WPS6957 Policy Research Working Paper 6957 The Environmental Implications of Russia’s Accession to the World Trade Organization Christoph Böhringer Thomas F. Rutherford David G. Tarr Natalia Turdyeva The World Bank Europe and Central Asia Region Sustainable Development Department June 2014 Policy Research Working Paper 6957 Abstract This report investigates the environmental impacts of “composition effect”) and the expansion of output with Russia’s accession to the World Trade Organization. A its associated increase in pollution (“scale effect”). The 10-region, 30-sector model of the Russian economy paper assesses the costs of three types of environmental is developed. The model is innovative and more regulations to reduce carbon dioxide emissions by 20 accurate empirically in that it contains foreign direct percent. The paper simultaneously implements a central investment, imperfectly competitive sectors, and case scenario with each of the carbon dioxide emission endogenous productivity effects triggered by World reduction policy initiatives. The analysis finds that the Trade Organization accession along with environmental welfare gains of World Trade Organization accession emissions data in Russia for seven pollutants that are are large enough to pay for the costs of any of the three tracked for all 30 sectors in each of the 10 regions. The environmental abatement policies, while leaving a net decomposition analysis shows that despite the fact that welfare gain. But the political economy implications World Trade Organization accession allows Russia to are that the non-market-based policies are more costly import better technologies and reduce pollution from the and the command and control policy, which is not well “technique effect,” on balance World Trade Organization targeted, is very costly. Based on a constant returns to accession alone will increase environmental pollution scale model, the estimated welfare gains are insufficient to in Russia through a shift toward dirty industries (the finance the costs of environmental regulation. This paper is a product of the Sustainable Development Department, Europe and Central Asia Region. It is part of a larger effort by the World Bank to provide open access to its research and make a contribution to development policy discussions around the world. Policy Research Working Papers are also posted on the Web at http://econ.worldbank.org. The authors may be contacted at dgtarr@gmail.com. The Policy Research Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange of ideas about development issues. An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished. The papers carry the names of the authors and should be cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the views of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/World Bank and its affiliated organizations, or those of the Executive Directors of the World Bank or the governments they represent. Produced by the Research Support Team The Environmental Implications of Russia’s Accession to the World Trade Organization Christoph Böhringer, Thomas F. Rutherford, David G. Tarr and Natalia Turdyeva* Key Words: trade and the environment; environmental policy efficiency; increasing returns to scale model and the environment; technique effect; cap and trade; energy efficiency; emissions intensity. JEL classification: F18; F13; F12; Q52; Q58; C68. *David G. Tarr, Consultant and Former Lead Economist, The World Bank, is the corresponding author, dgtarr@gmail.com; Christoph Böhringer is professor of economics at the University of Oldenburg; Thomas F. Rutherford is professor of agricultural and applied economics at the University of Wisconsin. Natalia Turdyeva is senior researcher at the Center for Economics and Financial Research, Moscow, Russia. The authors would like to thank Craig Meisner (as the Task Team Leader), Adriana Damianova and Kulsum Ahmed for their insight and guidance. The authors gratefully acknowledge the financial support for this project (P133836) provided through a Research Budget Grant from the World Bank's Development Research Administration (DECRA). Contents 1. Introduction ........................................................................................................................... 1 2. Environmental policy debate in Russia ................................................................................. 3 3. Trade and the environment literature: implications for Russia ............................................. 4 4. CGE model for Russia: structure and data ............................................................................ 7 4.1 Production and Geographic Structure ............................................................................. 7 4.1.1 Sectors, Regions and Core Data. .............................................................................. 7 4.1.2 Price determination for competitive goods and services sectors. ............................. 8 4.1.3 Structure of Production for Non-Fossil Fuel Sectors. .............................................. 9 4.1.4 Goods produced subject to increasing returns to scale ............................................. 9 4.1.5 Services sectors that are produced in Russia under increasing returns to scale and imperfect competition...................................................................................................... 11 4.1.6 Factors of Production ............................................................................................. 12 4.1.7 Trade ....................................................................................................................... 13 4.1.8 Government ............................................................................................................ 14 4.2 Emissions Modeling ...................................................................................................... 14 4.3 Key Data ........................................................................................................................ 15 4.3.1 Emissions Data. ...................................................................................................... 15 4.3.2 Ad Valorem Equivalence of Barriers to Foreign Direct Investment in Services Sectors ............................................................................................................................. 16 4.3.3 Share of Expatriate Labor Employed by Multinational Service providers............. 18 4.3.5 Input-output tables .................................................................................................. 19 4.3.6 Regional IO tables and Trade Flows of the Regions .............................................. 19 4.3.7 FDI Shares .............................................................................................................. 21 5. Results of Policy scenarios .................................................................................................. 21 5.1. Policy scenarios ............................................................................................................ 21 5.2. WTO Accession results ................................................................................................ 25 5.2.1 Explaining Differences across Regions. ................................................................. 25 5.2.2 Impact of WTO Accession on Carbon Emissions. ................................................. 26 5.3. Evaluating Alternate Policy Reforms to Reduce Carbon Emissions by 20 Percent ..... 27 5.3.1 Market Based Carbon Emissions Trading (“Cap and Trade”). .............................. 27 5.3.2. Carbon Emissions Intensity Standards .................................................................. 28 5.3.3 Energy Efficiency Standards ................................................................................. 28 5.4 Combining WTO Accession with Policies to Reduce Carbon Emissions by 20 Percent ............................................................................................................................................. 29 5.4.1 WTO Accession Combined with Carbon Emissions Trading ............................... 29 5.4.2 WTO Accession Combined with Emission Intensity Standards ............................ 29 5.4.3 WTO Accession Combined with Energy Efficiency Standards ............................. 30 6. Sensitivity Analysis ............................................................................................................. 30 6.1 Results with Constant Returns to Scale and Perfect Competition ................................. 30 6.2 Piecemeal Sensitivity Analysis...................................................................................... 31 7. Conclusions ......................................................................................................................... 32 References ............................................................................................................................... 33 Tables ...................................................................................................................................... 37 Figures ..................................................................................................................................... 75 Appendix: Environmental Database of the Model: Documentation of the Sources and Construction ............................................................................................................................ 85 A.1. Non-CO2 emission accounting.................................................................................... 85 A.2. CO2 emissions accounting .......................................................................................... 89 Appendix References .......................................................................................................... 89 ii THE ENVIRONMENTAL IMPLICATIONS OF RUSSIA’S ACCESSION TO THE WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION 1. Introduction After 18 years of negotiations, Russia joined the World Trade Organization (WTO) in 2012. WTO accession is a comprehensive process that involves multiple reforms including maximum tariff commitments on goods, non-protective application of standards and norms, market access for foreign suppliers of services, rules on trade related investment measures and limitations on trade distorting agricultural subsidies. Such comprehensive changes in policies and institutions are likely to lead to considerable changes in the structure of the economies of the acceding countries. The structural changes can have complex impacts on the environment that are very difficult to predict based on theory. Using the terminology of Grossman and Krueger (1993), the potential environmental impacts can be decomposed into: (i) a composition effect, namely inter-industry impacts along the lines of comparative advantage (toward or away from dirty industries) and competitive pressures that would shift output toward more efficient firms, lowering input use; (ii) a scale effect due to output changes induced by trade liberalization; and (iii) a technique effect, due to the use of more efficient imported technology (which could reduce input use and emissions), changes in process efficiency, and changes in fuel mix. Policy-makers in Russia are showing an interest in the expected environmental impacts of WTO accession, as they may want to introduce regulation to either mitigate negative impacts on the environment or complement positive impacts. In applied analysis, computable general equilibrium (CGE) models are widely used to quantify the economic and environmental impacts of policy regulations such as trade reforms or emission control policies. While most CGE assessments of environmental impacts are built on constant-returns-to-scale (CRTS) and competitive markets, these models omit potentially important productivity changes that could be associated with importing more efficient technology and processes. Further, both the scale and composition effects could be very different in a model that allows sectors subject to increasing returns to scale (IRTS). Such productivity effects are captured by CGE trade models that build on the trade theory introduced by Krugman (1979, 1980) and Ethier (1982) through the introduction of imperfect competition, increasing returns to scale and product differentiation. Yet these models typically fall short of detailed environmental accounting and the more sophisticated representation of inter-fuel substitution possibilities in production and consumption. 1 Against this background, we build on the ten-region, 30 sector model of the Russian economy developed by Rutherford and Tarr (2010) to assess Russian WTO accession; we incorporate environmental emissions data in Russia for seven pollutants associated with output (for non-carbon dioxide emissions) and burning of fossil fuel (for carbon dioxide emissions). Emissions are tracked for all 30 sectors in each of the ten Russian regions of our model. Our integrated trade and environment model contains increasing returns to scale sectors, foreign direct investment in business services, product differentiation and endogenous productivity effects from additional varieties of goods or services in imperfectly competitive sectors. In addition, we extend Rutherford and Tarr by allowing fuel substitution in production and consumption. We develop a methodology to quantify the decomposition of the scale, composition and technique effects of all simulations. Compared with earlier CGE research quantifying the impacts of trade on the environment based on CRTS models, we more effectively account for productivity changes that may have an important impact on emissions. In our assessment of WTO accession for Russia we find drastic differences in the economic and environmental impacts between model simulations without and with productivity changes. With a nominal per capita income above US$14,000 per year in 2013 (and a purchasing power parity per capita income of about US$18,000), it is possible that Russia is above the point on the environmental Kuznets curve where the higher incomes coming from WTO accession may increase the demand for greater environmental regulation. In fact, Antweiler et al., (2001) have shown in their empirical study of over 40 countries, that trade liberalization has been associated with a cleaner environment due to stronger environmental regulations following trade liberalization. Notwithstanding these optimistic possibilities for environmental regulation (and the stated objectives of the Russian government outlined in the next section), we believe it is crucial to address political economy considerations of environmental regulation. That is, to minimize opposition to environmental regulation, it is crucial to design policies that minimize the costs to industry of achieving a given level of environmental abatement. In a second set of simulations, we assess the costs of three types of environmental regulations to reduce carbon dioxide emissions by 20 percent: market based “cap and trade”; emission intensity standards; and energy efficiency standards. Given that part of the income increase from WTO accession might be used to pay for environmental abatement, in a third set of scenarios, we assess the impacts of “overlapping” policy reforms where we simultaneously implement our central case scenario of WTO accession with each of our three carbon emission reduction policy initiatives. Again, the relative costs of the different environmental regulations are compared. 2 The remainder of this document is organized as follows. Section 2 summarizes the environmental policy debate in Russia which explains the interest of Russian policy makers on potential trade-offs between trade liberalization and environmental quality. Section 3 provides a brief literature overview on trade and the environment. Section 4 presents the CGE model and the data sources underlying our impact assessment of Russia’s WTO accession. Section 5 motivates the policy scenarios to be investigated and discusses simulation results. In section 6 we assess the sensitivity of our results to key modeling, data and parameter assumptions. Section 7 concludes. Detailed documentation of the environmental data is in the appendix. 2. Environmental Policy Debate in Russia Russia is the largest country in the world, spanning nine time zones with a population of 143.7 million people. 1 It is also one of the richest countries in the world for oil, gas and a wide range of minerals. Russia’s natural endowment has been a key driver of economic growth in the current millennium, based on production and export of raw materials. The impacts of extraction and manufacturing industries from the Soviet-period to today have not been neutral to environmental damage and public health. Many industries are characterized by high resource use, extremely high energy inefficiency and obsolete production processes. The quality of environmental conditions in Russia is inadequate on about 15% of the country’s territory which is home to 58% of the population. 