a framework that allows fiscal-monetary policy interactions. In particular, one can assess how the use of monetary policy affects the roles of the two channels during periods of weak fiscal position. 25 Conversely, OECD fiscal consolidation packages have been estimated to have long-term multipliers close to 2 (Favero, Giavazzi and Perego 2011). 26 Four EU countries in the sample entered the 2008-09 recession with general government debt in the bottom quintile of the sample. 14 References Alesina, A., C. Favero and F. Giavazzi. 2015. “The Output Effect of Fiscal Consolidation Plans.” Journal of International Economics 96: S19-S42. Arellano, C. 2008. “Default Risk and Income Fluctuations in Emerging Economies.” American Economic Review 98(3): 690–712. Auerbach, A. J., and Y. Gorodnichenko. 2012. “Measuring the Output Responses to Fiscal Policy.” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 4(2): 1–27. Auerbach, A. J., and Y. Gorodnichenko. 2013. “Fiscal Multipliers in Recession and Expansion.” In Fiscal Policy after the Financial Crisis, edited by A. Alesina and F. Giavazzi, 63–98. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Auerbach, A. J., and Y. Gorodnichenko. 2017. “Fiscal Stimulus and Fiscal Sustainability.” NBER Working Paper 23789, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge. Bachmann, R., and E. R. Sims. 2012. “Confidence and the Transmission of Government Spending Shocks.” Journal of Monetary Economics 59(3): 235–249. Bertola, G., and A. Drazen. 1993. “Trigger Points and Budget Cuts: Explaining the Effects of Fiscal Austerity.” American Economic Review 83(1): 11–26 Bi, H., W. Shen, and S.-C. S. Yang. 2014. “Fiscal Limits, External Debt, and Fiscal Policy in Developing Countries.” IMF Working Paper 14/49, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC. Blanchard, O. J. 1990a. “Comment: Can Severe Fiscal Contractions Be Expansionary? Tales of Two Small European Countries.” In NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1990, Volume 5, edited by O. J. Blanchard and S. Fischer, 111–116. Cambridge: MIT Press. Blanchard, O. J. 1990b. “Suggestions for a New Set of Fiscal Indicators.” OECD Economics Department Working Paper 79, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, Paris. Blanchard, O.J. and D. Leigh. 2013. “Growth Forecast Errors and Fiscal Multipliers.” American Economic Review 103(3): 117-20. Blanchard, O., and R. Perotti. 2002. “An Empirical Characterization of the Dynamic Effects of Changes in Government Spending and Taxes on Output.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 117(4): 1329–1368. Bocola, L. 2016. “The Pass-Through of Sovereign Risks.” Journal of Political Economy 124(4): 879–926. Born, B., F. Juessen, and G. J. Müller. 2013. “Exchange Rate Regimes and Fiscal Multipliers.” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 37(2): 446–465. Candelon, B., and L. Lieb. 2013. “Fiscal Policy in Good and Bad Times.” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 37(12): 2679–2694. Corsetti, G., K. Kuester, A. Meier, and G. J. Müller. 2013. “Sovereign Risk, Fiscal Policy, and Macroeconomic Stability.” Economic Journal 123(566): F99–F132. Corsetti, G., A. Meier, and G. J. Müller. 2012. “Fiscal Stimulus with Spending Reversals.” Review of Economics and Statistics 94(4): 878–895. Davig, T., and E. M. Leeper. 2011. “Monetary–Fiscal Policy Interactions and Fiscal Stimulus.” European Economic Review 55(2): 211–227. 15 De Paoli, B., and P. Zabczyk. 2013. “Cyclical Risk Aversion, Precautionary Saving, and Monetary Policy.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 45(1): 1–36. Eggertsson, G. B., and P. Krugman. 2012. “Debt, Deleveraging, and the Liquidity Trap: A Fisher- Minsky-Koo Approach.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 127(3): 1469–1513. Fatás, A. and I. Mihov. 2009. “Why Fiscal Stimulus is Likely to Work.” International Finance 12(1): 57-73. Favero, C., and F. Giavazzi. 2007. “Debt and the Effects of Fiscal Policy.” NBER Working Paper 12822, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge. Favero, C. A., and F. Giavazzi. 2010. “Reconciling VAR-Based and Narrative Measures of the Tax-Multiplier.” CEPR Discussion Paper 7769, Centre for Economic Policy Research, London. Favero, C., F. Giavazzi and J. Perego. 2011. “Country Heterogeneity and the International Evidence on the Effects of Fiscal Policy.” IMF Economic Review 59(4): 652-682. Forni, L., L. Monteforte, and L. Sessa. 2009. “The General Equilibrium Effects of Fiscal Policy: Estimates for the Euro Area.” Journal of Public Economics 93(3–4): 559–585. Galí, J., J. D. López-Salido, and J. Vallés. 2007. “Understanding the Effects of Government Spending on Consumption.” Journal of the European Economic Association 5(1): 227–270. Giavazzi, F., and M. Pagano. 1990. “Can Severe Fiscal Contractions Be Expansionary? Tales of Two Small European Countries.” In NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1990, Volume 5, edited by O. J. Blanchard and S. Fischer, 75–111. Cambridge: MIT Press. Giavazzi, F., and M. Pagano. 