2 Due to high levels of air pollution, the average life expectancy of the population is reduced by about one year, while in more polluted cities by about four years. It is assumed that this factor is the reason for about 8% of deaths annually. The main sources of air pollution are Particulate Matter (PM), Sulphur Dioxide (SO2) and Nitrogen Oxide (NOx) linked to fossil fuel combustion (IFC 2008). A major challenge for Russia to address air pollution is the potential increase of the share of coal in the fuel mix, as export markets take priority for oil and natural gas use. Russia is currently planning to triple the share of coal in the energy mix so that the amount of coal burned will grow to between 322 million and 393 million tons of coal per year by 2030. 3 New coal generation is potentially a good option for Russia to increase its generation capacity, but care will need to be taken to identify the best “clean-coal” technologies to use in these new plants. 1 As of 1st of April, 2014, Rosstat (2014). 2 According to Rosgidromet (2013): “In 138 cities in Russia (57% of the urban population), the level of air pollution is characterized as high or very high.” 3 See “Energy strategy of the Russian Federation up to 2030,” appendix 4 entitled “Estimated energy balance of Russia until 2030,” by the Ministry of Energy of the Russian Federation. Available at: http://minenergo.gov.ru/aboutminen/energostrategy/pr_4.php 3 Russia is currently the world's fourth-largest emitter of greenhouse gas emissions. At the international level, Russia ratified the Kyoto Protocol in 2004 to be part of the global community’s solution to climate change. 4 More recently, there has been a shift in Russian attitude to national, non-binding targets as evidenced by the refusal to renew its Kyoto Protocol commitments at the Durban conference in 2011; but following the Copenhagen accords, Russia is still pursuing a greenhouse gas emission reduction of between 15% and 25% from 1990 emission levels by 2020. The Government of the Russian Federation has begun to formally recognize environmental challenges in their policies, strategies and programs. Russia’s Program on Environmental Protection 2012-2020 recognizes the inseparability of environmental, social and economic objectives as central for sustainable development. 5 The new policies mark a shift towards a sustainable development model emphasizing increased investments in energy and resource efficiency, cleaner technologies, recycling and reuse of wastes. Transition to an effective system of incentives that promotes less use of resources and cleaner and greener production would typically also improve competitiveness and increase access to export markets which demand efficient, low environmental-impact materials and products. According to its state program on "Energy Saving and Energy Efficiency Improvement until 2020," Russia's is seeking to achieve a 40% reduction in energy intensity by 2020 and 56% by 2030. In addition, it is striving to achieve 53% efficiency in gas-fired power generation by 2030. 6 Russia’s WTO accession has engendered concerns about potentially negative environmental impacts. We now consider this in the context of the broader trade liberalization and the environment literature. 3. Trade and the Environment Literature: Implications for Russia Impact assessment of the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) in the early 1990s stimulated theoretical and empirical analysis on the environmental impacts of 4 On November 5, 2004, Russia ratified the Kyoto Protocol, and the Protocol came into force in February 2005. Russia is listed in Annex B of the Protocol and, as such, is subject to a constraint on its GHG emissions for the period 2008-2012. The target for Russia is that the country’s combined emissions of Kyoto gases should not exceed five times their combined 1990 levels during the period 2008-2012. This target is generally expressed in annual terms: on average, Russia’s annual emissions of the six Kyoto gases should not exceed their 1990 level – 3,048 million tons of carbon dioxide equivalent (MtCO2e) – over the period 2008-2012. Since 1999, Russia’s economy has grown at a pace of more than 6 percent per year, calling into question whether Russia will stay within the borders set by the Kyoto Protocol for the period beyond 2012. 5 See Ministry of Natural Resources and Environment of the Russian Federation (2014). 6 See Ministry of Energy of the Russian Federation (2010). 4 trade liberalization. In their seminal papers, Grossman and Krueger (1993) as well as Copeland and Taylor (1994, 1995) decomposed the overall impact into three effects – changes in scale, composition and technique (see introduction). In the environment-trade literature the economic drivers for changes in scale, composition and technique are most commonly captured through the classical model of comparative advantage which explains the pattern of international trade through the relative cost differences between countries (see Rauscher 1997 and Dean 1992, 2002 for overviews). The theory of comparative advantage gives rise for two complementary views on the environmental impacts of trade liberalization (Antweiler et al. 2001). The so-called Factor Endowment hypothesis suggests that – as countries specialize according to their traditional comparative advantages – freer trade leads to a further concentration of those industries that employ the relatively abundant production factor: if emissions are linked to capital-intensive industries then then trade liberalization would lead to an expansion of these industries in relatively capital-abundant countries and thereby also increase emissions. The so-called Pollution Haven hypothesis suggests that trade liberalization will make countries with less stringent environmental regulations dirtier as they possess a policy-induced cost advantage. While the traditional theory of comparative advantage indirectly captures scale and technique effects, it focuses on composition effects through specialization. The new trade theory pioneered by Krugman (1979; 1980) or Ethier (1982) introduced imperfect competition and increasing returns to scale (IRTS). Scale and endogenous productivity effects through additional product varieties or rationalization gains are possible. The literature initiated by Melitz (2003) incorporates the Krugman-Ethier features and provides yet another source for productivity changes through firm heterogeneity. If trade liberalization leads to an expansion of industries subject to IRTS technology, such as refineries, base metals and chemicals – that are also very energy-intensive –pollution problems will be exacerbated due to the scale and composition effects compared to a CRTS reference. On the other hand, the technique effect could be offsetting. Productivity changes may emerge through trade liberalization due to rationalization gains or as the number of product varieties and technologies increase thereby rendering those sectors more productive, resulting in less resource use per unit of output and less pollution (formally represented in models of monopolistic competition with Dixit-Stiglitz varieties (Dixit and Stiglitz, 1977). Romer (1994) emphasized that the impact of trade liberalization via new products can be much more important quantitatively than improved resource allocation. The model we employ in this paper employs this feature. Finally, with firm heterogeneity, trade creates competitive pressure which induces high productivity firms to expand output and export while low productivity firms drop out of the market, increasing aggregate productivity. The intra- 5 industry reallocations of market shares and productive resources add to effects associated with inter-industry reallocations that are driven by comparative advantage. The model of this paper is more closely related to the strand of the trade-environment literature that deals with the implications of Foreign Direct Investment (FDI), and more specifically FDI in services. The optimistic micro view is that FDI supports knowledge transfer and market-penetration of innovative technologies which allow firms to reduce energy-pollution-intensity of production and consumption with the potential of leapfrogging, i.e. the possibility to bypass environment-intensive developments (Gentry 1999; Mielnik and Goldemberg, 2002). Since the papers of Markusen (1989) and Francois (1990), the theoretical literature has supported the view that the wide availability of business services results in total factor productivity gains to the manufacturing sector and the economy broadly. In recent years, there is a growing body of empirical literature that has found a positive impact on total factor productivity from FDI in business services. 7 In the case of Russia, we discuss below the wide range of commitments to foreign investors in services that Russia has made as part of its WTO accession negotiations. This includes commitments to foreign direct investors in environmental services including sewage services, refuse disposal services, sanitation services, cleaning services of exhaust gases, nature and landscape protection and environmental impact assessment services. The prospect of FDI-induced environmental improvements in host countries through better technologies and higher environmental standards is referred to as the "pollution halo" hypothesis (Zarsky 1999). On theoretical grounds, the scale, composition and technique effect can have positive or negative signs. Given this ambiguity, there is the need for empirical analysis to quantify not only the magnitude but also the direction of the individual and the composite environmental impacts. One rigorous empirical analysis is provided by Antweiler et al. (2001) who estimated the magnitudes of the scale, composition and technique effects for the case of sulphur dioxide concentrations in more than forty countries. According to their econometric regressions, a strong negative technique effect dominated the positive scale effect leading to a decrease in emissions (the technique effect, however, was mainly due to stricter environmental regulations after trade liberalization). Another econometric assessment has been undertaken by Cole et al. (1998) on the emission impacts of trade policy changes suggested by the Uruguay Round. In their analysis the composition effect increased emissions for industrialized countries whereas for most developing countries, emissions associated with 7 For the theoretical literature, see, for example, Markusen (1989) and Francois (1990) and the numerical application of Markusen, Rutherford and Tarr (2005). See Francois and Hoekman (2010) for a survey of more than a dozen empirical studies that support the finding of productivity effects from additional business services. Support comes from a variety of sources including studies that use firm level data, such as Arnold et al., (2011) for the Czech Republic and Fernandes and Paunov (2012) for Chile, Shepotylo and Vakhitov (2012) for Ukraine and Arnold et al., (2012) for India. 6 the composition effect declined. Trade liberalization induced an expansion of energy- intensive industries in industrialized countries and an expansion of labor-intensive manufactures in developing countries thus suggesting that in their analysis the Factor Endowment hypothesis dominates the Pollution Haven hypothesis. More recent empirical work (Frankel and Rose 2005, Kellenberg 2008) highlights the complex interplay between the Factor Endowment hypothesis and the Pollution Haven hypothesis and the need for country- specific analysis to determine which effect dominates based on real data (see also the mixed evidence on environmental impacts through FDI in Esty and Gentry, 1997 and Smarzynska and Wei, 2001). Econometric estimates on the technique effect of trade liberalization are scarce in part because of limited data availability. One exception is Martin (2012) who assesses the implications of trade openness on greenhouse gas emissions by India’s manufacturing firms. Martin found that the reduction in import tariffs led to improved fuel efficiency as fuel efficient manufacturing firms gained market share whereas fuel-inefficient firms lost market share; within the manufacturing sector, improved capital access tended to reduce fuel-intensity rather than increase it because of technological (energy-saving) progress embodied in new vintages. A substantial part of the applied literature on the trade-environment linkage is based on computable general equilibrium analyses. Most applications focus on the mutual effects that trade policies and CO2 reduction policies can have on each other. Examples are Babiker et al. (1997) and Kuik and Gerlagh (2003), who use CRTS multi-region multi-sector CGE models of global trade and energy use. In the same vein, Vennemo et al. (2007) quantify the environmental impacts of China's accession to the WTO as the outcome of scale, composition and technique effects (they use a CRTS small open economy model). They identify a dominate composition effect in favor of clean industries which leads to a decrease of China’s greenhouse gas emissions. 4. CGE Model for Russia: Structure and Data 4.1 Production and Geographic Structure 4.1.1 Sectors, Regions and Core Data There are 30 sectors in the model that are listed in table 1. There are three types of sectors: perfectly competitive goods and services, imperfectly competitive goods sectors and imperfectly competitive business services sectors. 7 We obtain data on the regions of Russia from the publication by Rosstat (2002, 2003) entitled Regions of Russia. 8 The regions have several names in Russian; the most common legal jurisdiction is referred to in Russian as an “oblast.” Oblasts are analogous to states in the United States or provinces in Canada. But there are also jurisdictions known as territories, federal cities, autonomous districts and an autonomous region. We group several contiguous regions into what we call “Regional Markets” (RMs). The mapping of regions into regional markets is shown at the top of table 2. In this paper, we shall analyze effects at the level of the Regional Market. Value-added, exports and imports by sector for our ten regional markets of Russia are presented in tables 3-11. We assume that firms and sectors operate at the Regional Market level, primary factors of production are not able to move between Regional Markets (unless otherwise noted). We assume a nested CES structure of demand (see figures 1, 2 and 3). Since this implies that the structure of demand is both homothetic and weakly separable; consumers and firms in a representative Regional Market r employ multiple stage budgeting for all goods. 4.1.2 Price Determination for Competitive Goods and Services Sectors Firms in each Regional Market have three choices for sales: sell in their own Regional Market; sell to other parts of Russia; or export to the rest of the world. This is depicted in figure 4. Firms maximize revenue for any given output level based on their transformation possibilities between the three types of goods which is defined by a constant elasticity of transformation production function. For all firms within the same Regional Market, the product they export to other parts of Russia (including other regions within their own regional market) is homogeneous. It follows from our assumptions of homogeneous demand and production outside of the own Regional Market, that for each competitive good, say good g, there will be only three prices for good g of Regional Market r: the price of good g in Regional Market r; the price of good g from Regional Market r in other parts of Russia; and the price of good g from Regional Market r in the rest of the world. The structure of demand for goods or services from competitive sectors is shown in figure 2. Consumers and firms in a representative Regional Market r first optimize their choice of expenditures on foreign goods versus goods from Russia. Subsequently they optimally allocate their expenditures between goods from other Russian Regional Markets and their own Regional Market. Finally, they optimally allocate their expenditures between goods from the other Russian Regional Markets. This structure assumes that consumers differentiate the products of producers from different regional markets; but, they regard as 8 The number of regions of Russia has varied over time. This study groups regions of Russia based on data from Rosstat (2002; 2003), which listed 89 regions, and had data on 88. 8 homogeneous the products of producers from different regions within the same regional market. 4.1.3 Structure of Production for Non-Fossil Fuel Sectors In figure 5, we depict the structure of production for non-fossil fuel sectors. Regional firms use intermediate inputs (which can be foreign inputs, inputs from other regions of Russia or from its own region) and primary factors of production to produce output. We emphasize that business services are not part of the “other services” nest; rather business services substitute for primary factors of production in a CES nest. 9 We show that the elasticity of substitution between business services and primary factors of production significantly impacts the results. We generalize Rutherford and Tarr (2010) by allowing for inter-fuel substitution as shown in figure 5. A mathematical description of the 30 sector national model of Russia is available as an appendix to Jensen, Rutherford and Tarr (2004). 