1996. “Non-Keynesian Effects of Fiscal Policy Changes: International Evidence and the Swedish Experience.” Swedish Economic Policy Review 3(1): 67– 103. Gilchrist, S., and E. Zakrajšek. 2012. “Credit Spreads and Business Cycle Fluctuations.” American Economic Review 102(4): 1692–1720. Guajardo, J., D. Leigh, and A. Pescatori. 2014. “Expansionary Austerity? International Evidence.” Journal of the European Economic Association 12(4): 949–968. Gupta, S., J. T. Jalles, C. Mulas-Granados, and M. Schena. 2017. “Governments and Promised Fiscal Consolidations: Do They Mean What They Say?” IMF Working Paper 17/39, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC. Harding, D., and A. Pagan. 2002. “Dissecting the Cycle: A Methodological Investigation.” Journal of Monetary Economics 49(2): 365–381. Ilzetzki, E., E. G. Mendoza, and C. A. Végh. 2013. “How Big (Small?) are Fiscal Multipliers?” Journal of Monetary Economics 60(2): 239–254. Jordà, Ò. 2005. “Estimation and Inference of Impulse Responses by Local Projections.” American Economic Review 95(1): 161–182. Kose, M. A., S. Kurlat, F. Ohnsorge, and N. Sugawara. 2017. “A Cross-Country Database of Fiscal Space.” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 8157, World Bank, Washington, DC. Laeven, L., and F. Valencia. 2013. “Systemic Banking Crises Database.” IMF Economic Review 61(2): 225–270. Mendoza, E. G., and V. Z. Yue. 2012. “A General Equilibrium Model of Sovereign Default and Business Cycles.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 127(2): 889–946. 16 Mountford, A. and H. Uhlig. 2009. “What Are The Effects of Fiscal Policy Shocks?” Journal of Applied Econometrics 24(6): 960-992. Nickel, C., and A. Tudyka. 2014. “Fiscal Stimulus in Times of High Debt: Reconsidering Multipliers and Twin Deficits.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 46(7): 1313–1344. OECD. 2009. OECD Economic Outlook: Interim Report. March. Paris: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development. Perotti, R. 1999. “Fiscal Policy in Good Times and Bad.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 114(4): 1399–1436. Perotti, R. 2008. “In Search of the Transmission Mechanism of Fiscal Policy.” In NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2007, Volume 22, edited by D. Acemoglu, K. Rogoff, and M. Woodford, 169–226. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Perotti, R. 2011. “Expectations and Fiscal Policy: An Empirical Investigation.” IGIER Working Paper 429, Bocconi University, Milan, Italy. Ramey, V. A. 2011. “Identifying Government Spending Shocks: It’s All in the Timing.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 126(1): 1–50. Riera-Crichton, D., C. A. Vegh, and G. Vuletin. 2015. “Procyclical and Countercyclical Fiscal Multipliers: Evidence from OECD Countries.” Journal of International Money and Finance 52: 15–31. Romer, C. D., and D. H. Romer. 2010. “The Macroeconomic Effects of Tax Changes: Estimates Based on a New Measure of Fiscal Shocks.” American Economic Review 100(3): 763–801. Sá, F., P. Towbin, and T. Wieladek. 2014. “Capital Inflows, Financial Structure and Housing Booms.” Journal of the European Economic Association 12(2): 522–546. Spilimbergo, A., S. Symansky, and M. Schindler. 2009. “Fiscal Multipliers.” IMF Staff Position Note 09/11, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC. Sutherland, A. 1997. “Fiscal Crises and Aggregate Demand: Can High Public Debt Reverse the Effects of Fiscal Policy?” Journal of Public Economics 65(2): 147–162. Towbin, P., and S. Weber. 2013. “Limits of Floating Exchange Rates: The Role of Foreign Currency Debt and Import Structure.” Journal of Development Economics 101: 179–194. Zubairy, S. 2014. “On Fiscal Multipliers: Estimates from a Medium Scale DSGE Model.” International Economic Review 55(1): 169–195. 17 Figure 1: Fiscal Position-Dependent Multipliers A. On Impact B. 1 Year 0.3 0.6 0.2 0.4 0.1 0.2 0.0 0.0 -0.1 -0.2 24.8 32.2 38.5 42.9 47.9 56.1 65.5 80.5 24.8 32.2 38.5 42.9 47.9 56.1 65.5 80.5 Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP) Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP) C. 2 Years D. Long Run 0.9 1.6 0.6 0.8 0.3 0.0 0.0 -0.8 -0.3 -1.6 -0.6 -2.4 24.8 32.2 38.5 42.9 47.9 56.1 65.5 80.5 24.8 32.2 38.5 42.9 47.9 56.1 65.5 80.5 Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP) Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP) Note: The graphs show the conditional fiscal multipliers for different levels of fiscal position at select horizons. Fiscal multipliers are defined as cumulative change in output relative to cumulative change in government consumption in response to a 1 unit government consumption shock. They are based on estimates from the IPVAR model, where model coefficients are conditioned only on fiscal position. Government debt as a percentage of GDP is the measure of fiscal position and the values shown on the x-axis correspond to the 10th to 90th percentiles from the sample. Fiscal position is strong (weak) when government debt is low (high). Solid lines represent the median, and dotted bands are the 16-84 percent confidence bands. 18 Figure 2: Conditional Impulse Responses A. Government Consumption B. GDP 1.2 0.2 1.0 Weak fiscal position 0.1 0.8 Strong fiscal position 0.6 0.0 0.4 -0.1 0.2 -0.2 Weak fiscal position 0.0 Strong fiscal position -0.2 -0.3 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Q uarters Q uarters Note: The graphs show the conditional impulse responses (deviation from baseline in percentage points) for strong (blue) and weak (red) fiscal positions. These are based on estimates from the IPVAR model, where model coefficients are conditioned only on fiscal position. Government debt as a percentage of GDP is the measure of fiscal position. The strong fiscal position corresponds to the 10th percentile of debt-to-GDP ratio from the sample, while the weak fiscal position corresponds to the 90th percentile. Solid lines represent the median, and dotted bands are the 16-84 percent confidence bands. 19 Figure 3: Ricardian and Interest Rate Channels: Joint Model A. Impulse Responses Private Consumption CDS 0.3 70 0.2 60 50 0.1 40 0.0 30 -0.1 20 10 -0.2 0 -0.3 -10 -0.4 -20 Weak fiscal position Strong fiscal position -30 Weak fiscal position Strong fiscal position -0.5 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Q uarters Q uarters B. Multipliers On Impact 2 Years 0.6 1.6 0.4 1.2 0.2 0.8 0.0 0.4 -0.2 0.0 -0.4 -0.4 23.1 32.0 38.5 42.8 47.4 54.6 63.8 76.7 23.1 32.0 38.5 42.8 47.4 54.6 63.8 76.7 Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP) Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP) Note: The upper graphs show the conditional impulse responses (deviation from baseline in percentage points) for strong (blue) and weak (red) fiscal positions. The lower graphs show the fiscal multipliers on impact and after two years (cumulative change in output relative to cumulative change in government consumption after a fiscal shock) by government debt, ranging from the 10th to the 90th percentile of government debt in the sample. These are based on estimates from the IPVAR model, where model coefficients are conditioned only on fiscal position. Government debt as a percentage of GDP is the measure of fiscal position. The strong fiscal position corresponds to the 10th percentile of debt-to-GDP ratio from the sample, while the weak fiscal position corresponds to the 90th percentile. Solid lines represent the median, and dotted bands are the 16- 84 percent confidence bands. 20 Figure 4: Ricardian and Interest Rate Channels: Impulse Responses in Separate Models A. Private Consumption B. CDS 0.2 80 60 0.1 40 0.0 20 -0.1 0 -0.2 -20 Weak fiscal position Strong fiscal position Weak fiscal position Strong fiscal position -0.3 -40 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Q uarters Q uarters Note: The graphs show the conditional impulse responses (deviation from baseline in percentage points) for strong (blue) and weak (red) fiscal positions. These are based on estimates from the IPVAR model, where model coefficients are conditioned only on fiscal position. Government debt as a percentage of GDP is the measure of fiscal position. The strong fiscal position corresponds to the 10th percentile of debt-to-GDP ratio from the sample, while the weak fiscal position corresponds to the 90th percentile. Solid lines represent the median, and dotted bands are the 16-84 percent confidence bands. Multipliers can be found in the supplementary annex. 21 Figure 5: Ricardian and Interest Rate Channels: Impulses Responses A. Sub-sample: Post-Crisis (2009-14) Private Consumption CDS 0.5 150 0.4 100 0.3 50 0.2 0.1 0 0.0 -50 -0.1 -100 -0.2 Weak fiscal position Strong fiscal position Weak fiscal position Strong fiscal position -0.3 -150 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Q uarters Q uarters B. Lag Structure: 3 Quarters Private Consumption CDS 0.2 100 Weak fiscal position Strong fiscal position 0.1 80 0.0 60 -0.1 40 -0.2 20 -0.3 0 -0.4 -20 Weak fiscal position Strong fiscal position -0.5 -40 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Q uarters Q uarters C. Government Debt Gap Private Consumption CDS 0.3 60 0.2 40 0.1 0.0 20 -0.1 0 -0.2 -20 -0.3 Weak fiscal position Strong fiscal position Weak fiscal position Strong fiscal position -0.4 -40 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Q uarters Q uarters Note: The panel C is based on government debt gap (deviation from group mean) as conditioning variable. Strong fiscal positions are defined as government debt in the 10th percentile and weak fiscal positions are defined as government debt in the 90th percentile in the sample. These are based on estimates from the IPVAR model, where model coefficients are conditioned on fiscal position, with government debt as a percentage of GDP is the measure of fiscal position. 