4.1.4 Goods Produced Subject to Increasing Returns to Scale The structure of demand for goods produced under increasing returns to scale is shown in figure 3. Consumers (and firms) in RM r, optimally allocate expenditures on good g among the goods available from the different regional markets of Russia and the rest of the world producers. Having decided how much to spend on the products from each regional market, consumers then allocate expenditures among the producers within each regional market. Since we assume identical elasticity of substitution at all levels, this is equivalent to firm level product differentiation of demand. That is, the structure is equivalent to a single stage in which consumers decide how much to spend on the output of each firm in the first stage of optimal allocation of expenditure. We assume that imperfectly competitive manufactured goods may be produced in each region or imported. Both Russian and foreign firms in these industries set prices such that marginal cost (which is constant with respect to output) equals marginal revenue in each regional market. There is a fixed cost of operating in each region and there is free entry, which drives profits to zero for each firm on its sales in each regional market in which it sells. Quasi-rents just cover fixed costs in each region in the zero profit equilibrium. We assume that all firms that produce from the same regional market have the same cost structure, but costs differ across regions. 9 For example, firms can employ an accountant or a lawyer, or contract for accounting or legal services. They can employ a driver and buy a truck, or contract for delivery services. These examples make it evident that it is more appropriate to allow substitution between business services and primary factors of production than to assume a Leontief structure. 9 Foreigners produce goods abroad at constant marginal cost but incur a fixed cost of operating in each RM in Russia. The cif import price of foreign goods is simply defined by the import price; by the zero profits assumption, in equilibrium the import price (less tariffs) must cover fixed and marginal costs that foreign firms incur in each regional market. Similar to foreign firms, Russian firms also produce their goods in their home regions; they incur a fixed cost of operation if each RM in which they operate. By the zero profit constraint, if they operate in a RM, the price of their product must just cover both fixed and marginal costs of operation in that RM. We assume that Russian firms do not have any market power on world markets and thus act as price takers on their exports to world markets. On the exports to the rest of the world then, price equals marginal costs. On sales to Russia, firms must use a specific factor in addition to the other factors of production. The existence of the specific factor implies that additional output or firms can only come at increasing marginal costs. Imperfectly competitive Russian goods producers sell in all of Russia; but services firms do not sell in other Russian regional markets. We employ the standard Chamberlinian large group monopolistic competition assumption within a Dixit-Stiglitz framework, which results in constant markups over marginal cost. For simplicity we assume that the ratio of fixed to marginal cost is constant with respect to all factors of production for all firms producing under increasing returns to scale (in both goods and services). This assumption in a Dixit-Stiglitz based Chamberlinian large-group model assures that output per firm for all firm types remains constant, i.e., the model does not produce rationalization gains or losses. An increase in the number of varieties increases the productivity of the use of imperfectly competitive goods based on the standard Dixit-Stiglitz formulation. Dual to the Dixit-Stiglitz quantity aggregator is the Dixit-Stiglitz cost function which shows the productivity adjusted cost of using the available varieties in the regional market when varieties are purchased at minimum cost for a given output level. This cost function for users of goods produced subject to increasing returns to scale declines in the total number of firms in the industry. The lower the elasticity of substitution, the more valuable is an additional variety. We have assumed that imperfectly competitive firms within a regional market have symmetric cost structures and face symmetric demand for their outputs. It follows from these assumptions that all imperfectly competitive firms from a regional market will obtain the same price in any regional market of Russia in which they operate, although the price will differ across regional markets since the fixed costs associated with entering any regional market vary across the regional markets. 10 4.1.5 Services Sectors That Are Produced in Russia under Increasing Returns to Scale and Imperfect Competition These sectors include telecommunications, financial services, most business services and transportation services. In services sectors, we observe that some services are provided by foreign service providers on a cross border basis analogous to goods providers from abroad. But a large share of business services are provided by service providers with a domestic presence, both multinational and Russian. 10 As shown in figure 5, our model allows for both types of foreign service provision in these sectors. There are cross border services allowed in this sector and they are provided from the firms outside of Russia at constant costs—this is analogous to competitive provision of goods from abroad. Cross border services from the rest of the world, however, are not good substitutes for service providers who have a presence within the regional market of Russia where consumers of these services reside. 11 Russian firms providing imperfectly competitive business services operate at the regional level and organize production in a manner fully analogous to imperfectly competitive Russian firms producing goods. Thus, figure 5 applies to both Russian imperfectly competitive goods and services firms. Other assumptions we made for imperfectly competitive goods producers, such as entry conditions, pricing and symmetry are also apply to imperfectly competitive services providers. The only difference is that we assume that regional services providers sell only in their own regional market (see figure 3). It follows from these assumptions that there is a unique price for all Russian providers of imperfectly competitive business services in a regional market. There are also multinational service firm providers that choose to establish a presence in a Regional Market of Russia in order to compete with regional Russian firms directly in the Russian Regional Market. The decision to locate in a regional market by a multinational must take into account the existence of a fixed cost of operating in a regional market. As with imperfectly competitive goods producers, quasi-rents must cover the fixed plus marginal costs of producing in a regional market and we have a zero profit equilibrium. When multinational service providers decide to establish a domestic presence in a regional market of Russia, they will import some of their technology or management expertise. That is, foreign direct investment generally entails importing specialized foreign inputs. Thus, the cost structure of multinationals differs from Russian service providers. Multinationals incur costs related to both imported primary inputs and Russian primary 10 One estimate puts the world-wide cross-border share of trade in services at 41% and the share of trade in services provided by multinational affiliates at 38%. Travel expenditures 20% and compensation to employees working abroad 1% make up the difference. See Brown and Stern (2001, table 1). 11 Daniels (1985) found that service providers charge higher prices when the service is provided at a distance. 11 factors, in addition to intermediate factor inputs. Foreign provision of services differs from foreign provision of goods, since the service providers use Russian primary inputs. This is shown in figure 6, where we show multinationals combining imported primary inputs with inputs of the service good from the regions within the regional market. Domestic service providers do not import the specialized primary factors available to the multinationals. The structure of production for multinational service providers is identical to that of Russian business service providers (shown in figure 5), except for a CES nest at the top which combines the output shown in figure 5 with imported primary inputs (see figure 6 of Rutherford and Tarr, 2006 for details). Foreign service providers also must use a specific factor to produce the output and this implies that additional output can only be obtained at increasing marginal costs. Since the structure of costs for all multinational firms that provide a service s in a given region m is identical and demand is symmetric, there is a unique price for all multinationals providers of service s in regional market m. For multinational firms, the barriers to foreign direct investment affect their profitability and entry. Reduction in the constraints on foreign direct investment in a region will induce foreign entry that will typically lead to productivity gains because when more varieties of service providers are available, buyers can obtain varieties that more closely fit their demands and needs (the Dixit-Stiglitz variety effect). 4.1.6 Factors of Production Primary factors include skilled and unskilled labor and three types of capital; (i) mobile capital (within regions); (ii) sector-specific capital in the energy sectors reflecting the exhaustible resource; and (iii) sector specific capital in imperfectly competitive sectors. We also have primary inputs imported by multinational service providers, reflecting specialized management expertise or technology of the firm. The existence of sector specific capital in several sectors implies that there are decreasing returns to scale in the use of the mobile factors and supply curves in these sectors slope up. The above list of primary factors exists in all regions. In the case of skilled and unskilled labor it is natural to assume that the representative agent in the region obtains the returns from these factors of production. Consistent with standard trade models, in our central model we assume that capital and labor are immobile between Russia and the Rest of the World. However, this model is a regional disaggregation of a national model of Russia; consequently, it does not seem reasonable to assume that all capital in a region is owned by the agents in that region. Thus, we make the assumption that a fraction of the capital in any region is held by agents outside of the region, but the capital is held by residents in the 12 country. We take the fraction of the capital held by agents in the region to be 50 percent, but this percentage is not crucial to the solution of the model. Regarding the capital of each region that is held outside of the region, it is convenient to think of a national mutual fund that holds the remaining capital in each region. For all three capital types ((i) mobile; (ii) specific capital in the energy sectors; and (iii) specific capital in the IRTS sectors) 50 percent of the capital used in the region is owned by this mutual fund and the balance is owned by the representative agent in the region. The national mutual fund invests in all regions and obtains an overall return. The representative agent in the region also holds shares in the national mutual fund. 12. For each region we report returns to capital as returns to the three types of regional capital held by the region’s representative agent. Plus the region’s representative agent obtains a share of the returns from the national mutual fund. The region’s return from national capital is the region’s share of the return of the national mutual fund reported as a percentage of initial consumption of the region. 4.1.7 Trade Trade flows for perfectly competitive goods between regions and the rest of the world is specified following the Armington (1969) approach, which distinguishes goods by origin. Firm level product differentiation characterizes trade for imperfectly competitive sectors. Regions are assumed to be price takers in the world market – i.e., the representation of the rest of the world is reduced to perfectly elastic import demand and export supply functions (export and import prices from the rest of the world are exogenous). Each region has a balance of trade constraint so that any change in the value of imports (either from the rest of the world or another regional market within Russia) is matched by an increase in the value of exports. Russia as a whole, represented as an aggregate of the regional markets, must satisfy a typical economy-wide balance of the trade constraint. The real exchange rate adjusts to ensure 12 Define M(r) as the representative agent’s share of the returns to the national mutual fund. We calculate M(r) as follows. For each region r, the initial consumption income C(r) equals its endowment income E(r) minus the share of the trade surplus B(r) attributed to the region: C(r) = E(r) – B(r). Define B(r) = [C(r)/C]* B where C is aggregate consumption for Russia and B is the aggregate trade surplus. That is, the region’s share of the trade surplus is proportional to its share of aggregate consumption. E(r) is defined above, but is also defined as: E(r) = L(r) + K(r) + M(r). That is, endowment income for each region is labor income L(r); plus capital income on regional capital held by the representative agent in the region K(r); plus the representative agent’s share of the returns to the national mutual fund M(r). E(r), L(r) and K(r) are all known. We calculate M( r) residually for each region r as: E(r) - L(r) - K(r) = C(r) - B(r) - L(r) - K(r) = M(r) . 13 that any change in the aggregate value of regional imports from the rest of the world, is matched by an equal change in the value of aggregate exports to the rest of the world. 4.1.8 Government Government demand across all regions is fixed at exogenous real levels. The government receives taxes to finance public expenditures. Public surpluses or deficits are balanced through lump-sum transfers with the representative households in each region. 4.2 Emissions Modeling The model accounts for seven pollutants whose environmental and health impacts are listed here along with the quantity of emissions in Russia in 2001. Carbon dioxide (CO2) emissions, which are by far the most important greenhouse gas emissions for Russia, are linked in fixed proportions to the use of coal, natural gas and refined oil products, with CO2 coefficients differentiated by the specific carbon content of the fuels. CO2 abatement can take place by fuel switching (inter-fuel substitution) or energy savings (either by fuel-non-fuel substitution or by a scale reduction of production and final demand activities or by more efficient production technologies that use less fuel per unit of output). All non-CO2 emissions are represented in fixed proportions to output or consumption activities. Estimates of discrete abatement potentials for non-CO2 emissions and associated 14 costs for these technologies are directly integrated into the model by means of an activity analysis approach. 4.3 Key Data 4.3.1 Emissions Data In our appendix, we provide detailed documentation of our data sources for pollution emissions in Russia and how we incorporated these data into our model. Here we summarize the key data that are relevant for the policy scenarios. Total emissions of our seven pollutants in Russia are listed here. Emission quantities of pollutants in the base year (2001). Note: Mt= million tons; kt= thousand tons. Figure 7 provides information on how the total of CO2 emissions is distributed across production activities and final consumption in the base year. We label final consumption as “c” on the horizontal axis. We see that the electricity sector is by far the most important source of CO2 emissions in the Russian economy, followed by ferrous metal production and housing services (the latter includes heating). With respect to environmental impacts of trade liberalization and the economic implications of emission control policies, emission intensities play a key role. The more emission intensive a sector is, the more adversely its production should be affected by pricing of emission inputs (another key determinant of adjustment cost is the ease of substituting away from emission inputs as described through the nesting structure and the elasticities of substitution between inputs). In figure 7 we show the total CO2 emissions across Russian 15 industries; in figure 8, we show emission intensities across Russian industries (aggregate for the economy). CO2 emission intensities are composed of direct emissions from fossil fuel inputs (bottom of the bar in the figure) as well as indirect emission embodied in electricity inputs (upper part of the bar). Emission intensities in coal and gas production, electricity generation and pipeline transportation (including gas leakage) are the highest. Indirect emissions embodied in electricity play a secondary role for most sectors. In table 12c (alternately we present the same data in figure 9), we report emission intensities for non-CO2 pollutants across industries – listed in descending order for sulfur dioxide (SO2). Electricity generation, non-ferrous and ferrous industries rank highest. These sectors also show substantial emission intensities for carbon monoxide (CO) where crude oil production has by far the highest intensity. The release of hydrocarbons (CnHm) is predominantly associated with coal production and transportation activities. Energy cost shares across industries are depicted in figure 10. 