22 Figure 6: Conditional Impulse Responses Based on Local Projections Model A. Output B. Private Consumption 1.0 0.5 0.5 0.0 0.0 -0.5 -0.5 -1.0 -1.0 Strong position Strong position Weak position Weak position -1.5 -1.5 0 1 2 3 4 0 1 2 3 4 Half-Years Half-Years Note: The graphs show the impulse responses for strong (blue) and weak (red) fiscal positions, as a cumulative percent change. These are defined as the coefficient estimates from a regression of h-period-ahead real output and real private consumption on lagged output, private consumption, CDS spreads, and unpredicted OECD forecast errors, in which all coefficients are interacted with government debt in percent of GDP. The strong fiscal position corresponds to the 10th percentile of debt-to-GDP ratio from the sample, while the weak fiscal position corresponds to the 90th percentile. Solid lines represent the coefficient estimates, and dotted bands are the 85 percent confidence bands. 23 Figure 7: Ricardian Channel Only: Impulse Responses of Private Consumption A. Recessions B. Financial Crises 0.2 2.0 Weak fiscal position Strong fiscal position 0.0 1.5 Weak fiscal position Strong fiscal position 1.0 -0.2 0.5 -0.4 0.0 -0.6 -0.5 -0.8 -1.0 -1.0 -1.5 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Q uarters Q uarters C. Countries with Stable Debt D. Nonlinear Debt 0.6 0.2 0.4 0.1 0.2 0.0 0.0 -0.2 -0.1 -0.4 -0.2 -0.6 Weak fiscal position Strong fiscal position Weak fiscal position Strong fiscal position -0.8 -0.3 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Q uarters Q uarters E. Fixed Exchange Rate F. Flexible Exchange Rate 0.3 0.1 0.2 0.0 0.1 -0.1 0.0 -0.2 -0.1 Weak fiscal position Strong fiscal position Weak fiscal position Strong fiscal position -0.2 -0.3 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Q uarters Q uarters Note: The graphs show the impulse responses of private consumption over time by fiscal position. These are based on estimates from the IPVAR model, where model coefficients are conditioned on fiscal position for the samples of recessions (defined as in Harding and Pagan 2002), expansions, financial crises (defined as in Laeven and Valencia 2013), non-crises, countries with stable debt (advanced economies excluding Belgium, Canada, and Italy during 1980- 2006), and nonlinear debt. “Nonlinear debt” are coefficients conditioned on a linear and a quadratic terms of government debt. Coefficients are jointly conditioned for fiscal position and recession, financial crises, and fixed exchange rates. The strong fiscal position corresponds to the 10th percentile of debt-to-GDP ratio from the sample, while the weak fiscal position corresponds to the 90th percentile. Dotted bands represent the 16-84 percent confidence bands. 24 Table 1: Country Coverage Advanced Developing Country Period Country Period Australia 1980:Q1-2013:Q4 Argentina 1993:Q1-2013:Q4 Belgium 1991:Q1-2013:Q4 Bulgaria 1999:Q1-2013:Q4 Canada 1980:Q1-2013:Q4 Brazil 1995:Q1-2013:Q4 Germany 1991:Q1-2013:Q4 Chile 1989:Q1-2013:Q4 Denmark 1999:Q1-2013:Q4 Colombia 2000:Q1-2013:Q4 Spain 1995:Q1-2013:Q4 Czech Republic 1999:Q1-2013:Q4 Finland 1998:Q1-2013:Q4 Croatia 2000:Q1-2013:Q4 France 1980:Q1-2013:Q4 Hungary 1995:Q1-2013:Q4 United Kingdom 1980:Q1-2013:Q4 Israel 1999:Q1-2013:Q4 Iceland 1997:Q1-2013:Q4 Mexico 1991:Q1-2013:Q4 Italy 1999:Q1-2013:Q4 Poland 1999:Q1-2013:Q4 Lithuania 1995:Q1-2013:Q4 Romania 1998:Q1-2013:Q4 Netherlands 1988:Q1-2013:Q4 Slovak Republic 1999:Q1-2013:Q4 Norway 1996:Q1-2013:Q4 South Africa 1993:Q1-2013:Q4 Portugal 1980:Q1-2013:Q4 Turkey 1998:Q1-2013:Q4 Slovenia 1995:Q1-2013:Q4 Sweden 1993:Q1-2013:Q4 United States 1980:Q1-2013:Q4 Note: The table shows the list of countries in the sample. Coverage corresponds to maximum temporal coverage for each country in the baseline specification of the IPVAR model. Coverage may differ for specifications used in the robustness exercises. The list of countries is presented in the Appendix. Our developing-country coverage comprises primarily emerging and frontier market economies that have some ability to tap into international financial markets, which renders the fiscal solvency risks that underpin our nonlinear crowding-out mechanisms relevant. We exclude low- income countries not only because of data reliability issues, but also because they primarily rely on concessional finance for government expenditure, which would not reflect the crowding-out mechanisms. 25 Table 2. Fiscal Multiplier Estimates Conditioning on government debt Study Sample Methodology Government debt High Low Our results 1/ 33 countries, IPVAR 0-0.5 0.6-0.9 1980-2014 Ilzetzki, Mendoza, Vegh (2013) 2/ 44 countries, SVAR -3 insignificant 1960-2007 Nickell and Tudyka (2014) 2/ 17 EU countries, IPVAR <0 1.2 1970-2010 Auerbach and Gorodnichenko 25 OECD LPM <0 >0 (2017) 3/ countries, 2003- 17 Conditioning on business cycles 4/ Study Sample Methodology Recession Expansion Favero, Giavazzi and Perego (2011) US, 1980-2009 GVAR "close to 2" 5/ Bachmann and Sims (2012) US, 1960-2011 VAR 2.13-3.35 1.04-1.1 Auerbach and Gorodnichenko US, 1947-2008 LPM 1.12-3.85 0.17-3.02 (2012) Auerbach and Gorodnichenko OECD, 1985- LPM 3.5 0 (2013) 2008 Blanchard and Leigh (2013) 6/ 26 European Panel "Substantially … countries, 2009- regression above 1" 12 Candelon and Lieb (2013) US, 1968-2010 TVAR 1-2.4 0.5 Unconditional 7/ Study Sample Methodology Average Blanchard and Perotti (2002) US, 1947-97 VAR 0.9-2.67 Gali, Lopez-Salido and Valles (2007) US, 1954-2003 DSGE 1.74-3.5 Perotti (2008) US, AUS, CAN, VAR 0 (UK, Canada) -3.1 (US) UK, 1926-2003 Fatas and Mihov (2009) Not applicable Survey >1 Mountford and Uhlig (2009) US, 1955-2000 VAR 0.65 Perotti (2011) US 1939-2008 SVAR, EVAR "in the neighbourhood of 1" Ramey (2011) US Survey 0.6-1.8 Auerbach and Gorodnichenko US, 1947-2008 LPM 1-2.12 (2012) Bachmann and Sims (2012) US, 1960-2011 VAR 0.89-0.88 Alesina, Favero and Giavazzi (2015) 16 OECD SUR negative to positive countries, 1978- 2009 Note: IPVAR stands for interacted panel vector autoregression, SVAR for structural vector autoregression,VAR for structural vector autoregression, TVAR for threshold vector autoregression, LPM for local projections model, EVAR stands for expectations-augmented vector autoregression. 1/ High government debt is defined as government debt above 60 percent of GDP, low government debt is the remainder. Fiscal instrument is government consumption 2/ High government debt is defined as debt in the 90th percentile of the sample (92 percent of GDP). High government debt is defined as debt in the 10th percentile of the sample (17 percent of GDP). Fiscal instrument is government consumption. 3/ Explicit multiplier estimates not available. Table shows longterm impulse response of real GDP. Fiscal instrument is government spending (consumption and investment). 4/ Fiscal instrument is government spending, except for Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2012) who use a wide range of fiscal instruments. 26 5/ Fiscal shocks are consolidation episodes (tax and spending) as identified in Devries et al. (2011). 6/ Fiscal shocks are structural fiscal balance changes during 2009-10. 7/ Fiscal instrument is government spending, except when otherwise specified. Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2012), Blanchard and Perotti (1999), Ramey (2011), and Gali, Lopez-Salido and Valles (2007) discuss a range of fiscal instruments. 27 Supplementary Appendix Why Do Fiscal Multipliers Depend on Fiscal Positions? ∗ Raju Huidrom, M. Ayhan Kose, Jamus J. Lim, and Franziska L. Ohnsorge This appendix presents some additional results. IT IS NOT FOR PUBLICATION. Figure A.1 Unconditional Fiscal Multipliers Figure A.2 Unconditional Impulse Responses Figure A.3 Distribution of Fiscal Positions Figure A.4 Ricardian and Interest Rate Channels in Separate Models: Fiscal Multipliers Figure A.5 Ricardian and Interest Rate Channels: Impulse Responses Figure A.6 Ricardian and Interest Rate Channels: Fiscal Multipliers Figure A.7 Ricardian and Interest Rate Channels: Impulse Reponses and Fiscal Multipliers Figure A.8 Ricardian Channel Only: Fiscal Multipliers Figure A.9 Baseline Model: Robustness Table A.1 Data Sources Table A.2 Distribution of Fiscal Positions Table A.3 Comparison of Fiscal and Business Cycle States ∗ Huidrom: International Monetary Fund; rhuidrom@imf.org. Kose: World Bank, Prospects Group; Brookings Institution; CEPR; and CAMA; akose@worldbank.org. Lim: Essec Business School; jamus.lim@essec.edu. Ohnsorge: World Bank, Prospects Group; and CAMA; fohnsorge@worldbank.org. 28 Figure A.1: Unconditional Fiscal Multipliers 0.4 0.2 0.0 -0.2 -0.4 -0.6 -0.8 On Impact 1 Year 2 Years Long Run Note: The graph shows the unconditional fiscal multipliers for select horizons. Bars represent the median, and the error bands are the 16-84 percent confidence bands. These are based on estimates from the SVAR model of Ilzetzki, Mendoza, and Vegh (2013) that features with no interaction terms. Figure A.2: Unconditional Impulse Responses A. Government Consumption B. GDP 1.2 0.08 1.0 0.04 0.8 0.6 0.00 0.4 0.2 -0.04 0.0 -0.2 -0.08 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Q uarters Q uarters Note: The graphs show the unconditional impulse responses (percentage points) to a positive shock to government consumption. Solid lines represent the median, and dotted lines are the 16-84 percent confidence bands. These are based on estimates from the SVAR model of Ilzetzki, Mendoza, and Vegh (2013) that features with no interaction terms. Figure A.3: Distribution of Fiscal Positions 25 20 15 10 5 0 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 110 120 130 Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP) Note: The graph shows the distribution of fiscal position (in percent), taken to be the annual government debt-to-GDP ratio, from the sample of advanced and developing economies during the period 1980-2014. 