4.3.2 Ad Valorem Equivalence of Barriers to Foreign Direct Investment in Services Sectors The business services sectors have been the subject of some of the most intense negotiations associated with Russian accession. Russia has made numerous commitments in this area. In many cases, Russia has implemented changes in the services sectors prior to accession to adapt to post-WTO requirements; in other cases, the commitments may be implemented only several years after accession due to a negotiated adjustment period. The counterfactual scenario that we implement in the business services sectors attempts to encapsulate all these cumulative reforms. Some of the key concessions are the following. Russia has agreed to increase the quota on the maximum share that foreign banks and insurance companies can attain from 15 percent to 50 percent. Russia will phase out the prohibition on foreign participation in mandatory insurance lines and has agreed to allow branches of foreign insurance companies to sell insurance in Russia nine years after the date of its accession. Russia reportedly agreed to terminate the Rostelecom monopoly on long distance fixed line telephone services as part of the Russia-EU bilateral agreement and did so several years prior to accession. (There were also multinational telephone operators operating in the Russian mobile telephone market several years prior to accession.) Russia will ensure national treatment and market access for a wide variety of professions, including lawyers, accountants, architects, engineers, marketing specialists, and health care professionals. Foreign owned companies will be permitted to 16 engage in wholesale and retail trade, franchise sectors and express courier services. 13 The European Union has negotiated intensely for the rights of companies other than Gazprom to construct a gas pipeline; but no success in this area has been reported. In banking, opposition galvanized around the branch banking issue. Russia was willing to allow subsidiaries of international banks. Subsidiaries must be registered as Russian entities, and the capital requirements would be based on capital in the Russian entity. Branches, however, do not have a separate legal status or capital requirement apart from their foreign parent bank. So branches are potentially very powerful competitors. The U.S. Treasury has been attempting to ensure branch banking is permitted in all countries admitted to the WTO. The Russian central bank maintained that it could not regulate or supervise branches adequately and that depositors would therefore be at risk. Banking interests in Russia succeeded in getting then President Putin himself to say that branch banking was a deal breaker for Russian WTO accession. Russia succeeded in avoiding a commitment on branch banking, becoming the only non-LDC acceding country to avoid such a commitment. 14 Nonetheless, multinational banks, operating as subsidiaries, have greater market access and national treatment rights under the bilateral U.S.-Russia agreement and Russia should benefit from greater involvement of multinational banks in Russia over time. Estimates of the ad valorem equivalence of these and other barriers to FDI in services are key to the results. Consequently, we commissioned several surveys from Russian research institutes that specialize in these sectors and econometric estimates of these barriers based on these surveys. These questionnaires provided us with data, descriptions and assessments of 15 the regulatory environment in these sectors. Using this information and interviews with specialist staff in Russia, as well as supplementary information, Kimura, Ando and Fujii (2004a, 2004b, 2004c) then estimated the ad valorem equivalence of barriers to foreign direct investment in several Russian sectors, namely in telecommunications; banking, insurance and securities; and maritime and air transportation services. The process involved converting the answers and data of the questionnaires into an index of restrictiveness in each industry. Kimura et al. then applied methodology explained in the volume by C. Findlay and T. Warren (2000), notably papers by Warren (2000), McGuire and Schulele (2000) and Kang (2000). 13 See Tarr (2007) for details. 14 Russia agrees to reopen discussions on this issue upon consideration of membership in the OECD. 15 This information was provided by the following Russian companies or research institutes: Central Science Institute of Telecommunications Research (ZNIIS) in the case of telecommunications, Expert RA for banking, insurance and securities; Central Marine Research and Design Institute (CNIIMF) for maritime transportation services and Infomost for air transportation services. We thank Vladimir Klimushin of ZNIIS; Dmitri Grishankov and Irina Shuvalova of ExpertRA; Boris Rybak and Dmitry Manakov of InfoMost; and Tamara Novikova, Juri Ivanov and Vladimir Vasiliev of CNIIMF. The questionnaires are available at www.worldbank.org/trade/russia-wto. The same sources provided the data on share of expatriate labor discussed below. 17 For each of these service sectors, authors in the Findlay and Warren volume evaluated the regulatory environment across many countries. The price of services is then regressed against the regulatory barriers to determine the impact of any of the regulatory barriers on the price of services. Kimura et al. then assumed that the international regression applies to Russia. Applying that regression and their assessments of the regulatory environment in Russia from the questionnaires and other information sources, they estimated the ad valorem impact of a reduction in barriers to foreign direct investment in these services sectors. 16 The results of the estimates are listed in table 12a. 17 In the case of maritime and air transportation services, we assume that the barrier will only be cut by 15 percentage points, since WTO commitments in these sectors are weak. 4.3.3 Share of Expatriate Labor Employed by Multinational Service Providers The impact of liberalization of barriers to foreign direct investment in business services sectors on the demand for labor in these sectors will depend importantly on the share of expatriate labor used by multinational firms. We explain in the results section that despite the fact that multinationals use Russian labor less intensively than their Russian competitors, if multinationals use mostly Russian labor their expansion is likely to increase the demand for Russian labor in these sectors. 18 We obtained estimates of the share of expatriate labor or specialized technology that is used by multinational service providers in Russia, but which is not available to Russian firms, from the Russian research institutes that specialize in these sectors. In general, we found that multinational service providers use mostly Russian primary factor inputs and only small amounts of expatriate labor or specialized technology. In particular, the estimated share of foreign inputs used by multinationals in Russia is: telecommunications, 10% plus or minus 2%; financial services, 3%, plus or minus 2%; maritime transportation, 3%, plus or minus 2%; and air transportation, 12.5%, plus or minus 2.5%. 4.3.4 Tariff and Export Tax Data Tariff rates by sector are taken from the paper by Shepotylo and Tarr (2012). They estimate the applied MFN tariff rates at the ten digit level in Russia for all years from 2001 to 16 Warren estimated quantity impacts and then using elasticity estimates was able to obtain price impacts. The estimates by Kimura et al. that we employ are for “discriminatory” barriers against foreign direct investment. Kimura et al. also estimate the impact of barriers on investment in services that are the sum of discriminatory and non-discriminatory barriers. 17 See Jensen, Rutherford and Tarr (2006) for an explanation of the estimate in telecommunications. 18 See Markusen, Rutherford and Tarr (2005) for a detailed explanation on why FDI may be a partial equilibrium substitute for domestic labor but a general equilibrium complement. 18 2020. They also provide aggregated tariff rates for the sectors of our model. From 2011 to 2012, the estimates are based on actual tariff rates and trade data in Russia. Russia will implement its tariff commitments under its WTO accession agreement progressively from 2012 to 2020. For 2012 to 2020, Shepotylo and Tarr estimate changes based on the progressive tariff reduction commitments Russia has taken under its WTO accession agreement. Unlike in the case of services, there is no evidence that Russia’s tariff commitments impacted its tariffs prior to 2012. Consequently, we take tariffs in 2011 at the benchmark tariff rates. We take the tariff rates in 2020 (when all tariff commitments are implemented) as the tariff rates in the counterfactual. These tariff are reported in table 12a. Export tax rates are calculated from the 2001 input-output table of Rosstat and are reported in table 12a. Since we do not change export taxes in the counterfactual simulations, these parameters are not very important to the results. 4.3.5 Input-Output Tables The core input-output model is the 2001 table produced by Rosstat. The official table contained only 22 sectors, and importantly has little service sector disaggregation. In order to disaggregate the table, we used costs and use shares from our 35 sector Russian input-output table for 1995 prepared by expert S. P. Baranov. (For details see www.worldbank.org/trade/russia-wto.) When we broke up a sector such as oil and gas into oil, gas and oil processing, we assumed that the cost shares and use shares of the sector were the same in 2001 as they were in the 1995 table. For example, steel is an input to the oil and gas sector. Suppose in 1995, that oil purchased 55 percent of the steel used in oil and gas. Then we assume that in 2001, oil purchased 55 percent of the steel used in oil and gas. 4.3.6 Regional IO Tables and Trade Flows of the Regions We constructed input-output tables of the 88 regions that are based on data from the regions (described below) and the national input-output table. The input-output tables for our ten regional markets are aggregates of the input-output tables of the regions in their respective regional markets. We assume that the technology of production is common across regions, so that the input-output coefficients from the national input-output table apply across all regions. As a first step, for each industrial sector, we took the national output from the national input-output table for 2001, and we used the data in Regions of Russia to allocate the shares of that output across the 88 regions. That is, from the Regions of Russia 2001, we have, by region, the value of total industrial output and industry shares of regional industrial output for the year 2000 (table 13.3); thousands of tons of oil recovery, including gas condensate, for the year 2000 19 (table 13.13); extraction of natural gas (in millions of cubic meters for the year 2000, table 13.14); thousands of tons of mined coal for the year 2000 (table 13.15). This allows us to calculate the value of industry output by sector and region. For each industrial sector, we then proportionally scaled the value of region level output so that the sum of industrial output across all regions was equal to the value of national output of the sector from the national input-output table. We infer regional demand (and supply) of services, assuming that intermediate and final demand for services share a common intensity of demand in all regions as in the national model. For example, if telecommunications costs are x percent of the costs of nonferrous metals production in the national model, we assume that telecommunications costs are x percent of nonferrous metals costs in each of the regions. Demand for telecommunications from non-ferrous metals will differ across regions, however, since the share of total output attributable to non-ferrous metals differs across regions. We have total external exports and imports by region, as well as the commodity structure of external exports and imports by region for the year 2001 (tables 23.1 and 23.2). We also have unpublished data supplied to us by Rosstat on inter-region exports and imports by sector. That is, for each of over 250 key commodities, we have an 88 by 88 matrix of bilateral trade flows among the regions. Supply and demand balance by region and by commodity requires adjustment of trade intensities. These adjustments assure that region exports and imports in aggregate are consistent with national import and export values, we have to adjust the region import and export intensities. We did this using a methodology that minimized the sum of squares of the difference between the original data on exports and imports and the adjusted exports and imports data, subject to the constraints of supply-demand balance and consistency with the national model data. Since we had greater confidence in the validity of the region output data than the inter-region trade flow matrix, in this optimization process, we fixed the output levels of the regions at the levels we had calculated above. We do not need to make any other adjustments, as the production technologies are assumed consistent across the regions. See appendix C of Rutherford and Tarr (2006) for the GAMS code that created the regional input- output tables. Since in every step of the process, we calculated region shares of the national input- output table, the process yields a set of 88 regional input-output tables which portray a regional disaggregation of the national input-output table. That is, summing over all the 88 input-output tables will yield the national input-output table, including wholesale and retail distribution margins, investment demand and government expenditure. Crucially, we may aggregate the 88 regions into a set of non-overlapping subsets and any such aggregation will 20 yield a set of input-output tables that is fully consistent with the national input-output table. In particular, our ten region model is consistent with the national input-output table. 4.3.7 FDI Shares The methodology is explained in detail in an appendix to Rutherford and Tarr (2006), but briefly, we first employed the NOBUS survey to obtain the shares of workers working in multinationals service sectors in each sector in each region. We used this as a proxy for the share of output in each service sector in each region. We also obtained information from (1) from the Russian service sector institutes mentioned above; (2) Regions of Russia (2003) by Rosstat; and (3) the “BEEPS” survey. Only the NOBUS survey provides data that allows us to estimate shares of multinational ownership by both region and sector. We thus start with our calculations based on the NOBUS information. When found, however, that when we aggregate the NOBUS shares across regions or sectors, the other three sources of information show considerably higher foreign ownership shares than the NOBUS survey. We believe that the NOBUS survey estimates are too small, and adjust them. We adjusted our estimates from the NOBUS to be consistent with the estimates of the service sectors institutes. The service sector institute estimates are lower than those from the BEEPS or Regions of Russia, and thus involve less adjustment of the NOBUS data. We employed least squares adjustment of the NOBUS data so that the weighted average over all of Russia in each sector is consistent with the national estimates we received from the specialist service sector research institutes in Russia. This process will give as a structure of ownership based on the NOBUS survey, with the economy-wide average by sector determined by the national data. Results are presented in table 12b. 5. Results of Policy scenarios 5.1. Policy Scenarios One of our principal interests is the quantification of economic and environmental impacts associated with Russia’s WTO accession. In our central WTO accession scenario without environmental abatement policies, we assume that: (i) barriers to foreign direct investment are eliminated or reduced (depending on the sector); (ii) following the work of Shepotylo and Tarr (2012), applied tariffs will fall according to the commitments of the Russian Federation as part of its WTO accession agreement; and (iii) in line with Rutherford and Tarr (2008; 2010), we postulate that better access to export markets for some industries will lead to improvement in terms of trade ranging from 0.5 percent (sectors: other industrial products, food industry, other goods and services) to 1.5 percent for sectors subject to more 21 intensive antidumping actions (sectors: ferrous metals, non-ferrous metals, chemical and petrochemical products. (See table 12a for details.) We then reflect “green” policy initiatives in Russia by means of three scenarios that capture Russia’s objectives in international climate policy as well as domestic energy use. The three environmental regulation policies we evaluate to reduce carbon emissions by 20 percent are: (i) CO2, market based “cap and trade” regulation; (ii) CST, uniform emissions intensity standards; and (iii) EEF, uniform energy efficiency standards. As mentioned in section 2, Russia is pursuing policies to reduce greenhouse gas emissions. Scenario CO2 imposes a 20 percent reduction of CO2 emissions in Russia from base-year emission levels to be achieved through a system of tradable emission rights (or equivalently a nation-wide CO2 tax). In the case of uniform emissions intensity standards (CST), we require that in all sectors and regions except for fossil fuels sectors (coal, crude oil and gas,) uniformly reduce the intensity of their carbon emissions per unit of the value of output produced. We solve for the uniform reduction in the intensity of carbon emissions such that a 20 percent reduction in carbon emissions is achieved. 19 In the case of uniform energy efficiency standards, we require that in all regions and sectors except electricity and fossil fuel production (crude oil, coal and natural gas) equi-proportionately reduce their use of gas, refined oil and electricity. We solve for the uniform reduction in the use of energy inputs such that a 20 percent reduction in carbon emissions is achieved. As trade liberalization tends to raise incomes, the environmental Kuznets curve suggests that above a given level of income, with higher incomes often comes a demand for greater environmental regulation and the ability to adopt cleaner technologies. In fact, Antweiler et al., (2001) have shown in their empirical study of over 40 countries, trade liberalization has been associated with a cleaner environment due to stronger environmental regulations following trade liberalization. In a third set of scenarios, we assess the impacts of “overlapping” policy reforms where we simultaneously implement our central case WTO accession with each of our three carbon emission reduction policy initiatives (scenarios WTO_CO2, WTO_CST and WTO_EFF). Below, we summarize the main features of our policy scenarios. In tables 13-20a we report results for our seven policy scenario. For all ten regions and for an overall average for Russia, we report aggregate results (welfare, emissions of our seven pollutants, decomposition of the CO2 change into the scale, composition and technique effects, changes 19 We allow for a tolerance in the solution of up to one percentage point of carbon emissions. That is, carbon emissions are reduced by between 19 and 21 percent. 22 in exports, imports, employment, factor returns and real exchange rate). In these tables, we also report output changes for all sectors in all regions. 23 Key features of trade and environmental policy scenarios Scenario name Trade reform Environmental regulation WTO WTO accession None CO2 None 20% CO2 emission reduction through market based cap and trade regulation CST None 20% CO2 emission reduction through emission intensity standards EEF None 20% CO2 emission reduction through energy intensity standards WTO_CO2 WTO accession 20% CO2 emission reduction through cap and trade WTO_CST WTO accession 20% CO2 emission reduction through emission intensity standards WTO_EFF WTO accession 20% CO2 emission reduction through energy intensity standards 24 5.2. WTO Accession Results The aggregate results for each of our ten regions of our WTO simulation scenario without environmental abatement are presented in table 13. Due to the possibility of inter-fuel substitution and optimization of export sales in the energy sectors that were not allowed in Rutherford and Tarr (2010), the estimated welfare gains overall are 0.8 percent of consumption larger with the present model. It has been shown by Rutherford and Tarr (2008; 2010) that the source of the largest gains is the reduction in barriers against foreign investors in services-- accounting for about 70 percent of the total gains. Consistent with the econometric evidence cited above, in our model new services providers increase the productivity of sectors that use services. Russian commitments to reduce barriers against multinational service providers will allow multinationals to obtain greater after tax returns on their investments in Russia and thus initially create positive profits. This will induce the multinationals to increase foreign direct investment to supply the Russian market until the additional entry restores a zero profit equilibrium. Although we find that there is some decline in the number of purely Russian owned businesses serving the services markets, on balance there will be additional service providers. Russian users of businesses services will then have improved access to the providers of services in areas like telecommunication, banking, insurance, transportation and other business services. 5.2.1 Explaining Differences across Regions While the average gain in welfare from WTO accession as a percent of GDP for the whole country is 4.0 percent, we estimate that the three regions that gain the most are: Northwest (5.6 percent), St. Petersburg (5.2 percent) and Far East (4.8 percent). The principal explanation for the differences across regions is the ability of the different regions to benefit from a reduction in barriers against foreign direct investment. Some regions may attract FDI much more easily than others. A key parameter in our model is the initial share of multinational investment in each sector in each region. Multinational firms have widely different shares of the business services sectors in the different regions. A 10 percent expansion of multinational firms will be a much larger absolute amount in a region that has substantial FDI initially. Thus, larger initial shares of FDI in a region will lead to larger absolute increases in FDI in the region when the barriers against FDI are reduced. In table 12b, we display our estimates of the shares of the industry captured by multinational firms. The three regions with the largest welfare gains are clearly the regions with the estimated largest shares of multinational investment (along with a fourth region, the 25 North region, which also gains substantially). All have estimated multinational shares of the service sector that are twice the national average in maritime services, rail services, truck services, air transportation services, telecommunications, science and financial services. On the other hand, we estimate that the Urals will gain only 3.3% of GDP, considerably less than the national average. But we see from table 12b that the Urals has relatively little FDI in the services sectors, as the Urals share of FDI ranges from about 50 to 70 percent of the national average depending on the sector. 5.2.2 Impact of WTO Accession on Carbon Emissions In table 13, we report the impact of WTO accession on carbon emissions, where we show the decomposition of emissions into the scale, composition and technique effects based on the following methodology. Let E = emissions, Y = the value of aggregate output, ai = emissions per unit of the value of output, yi = the value of output of sector i and . = the share of sector i’s output in the economy. With n sectors in the economy, aggregate emissions are: (1) = ∑ i= 1,…n (2) = ∑ where yi = Y i= 1,…n. It follows that, in the neighborhood of the equilibrium, the percentage change in emissions can be decomposed into: ΔE ΔY ∑ Δ ∑ Δ (3) = + ∑ + ∑ i= 1,…n. Y The first term on the right side of equation 3 is the scale effect; the second term is the composition effect and the third term is the technique effect. In all of our scenarios, we show the percentage change in carbon emissions in total and due to each of these three effects for each of the ten regions of our Russia model and an overall average for the Russian economy. 20 Looking at the overall average, we see that WTO accession increases carbon emissions by 4.3 percent. The main reason for the increase in emissions is the increase in output, as the increased scale of output results in an increase in carbon emissions of 4.9 20 Although our decomposition is based on a methodology that is a local approximation to a discrete change, we find that the sum of our components are accurate to within 0.5 percent points of carbon dioxide emissions in all cases except WTO_CST, where the tolerance is 1.2 percentage points of carbon dioxide emissions. 26 percent. The composition effect also increases emissions in the case of Russia by 1.0 percent. While the composition effect is ambiguous in general, the reason is that it has an adverse environmental impact in Russia is that two of the relatively dirty industries, namely ferrous metals and chemicals and petrochemicals, are (along with non-ferrous metals) the sectors that expand the most. 21 As shown in table 14, ferrous metals output expands in all nine of the regions in which it is produced. Output of chemicals and petro-chemicals expand in all ten regions. We have also shown that overall (Jensen, Rutherford and Tarr, 2007), non-ferrous metals output expands the most of any sector in the model. The reason these sectors expand is that trade liberalization, in general, tends to benefit export intensive sectors, since export intensive sectors experience the benefit of the removal of the anti-export bias of trade protection realized through a depreciated real exchange rate. In the case of Russia, it is ferrous metals, non-ferrous metals and chemicals that intensively export (two of which intensively emit carbon dioxide), while the relatively cleaner sectors, such as food and light industry, which do little exporting, decline in most regions. The technique effect, however, works toward a cleaner environment, reducing carbon emissions by 1.6 percent. The technique effect in this scenario comes about primarily due to increased productivity with existing resources due to the Dixit-Stiglitz productivity externality from additional varieties of imperfectly produced goods and services and a shift toward a less fossil fuel intensive form of production. 5.3. Evaluating Alternate Policy Reforms to Reduce Carbon Emissions by 20 Percent We emphasize that in all of our green policy scenarios, we do not calculate the benefits of a cleaner environment. Although this calculation is beyond scope of our analysis, we do not mean to infer that the net welfare change of these environmental policies is negative. Rather, we take a cleaner environment as an objective desired by the authorities, and assess different environmental regulations in terms of their direct economic costs, and by implication, political feasibility. 5.3.1 Market Based Carbon Emissions Trading (“Cap and Trade”) In tables 15 and 15a we show the results of our estimates of a policy of using a system of tradable emission rights (or equivalently a nation-wide CO2 tax) to achieve a 20 percent carbon emission reduction. We find that it would cost 0.5 percent of GDP. From our 21 In our dataset, non-ferrous metals does not intensively emit carbon dioxide; see figure 7. 27 decomposition analysis, we see that the reduction in carbon emissions is accomplished primarily through the technique effect. Although there is a modest 1 percent reduction in emissions through output reduction and a shift to cleaner industries results in a 3.1 percent reduction in carbon emissions, the technique effect accounts for over 16 percent reduction in carbon emissions. Since there are no productivity gains in this scenario, unlike our WTO accession scenario, the technique effect derives from fuel switching toward fuels that emit fewer carbon emissions and a switch to a less fuel intensive form of production. 5.3.2. Carbon Emissions Intensity Standards In tables 16 and 16a, we present our assessment of the impact of requiring a uniform reduction in the intensity of carbon emissions per unit of the value of output produced at the sector and regional level (coal, crude oil and gas production excluded). We find that requiring a 20 percent reduction in emissions intensity achieves the outcome of a 20 percent reduction in carbon emissions and does so at a cost of about 0.8 percent of GDP. Again, it is the technique effect which dominates the adjustment in carbon emissions, accounting for 17.1 percent reduction in carbon emissions. As expected, emission intensity standards are not as efficient as the market based emission trading system, but the additional costs of achieving the 20 percent carbon reduction are only 0.3 percent of GDP. The relatively small additional cost of this “command and control” regulation compared with a market based system can be attributed to the fact that “emissions intensity” is close to the target of a reduction in carbon emissions. 5.3.3 Energy Efficiency Standards In tables 17 and 17a, we show the results of our assessment of the impact of uniform energy efficiency standards where we require that in all regions and sectors except electricity and fossil fuel production (crude oil, coal and natural gas) to equi-proportionately reduce their use of gas, refined oil and electricity to achieve a 20 percent reduction in carbon emissions. We find that a uniform requirement to cut use of fossil fuel use by 25 percent, results in a 20 percent reduction in carbon emissions. The cost in terms of loss in GDP, however, is a very substantial 2.7 percent of GDP, more than five times the cost of the emissions trading system to achieve the same carbon emissions reduction. The higher cost of achieving the carbon emission reduction is partly due to the lack of adjustments of a market based system; but our results show that even more important is the fact that, compared with emissions intensity standards, energy efficiency standards do not closely target the objective of lower carbon emissions. 28 On the positive side for energy efficiency standards is that they achieve a much greater reduction in non-CO2 emissions than carbon emissions trading or carbon emissions intensity standards. This is especially true regarding nitrogen oxide and particulate matter, where energy efficiency standards achieve a double digit percent reduction. 5.4 Combining WTO Accession with Policies to Reduce Carbon Emissions by 20 Percent Given that many countries have complemented trade liberalization with policies to improve the environment, in this section we evaluate the impacts of Russia simultaneously acceding to the WTO and implementing one of our carbon reduction policies. 5.4.1 WTO Accession Combined with Carbon Emissions Trading In tables 18 and 18a, we show our results for combining WTO accession with a regulation to cut carbon emissions by 20 percent through carbon emissions trading. Although overall welfare gains fall compared with WTO accession independently, overall welfare gains as a percent of consumption remain high at 7.2 percent of consumption. Interestingly, while the composition effect of WTO accession alone increases carbon emissions due to an increase in the production of ferrous metals, chemicals and petro-chemicals, the composition effect is positive when combined with environmental regulation through emissions trading. We show in table 17a that in this combined scenario, the chemicals and petro-chemicals sector declines in eight of the ten regions and the ferrous metals sector declines in all sectors where it is produced. In addition, production of oil, gas and the pipeline sector decline in this scenario. The technique effect becomes even more important in this scenario, as it is responsible for a decline of 19.5 percent in total carbon emissions. In addition to switching away from fossil fuel use, the productivity gains of WTO accession allow production of output with fewer fossil fuels. 5.4.2 WTO Accession Combined with Emission Intensity Standards In tables 19 and 19a, we display our results for combining WTO accession with a regulation to cut carbon emissions by 20 percent by requiring all sectors (except for fossil fuels sectors) and regions to uniformly reduce the intensity of their carbon emissions per unit of the value of output produced. The welfare gain of 6.4 percent of consumption is substantial, but constitutes a reduction of 2.2 percent of consumption compared with WTO accession alone and a further reduction of 0.8 percent of consumption compared with 29 emissions trading combined with WTO accession. The switch to clean industries (the composition effect) is much weaker in this scenario than under emissions trading, since all sectors must reduce the intensity of their emissions uniformly, even if they start with fewer emissions per ruble of output. Then switching production to clean industries does not help achieve the regulatory target. Consequently, in this policy simulation, the technique effect is the strongest of all seven of our core policy scenarios. 5.4.3 WTO Accession Combined with Energy Efficiency Standards In tables 20 and 20a, we display the aggregate results for our ten regions of our final policy scenario in which we combine WTO accession with the regulatory requirement that all sectors except electricity and fossil fuel production (coal, natural gas and oil refining), uniformly reduce their use of gas, oil and electricity such that carbon emissions are reduced by 20 percent. With this environmental policy, the welfare gains fall very substantially to 0.6 percent of consumption. Thus, judged on the basis of carbon emissions alone, this policy is by far the most costly. In table 21, however, we can see that energy efficiency standards to achieve carbon emissions reduction are considerably more effective at achieving a reduction in emissions other than carbon dioxide. In fact, energy efficiency standards are more effective at reducing all six non-CO2 emissions. 