29 Figure A.4: Ricardian and Interest Rate Channels in Separate Models: Fiscal Multipliers A. Ricardian Channel Only On Impact 2 Years 0.3 0.9 0.2 0.6 0.1 0.3 0.0 -0.1 0.0 24.8 32.2 38.5 42.9 47.9 56.1 65.5 80.5 24.8 32.2 38.5 42.9 47.9 56.1 65.5 80.5 Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP) Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP) B. Ricardian Channel Only with CDS Sample On Impact 2 Years 0.6 1.6 0.4 1.2 0.2 0.8 0.0 0.4 -0.2 0.0 -0.4 -0.4 23.1 32.0 38.5 42.8 47.4 54.6 63.8 76.7 23.1 32.0 38.5 42.8 47.4 54.6 63.8 76.7 Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP) Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP) C. Interest Rate Channel On Impact 2 Years 0.4 1.6 1.2 0.2 0.8 0.0 0.4 -0.2 0.0 -0.4 -0.4 23.1 32.0 38.5 42.8 47.4 54.6 63.8 76.7 23.1 32.0 38.5 42.8 47.4 54.6 63.8 76.7 Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP) Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP) Note: The graphs show the fiscal multipliers on impact and after two years (cumulative change in output relative to cumulative change in government consumption after a fiscal shock) by government debt, ranging from the 10th to the 90th percentile of government debt in the sample. These are based on estimates from two IPVAR models, where model coefficients are conditioned only on fiscal position, that separately include, first, private consumption to proxy the Ricardian channel (top two rows) and, second, CDS spreads to proxy the interest rate channel (bottom row). The second row shows the fiscal multipliers from the model including only the Ricardian channel, but with the sample restricted to the sample of the joint model of Figure 3. Government debt as a percentage of GDP is the measure of fiscal position. Solid lines represent the median, and dotted bands are the 16-84 percent confidence bands. Multipliers can be found in the supplementary annex. 30 Figure A.5: Ricardian and Interest Rate Channels: Impulse Responses A. Sub-sample: Advanced Economies Only Private Consumption CDS 0.9 150 Weak fiscal position Strong fiscal position 0.6 100 50 0.3 0 0.0 -50 -0.3 -100 -0.6 -150 Weak fiscal position Strong fiscal position -0.9 -200 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Q uarters Q uarters B. Alternative thresholds for weak and strong fiscal positions Private Consumption CDS 0.2 30 0.1 20 0.0 10 -0.1 0 -0.2 -10 Weak fiscal position Strong fiscal position Weak fiscal position Strong fiscal position -0.3 -20 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Q uarters Q uarters C. Lag Structure: 5 Quarters Private Consumption CDS 0.3 60 0.2 0.1 30 0.0 -0.1 0 -0.2 -0.3 Weak fiscal position Strong fiscal position Weak fiscal position Strong fiscal position -0.4 -30 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Q uarters Q uarters D. Deviation of government debt in percent of GDP from country-specific average Private Consumption CDS 0.2 40 Weak fiscal position Strong fiscal position 30 0.1 Weak fiscal position Strong fiscal position 20 0.0 10 -0.1 0 -10 -0.2 -20 -0.3 -30 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Q uarters Q uarters Note: Impulse responses are based on estimates from the IPVAR model, where model coefficients are conditioned only on fiscal positions, with government debt in percent of GDP as the conditioning variable (except for the fourth row, where the fiscal position is defined as deviation of government debt in percent of GDP from the country-specific 31 average). Weak fiscal positions are defined as government debt in the 90th percentile and strong fiscal positions are defined as government debt in the 10th percentile in the sample (except for charts in the second row, where weak fiscal positions are defined as government debt in the 75th percentile and strong fiscal positions are defined as government debt in the 25th percentile in the sample). 32 Figure A.6: Ricardian and Interest Rate Channels: Fiscal Multipliers A. On Impact B. 2 Years 2 3 Strong position Weak position 2 1 1 0 0 -1 -1 -2 Strong position Weak position -2 -3 (Figure 3) (Figure 3) economies Three Debt gap (country) economies Three Debt gap (country) 2009-14 Five 2009-14 Five Debt gap Debt gap lags lags Advanced Advanced Baseline Baseline (group) (group) lags lags Note: The graphs show the fiscal multipliers on impact and after two years (cumulative change in output relative to cumulative change in government consumption after a fiscal shock) by government debt, for the 10th to the 90th percentile of government debt in the sample. These are based on estimates from the IPVAR model, where model coefficients are conditioned only on fiscal position. (The exception are the last two sets of multipliers which condition on the deviation of government debt from the group-specific mean, “Debt gap (group-mean)”, and country-specific mean, “Debt gap (country-mean)”.) Government debt as a percentage of GDP is the measure of fiscal position. The strong fiscal position corresponds to the 10th percentile of debt-to-GDP ratio from the sample, while the weak fiscal position corresponds to the 90th percentile. Vertical error bars represent the 16-84 percent confidence bands. The upper row uses a model that allows for both Ricardian and interest rate channels. The bottom row uses a model that allows only for Ricardian channels, to preserve degrees of freedom. 