6. Sensitivity Analysis 6.1 Results with Constant Returns to Scale and Perfect Competition As we mentioned above, most models that assess the impact of trade on the environment assume constant returns to scale and perfect competition, and exclude foreign direct investment and productivity impacts. In this sub-section, we investigate the impact of our more innovative and empirically accurate modeling framework by executing our seven basic scenarios in a model with constant returns to scale and perfect competition. In table 22, we show the aggregate results for the overall economy of all seven scenarios in a constant returns to scale model. Table 22 is directly comparable to table 21, where the latter is based on our central model with increasing returns to scale and FDI in services. Examining WTO accession alone, with constant returns to scale, the estimated welfare gains are much smaller; at 0.5 percent of GDP, they are within the range of the “Harberger constant.” 22 At the same time, the negative impact on emissions of all seven pollutants is considerably smaller in the CRTS model. The reason is that the smaller welfare 22 The Harberger constant is the loose characterization that the welfare gains from trade reform in constant returns to scale models is less than 1 percent of GDP. 30 gains are associated with smaller output expansion, which results in lesser emission of pollutants. In the case of CO2 emissions, our decomposition analysis shows that the negative scale effect on CO2 emissions, which is the primary culprit in the increase in CO2 emissions with IRTS, is much smaller in the CRTS model. A key result of our analysis with our central model is reversed with the CRTS model. We found that with IRTS, WTO accession is expected to expand incomes by more than enough to pay for the cost of environmental abatement policies, even if the least efficient policy of environmental regulation is used. With CRTS, simultaneous application of WTO accession and environmental regulation yields net benefits only if the market based cap and trade system is employed, and a substantial loss if the least efficient environmental policy is employed. When simultaneously applied with WTO accession, energy efficiency standards, which is the least efficient of our three environmental policies for CO2 reduction, yields a net welfare loss of 1.6 percent of GDP. 6.2 Piecemeal Sensitivity Analysis In tables 23a—23g, we present our estimates of the impact on emissions of our seven pollutants and welfare as a percent of GDP of varying the value of key parameters. In these scenarios, we retain the central value of all parameters except the parameter in question. We show results for each region and an overall economy average. As far as welfare is concerned, the gains to the economy generally increase with an increase in elasticities, since higher elasticities imply that the economy is able to more easily shift to sectors or products that are cheaper after trade and FDI liberalization.23 There are two parameters in the table that have a strong impact on the results: the elasticity of substitution between value-added and business services (esubs) and the elasticity of multinational firm supply (etaf). A liberalization of the barriers to FDI will result in a reduction in the cost of business services, both from the direct effect of lowering the costs of doing business for multinational service providers and from the indirect effect that additional varieties of business services allow users to purchase a quality adjusted unit of services at less cost. When the elasticity of substitution between value-added and business services is high (esubs = 2 in table 23a), users have the greater potential to substitute the cheaper business services and this increases productivity. The elasticity of multinational and Russian firm supply (etaf, etad) is primarily dependent on the sector specific factor for each firm type (foreign or domestic). When etaf is high, a reduction in the barriers to foreign direct investment results in a larger expansion in the number of 23 An increase in the elasticity of substitution between varieties reduces the welfare gain. This is because when varieties are good substitutes, additional varieties are worth less to firms and consumers. 31 multinational firms supplying the Russian market, and hence more gains from additional varieties of business services. In addition, the share of the services market captured by multinationals has a strong effect, since a liberalization results in a larger number of new varieties introduced. In tables 23b through 23g, we show the sensitivity of emissions to the parameters. In general, emissions of pollutants are more sensitive to the parameter specification than economic welfare. Carbon dioxide, sulphur dioxide, volatile organic components and especially hydrocarbons are especially sensitive to the parameter esubs. This shows that the scale and composition effects significantly dominate the technique effect. Higher values of esubs allow greater use on newer technologies (technically new varieties), which reduces pollution through the technique effect. But higher values of esubs mean more output expansion, and this (along with the shift to dirty industries we have noted) dominates, especially for most of the non-CO2 pollutants. 7. Conclusions To gain insights into the pending trade-offs between trade and FDI liberalization and pollution in Russia, we developed a ten-region, 30 sector model of the Russian economy. Our model contains foreign direct investment, imperfectly competitive sectors and endogenous productivity effects triggered by WTO accession. We incorporated environmental emissions data in Russia for seven pollutants which are tracked for all 30 sectors in each of the ten Russian regions of our model. We find that WTO accession alone will increase environmental pollution in Russia. Our decomposition shows that the negative effect on the environment of the composition effect (especially the relative expansion of dirty industries) and the expansion of output (scale effect) dominate the positive impact on the environment of the technique effect (which includes importing new, more efficient technologies, processes and services). Given the adverse impact on the environment of WTO accession, and that part of the income increase from WTO accession might be used to pay for environmental abatement, we assess the costs of three types of environmental regulations to reduce carbon dioxide emissions by 20 percent: market based “cap and trade”; emission intensity standards; and energy efficiency standards. In a third set of scenarios, we assess the impacts of “overlapping” policy reforms where we simultaneously implement our central case scenario of WTO accession with each of our three carbon emission reduction policy initiatives. We find that the welfare gains of WTO accession are large enough to pay for the costs of any of the three environment abatement policies, while leaving a net welfare gain. In 32 order to assist regulators in the design of policies that would minimize opposition to environmental regulation, we have assessed the relative costs of three alternate policies that achieve a 20 percent reduction in carbon dioxide emissions. We find that the market based “cap and trade” regulation is the least costly of the three policies, followed by emission intensity standards (which is reasonably efficient). Energy efficiency policies are significantly more costly at achieving the same level of carbon dioxide reduction compared with cap and trade and emissions intensity standards. In our sensitivity analysis, we find that there are drastic differences in the economic and environmental impacts between model simulations without and with the endogenous productivity effects of our model with increasing returns to scale and foreign direct investment. In particular, with a CRTS model, the welfare gains are insufficient to finance the costs of the least efficient environmental regulation. References Antweiler, W., B. R. Copeland, M. S. Taylor (2001), “Is Free Trade Good for the Environment?” The American Economic Review, 91: 877-908. Arnold, Jens M., Beata S. Javorcik and Aaditya Mattoo (2011), “Does Services Liberalization Benefit Manufacturing Firms: Evidence from the Czech Republic,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 85 (1), 136-146. Arnold, Jens M., Beata S. Javorcik, Molly Lipscomb and Aaditya Mattoo (2012), “Services reform and manufacturing performance: evidence from India,” World Bank Policy and Research Working Paper Series Paper No. 5948, January. Babiker, M. H., K. E. Maskus and T. F. Rutherford (1997), “ Carbon Taxes and the Global Trading System,” Paper prepared for presentation at the International Energy Workshop and Energy Modelling Forum Meeting at IIASA, June 23-25, 1997, Laxenburg, Austria. Cole, M.A., A. J. Rayner, J. M. Bates (1998), “Trade liberalization and the environment: The case of the Uruguay Round,” The World Economy, 21, 337-347. Copeland, B. R., and M. S. Taylor (1994), “North-South trade and the environment,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109: 755-787. Copeland, B. R. and M. S. Taylor (1995), “Trade and Transboundary Pollution,” American Economic Review, 85(4): 716-73. Dean, J. M. (1992), “Trade and the Environment: A Survey of the Literature,” In: P. Low (Ed.), International Trade and the Environment, Washington, D.C.: The World Bank, 15-28. Dean, J. M. (2002), International Trade and the Environment, Aldershot UK: Ashgate Publishing. 33 Dixit, A. K. and J. E. Stiglitz (1977), “Monopolistic Competition and Optimum Product Diversity,” American Economic Review, 67: 297–308. Ethier, W.J. (1982), “National and International Returns to Scale in the Modern Theory of International Trade,” American Economic Review, 72(2):389-405. Fernandes, Ana M. and Caroline Paunov (2012), “Foreign direct investment in services and manufacturing productivity: evidence for Chile,” Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 97 (2), March, 305-321. Findlay, Christopher and Tony Warren, eds., (2000), Impediments to Trade in Services: Measurement and Policy Implications, London: Routledge. Francois, Joseph F. (1990), “Trade in Producer Services and Returns due to Specialization under Monopolistic Competition,” Canadian Journal of Economics, 23:109-124. Francois, Joseph and Bernard Hoekman (2010), “Services Trade and Policy,” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 48 (September), 642-692. Frankel, J. A., and A. K. Rose (2005), “Is Trade Good or Bad for the Environment? Sorting Out the Causality,” The Review of Economics and Statistics, 87 (1): 85-91. Gentry, B.S. (1999), “Foreign Direct Investment and the Environment: Boon or Bane?” in: Foreign Direct Investment and the Environment, OECD proceedings, Paris, 21-46. Grossman, G.M. and A. B. Krueger (1993), “Environmental impacts of a North American free trade agreement,” In: Garber, P.M. (Ed.), The U.S.-Mexico Free Trade Agreement. MIT Press, Cambridge, USA. Helpman, E. (1981), “International Trade in the Presence of Product Differentiation, Economies of Scale, and Monopolistic Competition: A Chamberlin–Heckscher–Ohlin Model,” Journal of International Economics, 11: 305–340. Hummels, David and Volodymyr Lugovsky (2005), “Trade in Ideal Varieties: Theory and Evidence,” http://www.nber.org/papers/w11828, December. IFC (2008), Energy Efficiency in Russia: Untapped Reserves. International Finance Corporation. Ivanova, Nadezhda (2005), “Estimates of Own and Cross-Price Elasticities of Disaggregated Imported and Domestic Goods in Russia,” www.worldbank.org/trade/russia-wto, September. Jensen, Jesper, Thomas F. Rutherford and David G. Tarr (2004), “The Impact of Liberalizing Barriers to Foreign Direct Investment in Services: The Case of Russian Accession to the World Trade Organization,” World Bank Policy and Research Working Paper No. 3391. Available at: www.worldbank.or/trade/russia-wto. Jensen, Jesper, Thomas F. Rutherford and David G. Tarr (2007), “The Impact of Liberalizing Barriers to Foreign Direct Investment in Services: The Case of Russian Accession to the World Trade Organization,” Review of Development Economics 11: 482-506. Kang, Joog-Soon (2000), “Price Impact of Restrictiveness on Maritime Transportation Services,” in Findlay, Christopher and Tony Warren (eds), Impediments to Trade in Services: Measurement and Policy Implications, London: Routledge. 34 Kellenberg, D. K. (2008), “A Reexamination of the Role of Income for the Trade and Environment Debate,” Ecological Economics, 68(1-2): 106-115. Kimura, Fukunari, Mitsuyo Ando and Takamune Fujii (2004a), “Estimating the Ad Valorem Equivalent of Barriers to Foreign Direct Investment in the Telecommunications Services Sectors in Russia.” Available at http://www.worldbank.org/trade/russia-wto. Kimura, Fukunari, Mitsuyo Ando and Takamune Fujii (2004b), “Estimating the Ad Valorem Equivalent of Barriers to Foreign Direct Investment in the Maritime and Air Transportation Service Sectors in Russia.” Available at http://www.worldbank.org/trade/russia-wto. Kuik, O. J. and R. Gerlagh (2003), “Trade Liberalization and Carbon Leakage,” The Energy Journal, 24: 97- 120. Krugman, P. (1979), “Increasing Returns, Monopolistic Competition, and International Trade,” Journal of International Economics 9:469-479. Krugman, P. (1980), “Scale Economies, Product Differentiation, and the Pattern of Trade,” American Economic Review 70: 950-959. Markusen, James R, Thomas Rutherford and David Tarr (2005), “Trade and Direct Investment in Producer Services and the Domestic Market for Expertise,” Canadian Journal of Economics 38: 758-777. Markusen, James R. (1989), "Trade in Producer Services and in Other Specialized Intermediate Inputs," American Economic Review, 79:85-95. McGuire, Greg and Michael Schuele (2000), “Restrictiveness of International Trade in Banking Services,” in Findlay, Christopher and Tony Warren (eds.), Impediments to Trade in Services: Measurement and Policy Implications, London: Routledge. Melitz, M. J. (2003), “The Impact of Trade on Intra-industry Reallocations and Aggregate Industry Productivity,” Econometrica 71: 1695–1725. Mielnik, O. and J. Goldemberg (2002), “Foreign Direct Investment and Decoupling between Energy and Gross Domestic Product in Developing Countries,” Energy Policy, 30: 87-89. Ministry of Energy of the Russian Federation (2010), Energy Saving and Energy Efficiency Improvement until 2020. Available at: http://minenergo.gov.ru/upload/iblock/b61/b612746a17d6adae790262ad58b4c9d9.do c Ministry of Natural Resources and Environment of the Russian Federation (2014), State Program of the Russian Federation for Protection of the Environment, 2012-2020. Available at: http://www.mnr.gov.ru/upload/iblock/34e/Gosprogramma_OOS.pdf Rauscher, M. (1997), International Trade, Factor Movements and the Environment, Oxford: Oxford University Press. Romer, P. (1994), “New Goods, Old Theory, and the Welfare Costs of Trade Restrictions,” Journal of Development Economics, 43: 5–38. 35 Rosgidromet (2013) Review of environment and pollution in the Russian Federation in 2012, Moscow: The Federal Service for Hydrometeorology and Environmental Monitoring of Russia. Rossat (2002; 2003), Regions of Russia: Social and Economic Indicators, Moscow: Federal Service of State Statistics. Rosstat (2014) Socio-Economic Situation in Russia, January-April 2014, Moscow: Federal Service of State Statistics. Rutherford, T. F. and D. G. Tarr (2006), “Regional Impacts of Russia’s WTO Accession,” World Bank Policy and Research Working Paper No. 4015, www.worldbank.or/trade/russia-wto, June. Rutherford, T. F. and D. G. Tarr (2008), "Poverty Effects of Russia’s WTO Accession: modeling “real households” and endogenous productivity effects,” Journal of International Economics 75 (2008): 131-150. Rutherford, T. F. and D. G. Tarr (2010). “Regional Impacts of Russia’s WTO Accession,” Review of International Economics, Shepotylo, O. and D. G. Tarr (2008), “Specific Tariffs, Tariff Simplification and the Structure of Import Tariffs in Russia: 2001-2005,” Eastern European Economics, 46: 49-58. Shepotylo, O. and D. G. Tarr (2012), “Impact of WTO Accession and the Customs Union on the Bound and Applied Tariff Rates of the Russian Federation,” World Bank Policy and Research Working Paper No. 6161, August. Forthcoming in Eastern European Economics. Shepotylo, O. and V. Vakhitov (2012), “Services liberalization and productivity of manufacturing firms: evidence from Ukraine,” World Bank Policy and Research Working Paper 5944, January. Vennemo, H., K. Aunanb, J. Hec, T. Hud, S. Lic, and K. Rypdal (2008), “Environmental Impacts of China's WTO-accession,” Ecological Economics, 64: 893-911. Zarsky, L. (1999), “Havens, Halos and Spaghettis – Untangling the Evidence between Foreign Direct Investment and the Environment,” in: Foreign Direct Investment and the Environment, OECD proceedings, Paris, 47-74. 36 Tables Table 1. List of Sectors 1. Sectors where foreign direct investment from new multinational services providers is possible RLW Railway transportation TRK Truck transportation PIP Pipelines transportation MAR Maritime transportation AIR Air transportation TRO Other transportation TMS Telecommunications SCI Science & science servicing FIN Financial services 2. Sectors where new foreign firms may provide new goods from abroad FME Ferrous metallurgy NFM Non-ferrous metallurgy CHM Chemical & oil-chemical industry MWO Mechanical engineering & metal-working TPP Timber & woodworking & pulp & paper industry CNM Construction materials industry FOO Food industry OTI Other industries 3. Competitive sectors subject to constant returns to scale HEA Public services, culture and arts AGR Agriculture & forestry COL Coalmining HOU Housing and communal services CON Construction ELE Electric industry GAS Gas CRU Crude oil extraction OIL Oil refining and processing OTH Other goods-producing sectors PST Post TRD Wholesale and retail trade CLI Textiles and apparel 37 Table 2. List of Russian Regional Markets and Oblasts Russian regional "markets" (markets are aggregates of oblasts defined below) msc Moscow (msk,mos) stp Saint-Petersburg (len,spb) tmn Tumenskaya (tum,kha,yam) vgd Northwest (vol,klg,nov,psk) nor North (kpa,nen,krl,kom,arh,mur) cen Central (bel,bry,vla,vor,iva,kal,kos,krs,lip,orl,rya,smo,tam,tve,tul,yar) sou South (sar,ady,dag,ing,kab,klr,kar,sev,kdk,sta,ast,vlg,ros) url Urals (mar,mor,tat,udm,chv,kir,niz,pen,ulo,ore,sam,bas,per,krg,sve,chl) sib Siberia (alr,bur,tyv,hak,alt,irk,kem,nvs,tom,oms,eve,tai,ust,kra,sah,kam,mag,kor,chu) far Far East (agi,chi,hab,amu,sao,pri,eao) Oblasts (plus Republics, Territories, Federal Cities, Autonomous Regions, Autonomous Districts) 1. ady Adygeya, The Republic of 46. mar Mari El, The Republic of 2. agi Aginsky Buryatsky Autonomous District 47. mor Mordovia, The Republic of 3. alt Altaisky krai 48. msk Moscow city 4. alr Altay Republic 49. mos Moskovskaya 5. amu Amurskaya 50. mur Murmanskaya 6. arh Arkhangelskaya 51. nen Nenetsky Autonomous District 7. ast Astrakhanskaya 52. niz Nizhegorodskaya 8. bas Bashkortostan, The Republic of 53. sev North Osetia, The Republic of 9. bel Belgorodskaya 54. nov Novgorodskaya 10. bry Bryanskaya 55. nvs Novosibirskaya 11. bur Buryatia, The Republic of 56. oms Omskaya 12. chr Chechnya (sou), The Republic of */ 57. ore Orenburgskaya 13. chl Chelyabinskaya 58. orl Orlovskaya 14. chi Chitinskaya 59. pen Penzenskaya 15. chu Chukotsky Autonomous District 60. per Permskaya 16. chv Chuvashia, The Republic of 61. pri Primorsky krai 17. dag Dagestan, The Republic of 62. psk Pskovskaya 18. eve Evenkiysky Autonomous District 63. ros Rostovskaya 19. ing Ingushetia, The Republic of 64. rya Ryazanskaya 20. irk Irkutskaya 65. spb Saint Petersburg City 21. iva Ivanovskaya 66. sah Sakha, The Republic of 22. eao Jewish Autonomous Region 67. sao Sakhalinskaya 23. kab Kabardino Balkaria, The Republic of 68. sam Samarskaya 24. klg Kaliningradskaya 69. sar Saratovskaya 25. kal Kaluzhskaya 70. smo Smolenskaya 26. klr Kalymykia, The Republic of 71. sta Stavropolsky krai 27. kam Kamchatskaya 72. sve Sverdlovskaya 28. kar Karachaevo Cherkessia, The Republic of 73. tai Taimyrsky (Dolgano-Nenetsky) Autonomous 29. krl Karelia, The Republic of District 30. kem Kemerovskaya 74. tam Tambovskaya 31. hab Khabarovsky krai 75. tat Tatarstan, The Republic of 32. hak Khakasia, The Republic of 76. tom Tomskaya 33. kha Khanty-Mansiysky Autonomous District 77. tul Tulskaya 34. kir Kirovskaya 78. tum Tumenskaya 35. kom Komi, The Republic of 79. tve Tverskaya 36. kpa Komi-Permyatsky Autonomous District 80. tyv Tyva, The Republic of 37. kor Koryaksky Autonomous District 81. udm Udmurtia, The Republic of 38. kos Kostromskaya 82. ulo Ulyanovskaya 39. kdk Krasnodarsky krai 83. ust Ust-ordynsky Buryatsky Autonomous District 40. kra Krasnoyarsky krai 84. vla Vladimirskaya 41. krg Kurganskaya 85. vlg Volgogradskaya 42. krs Kurskaya 86. vol Vologodskaya 43. len Leningradskaya 87. vor Voronezhskaya 44. lip Lipetskaya 88. yam Yamalo-Nenetsky Autonomous District 45. mag Maganskaya 89. yar Yaroslavskaya / * No data. 38 Table 3. Value Added in 2000 by Russian Regional Market and by Sector (in billions of 2001 rubles) a/ St. North- Sector Sector b/ Central Far East North Siberia South Urals Moscow Petersb. Tumen west total MAR 4.7 1.3 1.4 7.2 4.1 14.7 4.0 1.7 6.9 1.0 47.1 AGR 110.2 17.5 7.4 84.8 125.2 155.3 15.2 11.8 8.2 15.1 550.7 AIR 3.6 1.3 1.0 5.3 4.5 10.0 14.9 1.6 2.5 0.6 45.2 CHM 13.9 0.3 1.6 10.6 9.3 35.6 7.7 2.0 0.1 4.2 85.4 CNM 10.3 1.1 0.7 4.6 6.7 12.2 8.8 2.4 0.8 0.7 48.2 COL 0.1 5.2 3.2 32.6 1.7 1.2 43.9 CON 76.4 7.1 6.1 54.7 105.2 151.6 138.6 29.7 24.1 11.4 605.0 CRU 4.5 16.9 9.9 37.7 97.5 282.9 1.0 450.3 ELE 26.7 7.8 7.1 34.7 22.9 62.9 42.9 10.5 19.1 5.8 240.4 FIN 43.5 16.4 14.3 60.7 44.0 106.8 115.7 20.8 47.0 9.0 478.0 FME 19.0 0.5 1.6 9.0 3.9 33.8 2.3 1.1 11.3 82.5 FOO 24.9 9.2 3.7 17.4 24.0 28.1 33.9 17.7 0.5 4.7 164.2 GAS 0.2 0.4 0.5 1.5 2.8 52.2 0.0 57.5 HEA 42.3 17.5 14.6 58.8 45.0 100.6 126.3 21.8 40.6 8.9 476.4 HOU 22.1 8.8 6.7 29.1 24.8 50.9 68.0 11.2 13.7 4.6 239.8 MWO 38.7 11.2 2.6 19.4 18.0 101.8 45.4 18.9 3.0 3.6 262.7 NFM 2.5 8.1 9.3 113.2 4.8 46.0 7.1 4.4 0.2 195.5 OIL 12.2 4.7 1.5 17.4 10.1 39.2 4.4 7.2 3.9 100.6 OTH 7.7 2.0 2.2 8.8 4.9 18.4 6.3 3.3 7.4 1.9 62.8 OTI 13.6 0.6 0.7 2.5 4.0 9.2 9.9 2.6 0.1 0.9 44.0 PIP 1.5 0.5 0.5 2.0 1.7 5.4 1.2 0.7 5.2 0.2 18.7 PST 2.7 1.0 0.8 3.5 2.9 6.3 6.8 1.3 2.8 0.6 28.7 RLW 23.5 6.9 6.3 30.2 20.5 53.8 34.5 9.4 16.1 6.2 207.3 SCI 8.8 3.2 2.4 10.4 7.8 22.6 16.5 4.1 9.8 1.5 87.0 TMS 7.6 2.8 2.2 10.1 8.3 18.7 21.1 3.6 7.4 1.5 83.3 TPP 6.8 4.4 15.1 13.1 2.6 13.0 6.8 7.3 0.6 4.2 73.9 TRD 205.4 78.2 67.0 300.6 223.3 535.3 456.6 101.6 386.8 48.2 2,402.9 TRK 10.2 3.5 3.1 13.6 11.3 24.6 23.0 4.7 12.9 2.2 109.2 TRO 4.5 1.5 1.3 5.7 5.1 11.2 10.7 2.0 5.7 0.9 48.7 CLI 3.8 1.6 1.2 5.0 4.4 8.6 12.9 2.0 1.9 0.8 42.3 Market total 747.2 228.8 202.7 975.2 790.0 1,778.0 1,241.5 305.6 962.3 151.1 7,382.4 a/ Value added defined here does not include taxes. b/ Sector codes are in Table 1, oblasts in the markets are listed in Table 2. Source: Regions of Russia, Roskomstat, and authors' calculations. 39 Table 4. Value-Added by Sector as a percent of the Value-Added of the Regional Market St. North- Sector Central Far East North Siberia South Urals Moscow Petersb. Tumen west MAR 0.6 0.6 0.7 0.7 0.5 0.8 0.3 0.6 0.7 0.6 AGR 14.8 7.6 3.7 8.7 15.8 8.7 1.2 3.9 0.9 10.0 AIR 0.5 0.6 0.5 0.5 0.6 0.6 1.2 0.5 0.3 0.4 CHM 1.9 0.1 0.8 1.1 1.2 2.0 0.6 0.7 0.0 2.8 CNM 1.4 0.5 0.4 0.5 0.8 0.7 0.7 0.8 0.1 0.4 COL 0.0 2.3 1.6 3.3 0.2 0.1 CON 10.2 3.1 3.0 5.6 13.3 8.5 11.2 9.7 2.5 7.6 CRU 1.9 8.3 1.0 4.8 5.5 29.4 0.7 ELE 3.6 3.4 3.5 3.6 2.9 3.5 3.5 3.5 2.0 3.9 FIN 5.8 7.2 7.0 6.2 5.6 6.0 9.3 6.8 4.9 5.9 FME 2.5 0.2 0.8 0.9 0.5 1.9 0.2 0.4 7.5 FOO 3.3 4.0 1.8 1.8 3.0 1.6 2.7 5.8 0.1 3.1 GAS 0.1 0.2 0.0 0.2 0.2 5.4 0.0 HEA 5.7 7.6 7.2 6.0 5.7 5.7 10.2 7.1 4.2 5.9 HOU 3.0 3.8 3.3 3.0 3.1 2.9 5.5 3.7 1.4 3.0 MWO 5.2 4.9 1.3 2.0 2.3 5.7 3.7 6.2 0.3 2.4 NFM 0.3 3.5 4.6 11.6 0.6 2.6 0.6 1.4 0.1 OIL 1.6 2.1 0.8 1.8 1.3 2.2 0.4 2.4 0.4 OTH 1.0 0.9 1.1 0.9 0.6 1.0 0.5 1.1 0.8 1.2 OTI 1.8 0.2 0.3 0.3 0.5 0.5 0.8 0.8 0.0 0.6 PIP 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.3 0.1 0.2 0.5 0.1 PST 0.4 0.4 0.4 0.4 0.4 0.4 0.6 0.4 0.3 0.4 RLW 3.1 3.0 3.1 3.1 2.6 3.0 2.8 3.1 1.7 4.1 SCI 1.2 1.4 1.2 1.1 1.0 1.3 1.3 1.4 1.0 1.0 TMS 1.0 1.2 1.1 1.0 1.0 1.1 1.7 1.2 0.8 1.0 TPP 0.9 1.9 7.5 1.3 0.3 0.7 0.5 2.4 0.1 2.8 TRD 27.5 34.2 33.0 30.8 28.3 30.1 36.8 33.3 40.2 31.9 TRK 1.4 1.5 1.5 1.4 1.4 1.4 1.9 1.5 1.3 1.5 TRO 0.6 0.7 0.7 0.6 0.6 0.6 0.9 0.7 0.6 0.6 CLI 0.5 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.6 0.5 1.0 0.7 0.2 0.5 Total 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 See Table 1 for sector codes. Source: Regions of Russia, Roskomstat. 40 Table 5. Share of Sector Value-Added by Regional Market of Russia (in percent) St. North- Sector Good Central Far East North Siberia South Urals Moscow Petersb. Tumen west Total MAR 10.0 2.8 2.9 15.2 8.8 31.3 8.5 3.7 14.7 2.0 100.0 AGR 20.0 3.2 1.3 15.4 22.7 28.2 2.8 2.1 1.5 2.7 100.0 AIR 7.9 2.8 2.1 11.6 10.0 22.1 32.9 3.6 5.5 1.4 100.0 CHM 16.3 0.4 1.8 12.4 10.9 41.6 9.1 2.4 0.1 4.9 100.0 CNM 21.3 2.3 1.5 9.6 13.9 25.2 18.2 4.9 1.6 1.4 100.0 COL 0.3 11.8 7.3 74.2 3.8 2.7 100.0 CON 12.6 1.2 1.0 9.0 17.4 25.1 22.9 4.9 4.0 1.9 100.0 CRU 1.0 3.7 2.2 8.4 21.7 62.8 0.2 100.0 ELE 11.1 3.2 2.9 14.4 9.5 26.2 17.9 4.4 7.9 2.4 100.0 FIN 9.1 3.4 3.0 12.7 9.2 22.3 24.2 4.4 9.8 1.9 100.0 FME 23.0 0.6 1.9 10.9 4.8 40.9 2.8 1.4 13.7 100.0 FOO 15.2 5.6 2.2 10.6 14.6 17.1 20.6 10.8 0.3 2.8 100.0 GAS 0.3 0.7 0.8 2.5 4.8 90.8 0.0 100.0 HEA 8.9 3.7 3.1 12.3 9.4 21.1 26.5 4.6 8.5 1.9 100.0 HOU 9.2 3.7 2.8 12.1 10.3 21.2 28.4 4.7 5.7 1.9 100.0 MWO 14.7 4.3 1.0 7.4 6.8 38.8 17.3 7.2 1.1 1.4 100.0 NFM 1.3 4.1 4.7 57.9 2.5 23.6 3.6 2.2 0.1 100.0 OIL 12.1 4.7 1.5 17.3 10.0 38.9 4.4 7.2 3.9 100.0 OTH 12.3 3.2 3.6 14.0 7.8 29.3 10.0 5.2 11.7 3.0 100.0 OTI 30.8 1.3 1.6 5.7 9.1 20.9 22.5 5.8 0.2 2.1 100.0 PIP 7.8 2.7 2.5 10.5 8.9 28.9 6.4 3.6 27.7 1.0 100.0 PST 9.3 3.5 2.8 12.2 10.1 22.0 23.9 4.5 9.9 1.9 100.0 RLW 11.3 3.3 3.0 14.6 9.9 25.9 16.6 4.5 7.8 3.0 100.0 SCI 10.1 3.6 2.8 11.9 8.9 26.0 18.9 4.7 11.3 1.7 100.0 TMS 9.1 3.3 2.7 12.1 9.9 22.4 25.3 4.3 8.9 1.8 100.0 TPP 9.3 5.9 20.5 17.8 3.5 17.6 9.2 9.8 0.8 5.7 100.0 TRD 8.5 3.3 2.8 12.5 9.3 22.3 19.0 4.2 16.1 2.0 100.0 TRK 9.3 3.2 2.8 12.5 10.4 22.6 21.1 4.3 11.8 2.0 100.0 TRO 9.2 3.1 2.7 11.7 10.5 23.0 21.9 4.2 11.8 1.9 100.0 CLI 9.0 3.7 2.8 11.7 10.5 20.4 30.6 4.7 4.6 1.9 100.0 Total 329.2 99.4 96.2 453.3 284.4 734.1 465.5 128.4 340.9 68.7 3000.0 Source: Regions of Russia and authors calculations. 41 Table 6: Exports by Product and by Regional Market (in billions of 2001 rubles) St. North- Good Central Far East North Siberia South Urals Moscow Petersb. Tumen west MAR 4.9 1.7 1.7 7.1 4.5 13.7 4.3 2.2 6.9 1.2 AGR 3.1 0.5 0.2 2.4 3.5 4.4 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.4 AIR 5.6 2.4 1.8 7.6 6.8 13.2 18.9 3.0 4.4 1.2 CHM 27.5 0.5 2.0 33.2 18.2 92.0 13.7 5.0 0.3 15.2 CNM 1.8 0.2 0.1 1.7 1.2 3.4 1.6 0.6 0.2 0.2 COL 0.1 4.2 2.6 26.4 1.3 0.9 CON 4.0 0.4 0.3 2.9 5.6 8.0 7.3 1.6 1.3 0.6 CRU 7.1 27.0 15.8 60.3 156.1 452.8 1.6 ELE 1.1 0.3 0.3 1.4 1.0 2.6 1.8 0.4 0.8 0.2 FIN 0.7 0.3 0.2 0.9 0.7 1.6 1.8 0.3 0.7 0.1 FME 50.5 1.1 3.7 22.4 11.1 83.8 7.1 4.8 28.3 FOO 8.7 9.7 2.5 12.6 23.1 10.1 27.0 9.2 0.1 3.6 GAS 1.4 3.1 3.6 11.5 21.8 410.7 0.0 HEA 0.3 0.1 0.1 0.4 0.3 0.6 0.8 0.1 0.2 0.1 HOU 0.3 0.1 0.1 0.4 0.3 0.6 0.8 0.1 0.2 0.1 MWO 22.8 14.2 1.9 43.0 23.3 97.0 95.5 30.4 1.9 5.0 NFM 4.6 15.1 18.4 203.1 11.1 101.6 17.2 11.3 0.6 OIL 35.5 13.7 4.5 50.9 29.5 114.4 12.8 21.1 11.5 OTH 1.7 0.4 0.5 1.9 1.1 4.0 1.4 0.7 1.6 0.4 OTI 7.2 0.3 0.4 1.3 2.1 4.9 5.3 1.4 0.0 0.5 PST 0.3 0.1 0.1 0.5 0.4 0.8 0.9 0.2 0.4 0.1 RLW 0.9 0.3 0.2 1.1 0.8 2.0 1.3 0.3 0.6 0.2 SCI 0.6 0.2 0.2 0.7 0.5 1.6 1.1 0.3 0.7 0.1 TMS 0.9 0.3 0.3 1.2 1.0 2.1 2.4 0.4 0.9 0.2 TPP 3.1 17.1 29.2 35.1 1.7 13.3 2.1 12.7 0.4 8.1 TRD 2.0 0.8 0.7 3.0 2.2 5.3 4.5 1.0 3.9 0.5 TRK 0.4 0.1 0.1 0.5 0.4 0.9 0.9 0.2 0.5 0.1 TRO 0.5 0.2 0.2 0.7 0.6 1.3 1.2 0.2 0.7 0.1 CLI 2.6 1.1 0.8 3.4 3.1 6.0 9.0 1.4 1.3 0.5 See Tables 1 and 2 for sector and region definitions. Source: Roskomstat unpublished surveys and authors' calculations. 42 Table 7. Sector Exports as a Percent of Total Exports of the Regional Market St. North- Good Central Far East North Siberia South Urals Moscow Petersb. Tumen west MAR 3 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 1 2 AGR 2 1 0 0 2 1 0 0 0 1 AIR 3 3 2 2 3 2 8 3 0 2 CHM 14 1 2 7 8 12 6 5 0 22 CNM 1 0 0 0 1 0 1 1 0 0 COL 0 4 3 5 1 0 CON 2 0 0 1 2 1 3 1 0 1 CRU 8 26 3 27 20 50 2 ELE 1 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 FIN 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 FME 26 1 4 5 5 11 3 4 41 FOO 5 10 2 3 10 1 11 8 0 5 GAS 2 3 1 5 3 45 0 HEA 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 HOU 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 MWO 12 15 2 9 10 13 40 28 0 7 NFM 2 16 18 42 5 13 7 10 1 OIL 19 15 4 10 13 15 5 19 1 OTH 1 0 0 0 0 1 1 1 0 1 OTI 4 0 0 0 1 1 2 1 0 1 PST 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 RLW 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 SCI 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 TMS 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 TPP 2 18 28 7 1 2 1 12 0 12 TRD 1 1 1 1 1 1 2 1 0 1 TRK 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 TRO 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 CLI 1 1 1 1 1 1 4 1 0 1 Total 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 See Tables 1 and 2 for sector and region definitions. Source: Roskomstat unpublished surveys and authors' calculations. 43 Table 8. Sector Export Intensities by Regional Market: Exports of the Sector as a Percent of Production of the Sector (in percent) St. North- Good Central Far East North Siberia South Urals Moscow Petersb. Tumen west MAR 53 57 57 51 53 50 54 57 51 57 AGR 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 AIR 46 48 48 44 45 43 43 48 47 48 CHM 27 21 17 48 27 37 24 35 40 57 CNM 3 3 3 6 3 5 3 4 4 7 COL 23 23 23 23 23 23 CON 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 CRU 56 56 56 56 56 56 56 ELE 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 FIN 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 FME 40 35 34 37 43 37 48 75 37 FOO 4 12 8 8 11 4 9 6 3 9 GAS 27 27 27 27 27 27 27 HEA 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 HOU 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 MWO 11 25 14 48 25 18 45 32 12 27 NFM 44 45 48 43 58 55 62 67 79 OIL 32 32 32 32 32 32 32 32 32 OTH 12 12 12 12 12 12 12 12 12 12 OTI 15 15 15 15 15 15 15 15 15 15 PST 9 9 9 9 9 9 9 9 9 9 RLW 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 SCI 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 TMS 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 TPP 7 77 33 48 11 17 5 30 12 33 TRD 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 TRK 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 TRO 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 CLI 11 11 11 11 11 11 11 11 11 11 Total 364 534 474 545 488 477 397 459 357 510 See Tables 1 and 2 for sector and region definitions. Source: Roskomstat unpublished surveys and authors' calculations. 44 Table 9: Imports by Product and by Regional Market (in x 2001 rubles) St. North- Good Central Far East North Siberia South Urals Moscow Petersb. Tumen west AGR 4.6 1.4 0.8 4.3 5.0 7.6 7.9 2.0 1.3 0.8 AIR 0.3 0.1 0.1 0.4 0.3 0.6 0.9 0.1 0.2 0.1 CHM 12.5 4.0 2.8 18.8 9.7 25.5 47.9 8.9 4.9 3.6 CNM 2.7 0.5 0.4 3.3 2.8 4.6 11.6 2.2 0.8 0.7 COL 0.6 0.2 0.2 1.3 0.4 1.2 0.6 0.2 0.2 0.2 CON 8.0 4.0 3.4 10.2 10.0 20.4 15.3 4.7 16.4 1.7 CRU 1.5 0.6 0.2 2.2 1.4 5.1 0.6 0.9 1.1 0.0 ELE 0.3 0.1 0.1 0.4 0.3 0.8 0.5 0.1 0.2 0.1 FIN 1.6 0.6 0.5 2.2 1.6 3.7 4.2 0.8 1.7 0.3 FME 9.5 1.2 0.8 3.1 7.8 11.7 13.4 4.3 2.9 2.8 FOO 19.1 7.2 3.0 14.4 17.9 25.3 79.1 36.2 4.2 7.7 GAS 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.1 0.3 0.2 0.0 0.2 0.0 HEA 0.9 0.4 0.3 1.3 1.0 2.3 2.8 0.5 0.9 0.2 HOU 3.5 1.4 1.1 4.6 3.9 8.0 10.7 1.8 2.2 0.7 MWO 35.8 14.3 8.2 18.0 31.1 60.3 198.5 49.6 20.1 10.9 NFM 3.9 2.1 1.5 13.2 4.7 10.9 9.2 3.5 2.2 1.2 OIL 4.1 1.1 1.0 4.5 4.0 9.0 6.4 1.6 3.3 0.8 OTH 1.7 0.6 0.5 2.2 1.7 4.1 3.7 0.8 2.0 0.4 OTI 1.2 0.3 0.2 1.1 1.1 2.1 1.5 0.4 0.6 0.2 PST 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.1 0.2 0.2 0.0 0.1 0.0 RLW 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.2 0.1 0.3 0.3 0.1 0.2 0.0 SCI 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 TMS 0.8 0.3 0.2 1.0 0.8 1.8 2.0 0.4 0.7 0.2 TPP 2.7 0.6 1.1 0.7 3.6 2.0 22.1 7.3 0.1 2.8 TRD 1.0 0.4 0.3 1.5 1.1 2.6 2.4 0.5 1.5 0.2 TRK 0.4 0.1 0.1 0.5 0.4 0.9 0.9 0.2 0.5 0.1 TRO 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.2 0.2 0.3 0.3 0.1 0.2 0.0 CLI 25 10 8 32 29 56 84 13 13 5 Total 142 52 35 142 140 268 528 140 81 41 See Tables 1 and 2 for sector and region definitions. Source: Roskomstat unpublished surveys and authors' calculations. 45 Table 10. Sector Imports as a Percent of Total Imports of the Regional Market St. North- Good Central Far East North Siberia South Urals Moscow Petersb. Tumen west AGR 3 3 2 3 4 3 1 1 2 2 AIR 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 CHM 9 8 8 13 7 10 9 6 6 9 CNM 2 1 1 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 COL 0 0 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 1 CON 6 8 10 7 7 8 3 3 20 4 CRU 1 1 1 2 1 2 0 1 1 0 ELE 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 FIN 1 1 2 2 1 1 1 1 2 1 FME 7 2 2 2 6 4 3 3 4 7 FOO 13 14 9 10 13 9 15 26 5 19 GAS 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 HEA 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 1 0 HOU 2 3 3 3 3 3 2 1 3 2 MWO 25 28 23 13 22 23 38 35 25 27 NFM 3 4 4 9 3 4 2 2 3 3 OIL 3 2 3 3 3 3 1 1 4 2 OTH 1 1 1 2 1 2 1 1 2 1 OTI 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 0 1 0 PST 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 RLW 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 SCI 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 TMS 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 0 1 0 TPP 2 1 3 1 3 1 4 5 0 7 TRD 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 0 2 1 TRK 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 TRO 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 CLI 17 20 22 23 21 21 16 9 15 13 Total 142 52 35 142 140 268 528 140 81 41 See Tables 1 and 2 for sector and region definitions. Source: Roskomstat unpublished surveys and authors' calculations. 