33 Figure A.7: Ricardian and Interest Rate Channels: Impulse Reponses and Multipliers Output Real Effective Exchange Rate before Private Consumption before Current Account Balances A. Impulse Responses Private Consumption Private Consumption 0.4 0.3 Weak fiscal position Strong fiscal position Weak fiscal position Strong fiscal position 0.2 0.2 0.1 0.0 0.0 -0.1 -0.2 -0.2 -0.3 -0.4 -0.4 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Q uarters Q uarters CDS CDS 80 80 Weak fiscal position Strong fiscal position Weak fiscal position Strong fiscal position 60 60 40 40 20 20 0 0 -20 -20 -40 -40 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Q uarters Q uarters B. Multipliers On Impact On Impact 0.6 0.6 0.4 0.4 0.2 0.2 0.0 0.0 -0.2 -0.2 -0.4 -0.4 23.1 32.0 38.5 42.8 47.4 54.6 63.8 76.7 23.1 32.0 38.5 42.8 47.4 54.6 63.8 76.7 Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP) Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP) 2 Years 2 Years 1.8 1.8 1.5 1.5 1.2 1.2 0.9 0.9 0.6 0.6 0.3 0.3 0.0 0.0 -0.3 -0.3 23.1 32.0 38.5 42.8 47.4 54.6 63.8 76.7 23.1 32.0 38.5 42.8 47.4 54.6 63.8 76.7 Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP) Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP) 34 Note: The left column shows results from a model in which the Cholesky ordering of output and private consumption is reversed to order output first. The right column shows results from a model in which the Cholesky ordering of real exchange rates and current account balances is reversed to order real exchange rates first. The results are based on estimates from the IPVAR model, where model coefficients are conditioned only on fiscal position. Government debt as a percentage of GDP is the measure of fiscal position. The strong fiscal position corresponds to the 10th percentile of debt-to-GDP ratio from the sample, while the weak fiscal position corresponds to the 90th percentile. Solid lines represent the median, and dotted bands are the 16-84 percent confidence bands. The top two rows of the Figure show the conditional impulse responses (deviation from baseline in percentage points) for strong (blue) and weak (red) fiscal positions. The bottom two rows show the conditional fiscal multipliers for different fiscal positions at select horizons. Fiscal multipliers are defined as cumulative change in output relative to cumulative change in government consumption in response to a 1 unit government consumption shock. 35 Figure A.8: Ricardian Channel Only: Fiscal Multipliers A. On Impact B. 2 Years 2 5 Strong position Strong position 4 1 Weak position 3 Weak position 2 0 1 0 -1 -1 Expansions Non-Crises Nonlinear Crises Recessions Stable debt exchange rate exchange rate Expansions Non-Crises Nonlinear Crises Recessions Stable debt exchange rate exchange rate Baseline Baseline Flexible debt Flexible debt Fixed Fixed Note: The graphs show the fiscal multipliers on impact and after two years (cumulative change in output relative to cumulative change in government consumption after a fiscal shock) by government debt, for the 10th to the 90th percentile of government debt in the sample. These are based on estimates from the IPVAR model, where model coefficients are conditioned on fiscal position for the sample samples of recessions (defined as in Harding and Pagan 2002), expansions, crises (defined as in Laeven and Valencia 2013), non-crises, advanced economies with stable debt (advanced economies excl. Belgium during 1980-2006), and nonlinear debt. “Nonlinear debt” are coefficients conditioned on a linear and a quadratic terms of government debt. Coefficients are jointly conditioned for fiscal position and fixed exchange rates (defined as in Ilzetzki, Mendoza and Vegh 2013). “Baseline” are the fiscal multipliers corresponding to the left chart of Figure 4. Government debt as a percentage of GDP is the measure of fiscal position. The strong fiscal position corresponds to the 10th percentile of debt-to-GDP ratio from the sample, while the weak fiscal position corresponds to the 90th percentile. Vertical error bars represent the 16-84 percent confidence bands. The upper row uses a model that allows for both Ricardian and interest rate channels. The bottom row uses a model that allows only for Ricardian channels, to preserve degrees of freedom. 36 Figure A.9: Baseline Model: Robustness A. During Recessions On Impact 2 Years 0.6 2.5 2.0 0.4 1.5 1.0 0.2 0.5 0.0 0.0 -0.5 12.4 24.8 32.2 38.5 42.9 47.9 56.1 65.5 80.5 107.4 12.4 24.8 32.2 38.5 42.9 47.9 56.1 65.5 80.5 107.4 Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP) Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP) B. Nonlinear Government Debt On Impact 2 Years 0.4 0.9 0.6 0.3 0.3 0.2 0.0 0.1 -0.3 0.0 -0.6 -0.1 -0.9 12.4 24.8 32.2 38.5 42.9 47.9 56.1 65.5 80.5 107.4 12.4 24.8 32.2 38.5 42.9 47.9 56.1 65.5 80.5 107.4 Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP) Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP) C. Fixed Exchange Rate Regimes On Impact 2 Years 0.3 0.8 0.2 0.6 0.2 0.1 0.4 0.1 0.2 0.0 0.0 -0.1 -0.1 -0.2 12.4 24.8 32.2 38.5 42.9 47.9 56.1 65.5 80.5 12.4 24.8 32.2 38.5 42.9 47.9 56.1 65.5 80.5 Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP) Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP) D. Flexible Exchange Rate Regimes On Impact 2 Years 0.7 3 0.6 2 0.5 0.4 1 0.3 0.2 0 24.8 32.2 38.5 42.9 47.9 56.1 65.5 80.5 24.8 32.2 38.5 42.9 47.9 56.1 65.5 80.5 Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP) Gove rnment de bt (percent of GDP) 37 Note: The graphs show the conditional fiscal multipliers for different levels of fiscal position at select horizons. Fiscal multipliers are defined as cumulative change in output relative to cumulative change in government consumption in response to a 1 unit government consumption shock. They are based on estimates from the IPVAR model, where model coefficients are conditioned only on fiscal position. Government debt as a percentage of GDP is the measure of fiscal position and the values shown on the x-axis correspond to the 10th to 90th percentiles from the sample. Fiscal position is strong (weak) when government debt is low (high). Solid lines represent the median, and dotted bands are the 16-84 percent confidence bands. 38 Table A.1: Data Sources Variable Definition Frequency Source Output Real gross domestic product (GDP) Quarterly Ilzetzki, Mendoza, and Vegh (2013), OECD, Haver Analytics Private consumption Real personal consumption expenditure Quarterly Ilzetzki, Mendoza, and Vegh (2013), OECD, Haver Analytics Private investment Real private gross fixed capital formation Quarterly Government consumption Real government consumption expenditurea Quarterly Ilzetzki, Mendoza, and Vegh (2013), OECD, Haver Analytics a Government investment Real government gross fixed capital formation Quarterly OECD, Haver Analytics, Eurostat b Real effective exchange rate Real effective exchange rate Quarterly Ilzetzki, Mendoza, and Vegh (2013), BIS Current account Current account as percent of GDP Quarterly Ilzetzki, Mendoza, and Vegh (2013), WEO Government debt General government debt as percent of GDP Annual WEO Fiscal balance Overall fiscal balance as percent of GDP Annual WEO Government consumption-to-GDP ratio Government consumption as percent of GDP Annual WDI Government investment-to-GDP ratio Government investment as percent of GDP Annual WDI Interest rate Short term nominal interest rate Quarterly Ilzetzki, Mendoza, and Vegh (2013) Note: The main source for the quarterly series is Ilzetzki, Mendoza, and Vegh (2013). This database which ends around 2008 is extended by splicing from different sources as mentioned in the table. a This refers to general government for most countries while for a few countries central government is taken. See Ilzetzki, Mendoza, and Vegh (2013). b The narrow index wherever available is taken while the remainder uses the broad index. Details are available upon request. Table A.2: Distribution of Fiscal Positions Percentile 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 Debt-GDP Ratio 12.4 17.3 24.8 28.7 32.2 35.9 38.5 40.7 42.9 45.1 47.9 51.4 56.1 60.1 65.5 71.3 80.5 92.4 107.4 Note: The table shows the percentile values of fiscal position, taken to be annual government debt-to-GDP ratio, from the sample of advanced and developing economies during the period 1980-2014. 39 Table A.3: Comparison of Fiscal and Business Cycle States Full Sample Advanced Developing a Relative frequency Strong fiscal and recessionary state 2.2 2.4 1.8 Weak fiscal and recessionary state 2.1 2.4 3.0 Test of differences b [52.3, 54.0] [57.3, 57.9] [43.4, 44.6] In means 0.25 0.76 0.55 Note: The table shows the association (or lack thereof) between different fiscal positions and the recessionary state. a The top panel shows the relative frequency (percent of observations) of the strong fiscal position and the recessionary state, and that of weak fiscal position and the recessionary state. The frequencies are reported for the full sample and also for specific country groups: advanced and developing economies. The strong (weak) fiscal position corresponds to the 10th (90th) percentile of debt-to-GDP ratio in each sample. The bottom panel reports results that show the statistical significance of the difference of those relative frequencies. The recessionary state is determined by the Harding-Pagan (2002) business cycle dating algorithm. b The top entry shows the average debt-to-GDP ratio (in percent) during expansions (left) and recessions (right). The bottom entry shows the p-values of two-group t-test of difference in means with unequal variances. 40