46 Table 11. Sector Import Intensities by Regional Market: Regional Imports of the Sector as a Percent of Regional Consumption of the Product St. North- Good Central Far East North Siberia South Urals Moscow Petersb. Tumen west AGR 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 AIR 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 CHM 35 36 30 47 29 33 74 58 19 57 CNM 13 16 13 18 10 11 29 25 8 20 COL 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 CON 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 CRU 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 ELE 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 FIN 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 FME 32 17 19 14 36 17 38 37 25 75 FOO 25 23 13 15 20 15 31 94 10 50 GAS 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 HEA 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 HOU 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 MWO 36 37 24 15 27 26 98 100 16 53 NFM 16 40 41 96 35 23 39 41 23 25 OIL 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 OTH 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 OTI 7 6 6 6 6 6 7 7 6 6 PST 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 RLW 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 SCI 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 TMS 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 TPP 13 11 28 4 19 5 60 83 1 78 TRD 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 TRK 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 TRO 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 CLI 73 73 73 73 73 73 73 73 73 73 Total 142 52 35 142 140 268 528 140 81 41 See Tables 1 and 2 for sector and region definitions. Source: Roskomstat unpublished surveys and authors' calculations. 47 Table 12a. Tariff Rates, Export Tax Rates, Estimated Ad Valorem Equivalence of Barriers to FDI in Services Sectors and Estimated Improved Market Access (ad-valorem in %) -- by sector Estimated Equivalent % barriers Tariff rates change in to FDI 2011-pre WTO 2020-final Export tax world market Base Post-WTO accession commitments rates price Year Accession Electric industry 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 Oil extraction 1.7 1 7.9 0.0 Oil processing 5.1 4.9 4.6 0.0 Gas 4.7 5 18.8 0.0 Coalmining 4.4 4.4 0.0 0.0 Ferrous metallurgy 8.6 5.9 0.4 1.5 Non-ferrous metallurgy 10 7.4 5.3 1.5 Chemical & oil-chemical industry 7.4 5.2 1.6 1.5 Mechanical engineering & metal-working 8.9 5.7 0.0 0.0 Timber & woodworking & pulp & paper industry 14.3 8.2 6.9 0.0 Construction materials industry 12.7 9.9 1.6 0.0 Textiles and Apparel 12.3 8.2 4.1 0.5 Food industry 18.2 13.6 3.1 0.5 Other industries 10.4 7.4 0.0 0.5 Agriculture & forestry 7.7 5.7 0.6 0.0 Other goods-producing sectors 14.2 10.7 0.0 0.5 Telecommunications 33.0 0.0 Science & science servicing (market) 33.0 0.0 Financial services 36.0 0.0 Railway transportation 33.0 0.0 Truck transportation 33.0 0.0 Pipelines transportation 33.0 0.0 Maritime transportation 95.0 80.0 Air transportation 90.0 75.0 Other transportation 33.0 0.0 Source: Shepotylo and Tarr (2014) for tariff rates; Kimura et al. (2004a,b,c) for barriers to FDI; Roskomstat for export tax rates; authors' estimates for change in world market prices. 48 Table 12b. Shares of Business Services Sectors in the Regions of Russia Captured by Multinational Firms (ad-valorem in %) -- by sector Other Maritime Rail Truck Pipeline Air Transp. Telecom Science Financial Moscow 0.47 0.02 0.03 0.06 0.11 0.02 0.08 0.07 0.13 St. Petersburg 0.70 0.06 0.10 0.06 0.50 0.08 0.30 0.20 0.18 Tumen 0.29 0.04 0.05 0.01 0.46 0.04 0.20 0.12 0.08 Northwest 0.70 0.06 0.10 0.06 0.50 0.08 0.30 0.20 0.20 North 0.70 0.06 0.10 0.06 0.50 0.08 0.30 0.20 0.20 Central 0.41 0.03 0.07 0.05 0.35 0.05 0.20 0.09 0.09 South 0.46 0.04 0.06 0.05 0.30 0.05 0.19 0.10 0.09 Urals 0.15 0.02 0.03 0.02 0.16 0.03 0.09 0.07 0.04 Siberia 0.28 0.02 0.05 0.03 0.26 0.04 0.15 0.09 0.07 Far East 0.70 0.06 0.10 0.06 0.50 0.08 0.30 0.20 0.20 National average 0.35 0.03 0.05 0.03 0.25 0.04 0.15 0.10 0.10 49 Table 12c. Base-Year Pollution Intensities by Sector for non-CO2 Pollutants (in grams per ruble) Volatile Sulphur Hydro- Carbon Nitrogen Particulate Organic sector Dioxide carbons Monoxide Oxide Matter Components NFM 4.3 0.0 1.4 0.2 0.5 0.0 ELE 2.8 0.0 0.4 1.8 2.3 0.0 FME 1.9 0.0 1.1 0.1 0.3 0.0 industry average 0.3 0.2 0.3 0.1 0.2 0.1 OIL 0.3 0.1 0.2 0.1 0.1 0.3 CRU 0.2 1.4 3.8 0.2 0.7 1.2 CHM 0.2 0.1 0.5 0.2 0.3 0.2 CNM 0.1 0.0 0.6 0.3 1.0 0.0 CLI 0.1 0.0 0.2 0.1 0.2 0.0 HOU 0.1 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 COL 0.1 3.7 0.1 0.1 0.3 0.0 MAR 0.1 1.5 0.3 0.2 0.2 0.1 RLW 0.1 1.3 0.3 0.1 0.2 0.1 TRK 0.1 1.2 0.3 0.1 0.2 0.1 AIR 0.1 1.1 0.2 0.1 0.2 0.1 TRO 0.1 1.2 0.3 0.1 0.2 0.1 PIP 0.1 1.5 0.3 0.2 0.2 0.1 GAS 0.0 0.2 0.3 0.0 0.0 0.1 FOO 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.1 0.0 MWO 0.0 0.0 0.2 0.1 0.2 0.0 TPP 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.1 0.0 AGR 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.1 0.0 OTH 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 OTI 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 Source: Authors’ calculations based on the SUST_RUS database. See the appendix for details. 50 Table 13. Impact of WTO Accession on Regional Markets, including decomposition of CO2 emissions (Results are Percentage Change from Base Year) Overall St. North- Far average Moscow Peters. Tumen west North Central South Urals Siberia East Aggregate welfare Welfare (EV as % of consumption) 8.6 7.7 11.5 13.7 12.0 10.7 8.8 9.2 7.1 8.3 10.7 Welfare (EV as % of GDP) 4.0 4.2 5.2 2.9 5.6 4.4 4.1 4.4 3.2 3.9 4.8 Carbon Dioxide Emissions and Decomposition CO2 price (ruble per ton of CO2) 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 CO2 emissions, decomposed into: 4.3 2.4 8.9 3.7 8.2 5.2 6.1 4.4 3.3 4.6 4.9 Output effect (% of CO2) 4.9 4.9 7.0 5.1 7.4 6.5 5.0 5.4 3.7 4.8 6.7 Composition effect (% of CO2) 1.0 -0.9 4.4 0.1 2.7 0.4 2.6 0.7 1.0 1.3 0.4 Technique effect (% of CO2) -1.6 -1.5 -2.7 -1.4 -2.0 -1.6 -1.5 -1.6 -1.3 -1.5 -2.1 Non-Carbon Dioxide Emissions Sulphur Dioxide 6.2 4.5 28.8 3.5 10.1 7.7 11.2 10.6 9.2 4.1 4.7 Nitrogen Oxide 2.8 1.7 4.6 2.8 6.8 3.7 3.0 3.6 2.4 2.8 2.9 Hydrocarbons 1.7 -2.0 4.5 1.9 4.8 4.1 2.6 1.8 -0.1 2.7 8.6 Particulate Matter 3.0 1.5 5.9 2.8 5.0 4.0 2.6 2.9 3.1 2.9 2.5 Volatile Organic Components 2.7 3.8 1.8 2.8 13.3 2.9 6.2 3.5 1.8 3.0 4.5 Carbon Monoxide 4.5 9.9 13.6 2.7 9.8 4.8 17.0 5.8 4.4 3.4 3.5 Aggregate trade Regional terms of trade (% change) 2.9 16.3 17.9 16.2 17.8 16.9 16.3 15.8 15.2 15.1 17.0 Regional exports (% change) 3.0 3.3 3.8 2.9 3.6 3.7 3.1 2.7 2.6 2.8 3.9 Real exchange rate (% change) 1.8 1.9 2.7 2.2 2.2 2.2 2.1 2.1 1.2 1.4 2.5 International exports (% change) 8.1 11.1 17.6 2.6 17.9 7.5 19.5 8.6 8.7 7.4 9.5 Return to primary factors (% change) Unskilled labor 3.7 3.9 6.0 3.5 5.6 5.0 3.7 4.5 2.3 3.6 5.6 Skilled labor 3.7 2.5 6.2 4.8 6.1 5.5 4.2 4.3 2.2 3.8 6.2 National capital 3.8 3.9 4.6 4.1 4.2 4.2 4.0 4.0 3.1 3.3 4.4 Regional mobile capital 5.8 6.0 9.5 4.3 9.5 7.1 6.5 6.0 4.9 5.5 7.5 Crude oil resources 4.4 5.1 3.7 4.9 4.6 2.5 2.7 5.5 Natural gas resources 7.0 8.1 -10.1 -3.3 -2.0 -5.2 -6.1 -3.6 Coal resources 9.7 12.4 10.9 11.2 8.8 9.0 12.5 Specific capital in domestic firms -29.9 -22.5 -47.7 -20.8 -24.5 -16.9 -24.1 -16.3 -19.3 -26.3 Specific capital in multinational firms 60.2 47.7 215.9 79.1 140.9 114.3 125.9 138.8 159.5 113.0 Factor adjustments Unskilled labor (% changing sectors) 2.0 1.9 3.1 1.9 3.8 2.0 2.1 1.5 2.0 1.9 2.3 Skilled labor (% changing sector) 2.6 2.6 3.9 2.7 4.1 2.9 2.7 2.1 2.3 2.5 3.3 Source: Authors' estimates 51 Table 14. Impact of WTO Accession on Output by Sector and Regional Market. (Results are Percentage Change from Base Year) Good Central Siberia South North Urals Far East Moscow St. Pete. Tumen Northwest FME 26.6 13.1 37.4 24.7 13.7 23.3 38.5 293.0 12.0 CHM 8.6 20.9 11.2 3.3 12.4 5.2 6.2 8.8 47.6 25.5 TMS 13.7 8.6 13.2 20.3 0.4 21.5 -0.7 21.3 10.3 21.9 TRK 10.1 6.8 8.8 11.5 4.3 13.6 5.1 14.5 5.4 15.2 COL 7.8 6.4 8.0 8.8 6.7 8.6 TRD 6.7 4.7 4.9 5.3 4.2 6.1 5.0 7.8 3.0 9.3 NFM 5.8 3.6 20.2 8.1 14.5 4.6 22.6 -6.6 -22.3 PST 3.9 3.1 4.0 4.5 2.4 4.9 2.8 4.2 4.2 4.7 OIL 4.9 0.6 5.4 5.1 0.4 6.2 1.8 1.3 8.7 ELE 3.3 3.0 3.5 3.4 2.7 3.2 2.0 4.1 3.6 5.7 HOU 2.1 2.2 2.8 3.1 1.5 3.1 2.2 2.6 3.2 2.9 RLW 3.7 0.8 1.9 1.9 1.4 2.1 0.4 6.1 0.5 4.3 CRU 1.5 2.5 2.8 1.5 3.0 2.7 1.9 SCI 1.7 2.0 0.5 1.8 0.1 4.5 1.1 7.5 -4.3 6.8 HEA 1.4 1.3 1.7 1.5 1.2 1.7 1.5 1.7 1.2 1.7 CLI 1.0 -0.4 1.1 1.2 0.3 1.2 0.0 -1.9 6.0 -2.9 MWO -4.1 0.9 1.3 -0.3 -4.3 2.3 8.4 2.1 2.8 -5.4 CON 0.4 -0.9 0.8 -0.2 0.3 -0.4 1.8 -1.8 3.4 -3.6 OTI -0.9 -2.6 0.1 -0.1 -1.2 -1.4 2.6 0.5 2.6 -2.0 AIR -0.8 -3.7 -0.9 2.8 -3.1 2.7 -1.6 -0.3 2.9 -0.6 TPP -6.2 -5.0 -9.4 0.6 -1.9 17.1 -11.3 -7.2 16.3 -9.2 AGR -1.4 -1.1 -0.2 -1.7 0.5 -2.5 -0.8 -6.7 6.4 -8.6 GAS -3.0 -1.3 -1.8 -2.5 -2.0 2.9 -5.0 PIP -1.3 -2.8 -2.1 -3.3 -1.9 -2.3 -3.7 -3.3 0.1 0.5 CNM -2.5 -4.8 -1.2 -1.3 -2.7 -1.9 -4.5 -5.9 6.2 -7.8 OTH -2.0 -6.5 -3.0 -4.9 -1.2 -6.5 0.1 -8.7 3.7 -13.0 FIN -5.5 -6.1 -5.4 -5.8 -6.3 -5.3 -5.6 -4.9 -7.5 -4.1 TRO -4.3 -9.5 -6.3 -1.3 -15.1 0.6 -18.1 1.0 -13.2 1.6 FOO -8.4 -6.8 -6.1 -3.8 -6.4 -7.1 -11.0 -8.4 4.5 -11.6 MAR -6.4 -11.4 -8.0 -4.9 -6.9 -4.3 -9.2 -5.8 -6.1 -7.6 See table 1 for sector codes. Source: Author's estimates. 52 Table 15: Impact of “Cap and Trade” Market Based Emission Control System to Reduce Carbon Emissions by 20 Percent on Regional Markets, with decomposition of carbon emission effects. (Results are Percentage Change from Base Year.) Overall St. North- Far average Moscow Peters. Tumen west North Central South Urals Siberia East Aggregate welfare Welfare (EV as % of consumption) -1.1 -1.8 -1.4 -0.2 0.5 -1.2 -0.1 -1.3 -0.5 -0.6 -1.7 Welfare (EV as % of GDP) -0.5 -1.0 -0.6 0.0 0.3 -0.5 -0.1 -0.6 -0.2 -0.3 -0.8 Carbon Dioxide Emissions and Decomposition CO2 price (ruble per ton of CO2) 96.0 96.0 96.0 96.0 96.0 96.0 96.0 96.0 96.0 96.0 CO2 emissions, decomposed into: -20.0 -18.3 -18.9 -21.9 -21.7 -18.9 -20.3 -18.3 -20.5 -20.7 -19.1 Output effect (% of CO2) -1.0 -1.0 -0.9 -2.3 -1.0 -1.0 -0.7 -1.0 -0.9 -0.8 -1.0 Composition effect (% of CO2) -3.1 0.1 -0.8 -9.9 -4.3 -2.5 -2.4 -1.2 -2.5 -4.7 -2.3 Technique effect (% of CO2) -16.3 -17.5 -17.5 -10.5 -17.3 -15.8 -17.6 -16.3 -17.6 -16.0 -16.2 Non-Carbon Dioxide Emissions Sulphur Dioxide -0.1 -2.7 -0.6 -5.2 -12.9 -0.2 -9.1 -5.3 -3.6 2.1 0.7 Nitrogen Oxide -3.3 -3.9 -2.9 -3.6 -5.0 -3.1 -3.9 -4.1 -3.3 -2.3 -3.0 Hydrocarbons -4.2 -2.4 -2.4 -2.1 -3.2 -5.8 -3.5 -2.8 -2.1 -10.6 -19.1 Particulate Matter -2.9 -4.0 -3.6 -2.7 -4.4 -2.7 -3.8 -4.1 -3.5 -1.6 -2.2 Volatile Organic Components -1.5 -3.8 -1.5 -1.6 -0.4 -1.2 1.2 -1.4 -1.4 -2.9 -0.6 Carbon Monoxide -1.7 -1.0 -0.9 -1.8 -12.8 -0.6 -13.0 -2.4 -2.3 1.1 -0.1 Aggregate trade Regional terms of trade (% change) -0.1 1.5 1.3 0.5 0.8 1.4 1.3 1.3 1.2 1.7 1.5 Regional exports (% change) -1.2 -1.5 -1.3 -1.8 -1.0 -1.4 -0.6 -0.9 -0.8 -1.8 -1.5 Real exchange rate (% change) 0.4 0.4 0.3 -0.3 0.9 0.3 0.8 0.4 0.5 0.3 0.2 International exports (% change) 0.4 3.6 0.3 1.1 -3.9 1.2 -5.5 1.3 0.2 -0.1 2.4 Return to primary factors (% change) Unskilled labor -1.7 -1.4 -1.6 -2.1 -0.7 -1.9 -1.3 -1.8 -1.9 -2.1 -1.9 Skilled labor -2.6 -1.4 -1.6 -4.9 -2.1 -3.2 -1.9 -2.2 -2.1 -4.4 -3.4 National capital -1.7 -1.7 -1.9 -2.4 -1.3 -1.9 -1.4 -1.8 -1.6 -1.9 -2.0 Regional mobile capital -1.8 -2.1 -2.0 -0.2 -2.9 -1.6 -2.4 -1.8 -1.9 -1.5 -1.5 Crude oil resources -0.6 -1.3 1.4 0.1 0.5 0.7 0.1 -0.1 Natural gas resources -32.9 -34.6 -2.2 -19.2 -16.2 -13.6 -19.5 -20.7 Coal resources -13.6 -12.9 -11.0 -12.1 -13.4 -13.8 -13.3 Specific capital in domestic firms -0.4 -0.6 -1.3 -1.4 -1.2 -0.9 -1.2 -1.8 -0.3 -0.9 Specific capital in multinational firms 0.1 0.9 3.8 0.7 1.8 2.4 2.6 3.9 3.7 2.1 Factor adjustments Unskilled labor (% changing sectors) 0.9 0.6 0.6 1.2 2.0 0.8 1.0 0.5 0.9 1.3 1.0 Skilled labor (% changing sector) 1.5 0.6 0.8 2.1 2.5 1.8 1.3 0.7 1.2 3.3 2.2 Source: Authors' estimates 53 Table 15a. Impact of 20 Percent CO2 Reduction through Market Based Cap and Trade on Output by Sector and Regional Market. (Results are Percentage Change from Base Year) Good Central Siberia South North Urals Far East Moscow St. Pete. Tumen Northwest NFM 18.3 8.1 15.2 9.2 19.3 6.9 26.4 25.6 202.6 MAR 4.5 2.4 3.0 2.1 3.2 3.5 4.3 2.8 -2.7 3.7 OTH 5.0 3.0 1.9 1.1 3.0 1.4 0.7 0.0 -4.4 6.4 TPP 0.4 1.6 -1.6 -0.7 -0.4 14.3 -1.7 0.3 -4.9 10.6 FOO 3.3 1.0 2.1 0.3 1.5 1.2 2.8 1.1 -3.3 6.0 OIL 5.3 0.5 1.2 0.9 2.6 0.3 1.2 0.3 -4.9 PST 1.0 0.6 0.7 0.6 0.9 0.4 0.6 0.4 0.2 1.6 TMS 0.6 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.5 0.0 0.2 0.0 0.1 1.0 CLI 1.9 0.1 0.0 -0.4 1.1 -0.9 0.3 0.0 -3.6 3.2 AGR 3.0 -0.7 0.2 -1.5 1.0 -1.4 0.5 -0.3 -6.3 4.6 HEA 0.0 -0.1 -0.4 -0.2 -0.1 -0.4 -0.6 -0.3 -0.1 0.1 FIN -0.3 -0.2 -0.3 -0.2 -0.3 -0.3 -0.3 -0.3 -0.6 -0.5 CON 0.9 -0.3 -0.6 -1.0 -0.6 -1.1 -0.2 -0.6 -4.1 2.6 CRU -0.6 -0.5 -0.6 -0.5 -0.7 -1.3 -0.1 SCI -1.2 -1.0 -1.1 -0.9 -1.5 -1.7 -0.3 -0.8 -2.3 -0.5 TRD -2.9 -1.4 -0.8 -0.7 -1.2 -0.7 -1.5 -1.6 0.9 -3.1 TRO -1.5 -2.3 -1.6 -1.7 -1.7 -1.6 -1.7 -1.8 -1.9 -1.7 OTI 0.3 -2.7 -1.1 -2.9 -0.7 -2.9 -0.2 -1.3 -7.3 0.3 MWO -0.7 -5.7 -1.9 -3.6 -2.8 -5.4 2.8 -1.2 -7.1 5.7 TRK -3.3 -2.8 -2.5 -2.3 -2.8 -2.0 -3.1 -2.9 -0.9 -3.0 HOU -2.1 -2.9 -3.1 -3.1 -2.6 -3.5 -3.4 -2.9 -2.7 -1.7 RLW -3.9 -4.8 -2.3 -3.1 -3.9 -2.1 -1.3 -2.1 -2.1 -5.4 AIR -1.2 -2.6 -3.4 -4.7 -1.7 -5.4 -3.2 -5.0 -6.8 -0.4 ELE -4.0 -3.8 -4.1 -3.8 -4.1 -3.8 -3.8 -3.4 -5.7 -4.5 CNM -2.3 -6.3 -3.5 -5.4 -3.7 -6.0 -5.9 -5.8 -7.5 -1.7 PIP -9.3 -8.7 -6.8 -7.5 -6.0 -7.0 -17.9 -7.9 -3.9 -23.8 CHM -6.7 -18.1 -10.1 -10.5 -11.0 -11.3 -9.8 -12.6 -23.0 -0.6 GAS -13.1 -11.7 -13.0 -10.5 -13.7 -20.7 -5.7 COL -17.7 -19.3 -18.4 -18.8 -19.5 -19.1 FME -21.1 -22.5 -26.2 -22.7 -21.6 -21.7 -28.4 -54.2 -18.0 See table 1 for sector codes. Source: Authors' estimates. 54 Table 16: Impact on the Regions of Russia of Emission Intensity Standards to Reduce Carbon Emissions by 20 Percent, with decomposition of carbon emission effects. (Results are Percentage Change from Base Year unless otherwise indicated.) Overall St. North- Far average Moscow Peters. Tumen west North Central South Urals Siberia East Aggregate welfare Welfare (EV as % of consumption) -1.7 -1.5 -1.6 -6.9 -1.4 -2.0 -1.2 -1.6 -1.4 -1.6 -1.9 Welfare (EV as % of GDP) -0.8 -0.8 -0.7 -1.5 -0.6 -0.8 -0.6 -0.8 -0.6 -0.7 -0.9 Carbon Dioxide Emissions and Decomposition CO2 price (ruble per ton of CO2) 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 CO2 emissions, decomposed into: -20.0 -19.4 -20.1 -24.1 -21.0 -18.5 -20.6 -19.8 -20.4 -17.2 -17.7 Output effect (% of CO2) -1.8 -1.5 -1.5 -4.2 -1.7 -1.8 -1.5 -1.7 -1.6 -1.5 -1.6 Composition effect (% of CO2) -1.0 1.5 1.3 -13.4 1.0 -0.1 1.1 0.7 0.6 -0.7 -0.2 Technique effect (% of CO2) -17.1 -19.4 -19.9 -5.6 -20.4 -16.7 -20.3 -18.8 -19.5 -15.1 -15.9 Non-Carbon Dioxide Emissions Sulphur Dioxide 1.0 4.9 3.8 -0.2 -0.6 1.1 2.6 2.9 0.5 0.6 3.1 Nitrogen Oxide 2.0 5.0 2.9 -1.6 5.0 2.5 5.7 3.6 1.2 1.6 2.5 Hydrocarbons -3.6 -5.9 -5.6 -2.6 -5.3 -4.3 -5.4 -4.3 -3.1 -4.9 -6.2 Particulate Matter 1.1 4.9 4.1 -1.4 6.8 2.6 5.5 4.9 0.8 0.7 0.8 Volatile Organic Components -1.4 -1.3 -1.7 -1.6 0.7 -1.0 -0.6 -1.6 -1.1 -1.0 -0.7 Carbon Monoxide -1.2 1.2 -0.6 -1.7 -2.9 -0.7 -2.1 -1.3 -1.4 -0.3 0.2 Aggregate trade Regional terms of trade (% change) -0.6 2.5 2.4 0.9 2.4 2.3 2.6 2.4 2.4 2.5 2.4 Regional exports (% change) -1.3 -1.2 -1.3 -2.3 -1.3 -1.2 -1.2 -1.2 -1.0 -1.3 -1.3 Real exchange rate (% change) -0.3 -0.2 -0.3 -1.1 -0.3 -0.4 -0.3 -0.4 -0.3 -0.3 -0.3 International exports (% change) -0.4 -2.9 -2.1 1.8 -2.7 -0.4 -3.4 -0.4 -0.7 -0.6 -0.9 Return to primary factors (% change) Unskilled labor 0.0 0.3 0.2 -0.8 0.2 -0.2 0.2 -0.1 -0.1 -0.1 -0.1 Skilled labor 0.3 1.2 0.9 -2.7 1.0 0.0 1.0 0.7 0.7 -0.2 0.0 National capital -1.1 -1.0 -1.0 -1.8 -1.0 -1.1 -1.0 -1.1 -1.1 -1.1 -1.0 Regional mobile capital -0.7 -1.0 -1.0 0.7 -1.1 -0.8 -0.9 -0.7 -0.7 -0.7 -0.9 Crude oil resources -2.4 -2.9 -1.8 -1.3 -1.5 -1.4 -1.2 -1.0 Natural gas resources -42.7 -44.3 -25.2 -26.9 -28.0 -27.6 -27.0 -24.9 Coal resources -7.9 -8.1 -8.3 -8.8 -8.8 -7.9 -7.7 Specific capital in domestic firms -0.9 -1.0 -1.8 -1.4 -1.3 -1.2 -1.5 -1.5 -0.9 -0.8 Specific capital in multinational firms -0.8 -0.9 -2.2 -1.1 -1.1 -0.7 -0.5 -0.4 -0.7 -1.0 Factor adjustments Unskilled labor (% changing sectors) 0.7 0.7 0.7 1.1 0.8 0.6 0.7 0.7 0.7 0.7 0.7 Skilled labor (% changing sector) 1.1 0.9 0.9 2.1 1.0 1.0 0.9 0.9 0.9 1.2 1.2 Source: Authors' estimates 55 Table 16a. Impact of 20 Percent CO2 Reduction through Emissions Intensity Standards on Output by Sector and Regional Market. (Results are Percentage Change from Base Year) Good Central Siberia South North Urals Far East Moscow St. Pete. Tumen Northwest ELE 6.3 4.8 5.5 4.9 5.3 4.9 5.3 5.6 -0.1 7.2 NFM 0.9 0.6 -1.7 0.7 -0.7 2.6 4.2 4.4 11.0 SCI 0.1 0.0 -0.1 0.1 -0.2 0.3 0.3 0.2 -1.7 0.4 FIN -0.1 -0.1 -0.2 -0.2 -0.1 -0.2 -0.2 -0.2 -0.7 -0.1 HEA -0.3 -0.4 -0.5 -0.4 -0.4 -0.5 -0.5 -0.4 -0.8 -0.4 CON -0.5 -0.1 -0.8 -0.1 -0.7 0.5 -0.3 -0.3 -3.2 -0.3 CRU -0.5 -0.8 -0.6 -0.7 -0.4 -1.2 -1.0 CNM -0.4 -0.4 -0.8 -0.4 -0.8 0.1 -0.2 0.0 -5.5 -0.2 TMS -1.1 -0.9 -1.1 -0.9 -1.0 -0.9 -1.1 -1.0 -1.4 -1.2 CHM 0.3 0.7 -1.0 -0.6 -1.1 0.9 0.7 1.3 -15.7 2.5 HOU -0.7 -0.9 -1.0 -1.2 -0.9 -1.0 -0.9 -0.8 -3.7 -0.9 MWO -1.0 -2.1 -2.1 -0.8 -1.9 0.0 -0.7 -0.7 -5.6 -0.4 AGR -0.7 -1.3 -1.7 -1.2 -1.5 -0.7 -0.5 -0.6 -7.3 -0.2 OTI -0.9 -1.1 -1.4 -1.1 -1.3 -0.3 -0.8 -0.8 -7.7 -1.1 PST -1.8 -1.6 -1.6 -1.6 -1.6 -1.5 -1.5 -1.7 -2.0 -2.0 TRO -1.6 -1.5 -1.7 -1.7 -1.5 -1.7 -1.7 -1.6 -2.2 -1.7 RLW -1.9 -1.4 -2.0 -1.8 -1.9 -1.4 -1.5 -1.5 -2.2 -2.2 FOO -1.0 -1.4 -1.9 -1.7 -1.4 -1.1 -0.9 -1.0 -7.7 -1.1 OIL -1.1 -0.5 -3.0 -1.3 -0.7 -0.2 -2.9 -1.7 -7.2 OTH -2.4 -1.1 -2.7 -0.6 -2.4 -0.5 -2.3 -2.1 -5.8 -1.9 TRD -3.5 -2.2 -2.0 -1.8 -2.1 -2.3 -2.7 -2.8 0.5 -3.7 CLI -1.9 -1.9 -2.3 -2.2 -2.1 -2.0 -1.7 -2.0 -6.8 -1.9 TPP -1.5 -3.8 -2.4 -2.7 -2.0 -6.9 -1.4 -2.1 -5.2 -2.0 TRK -3.5 -3.0 -2.9 -3.0 -3.0 -3.3 -3.5 -3.4 -1.2 -3.8 FME -4.3 -3.5 -6.6 -3.6 -4.9 -1.1 -4.1 -10.4 -3.5 MAR -5.8 -4.4 -6.7 -6.5 -5.0 -5.6 -5.5 -6.4 -8.2 -7.1 COL -7.0 -6.3 -7.2 -6.5 -7.3 -6.2 PIP -12.7 -9.3 -8.2 -7.8 -7.3 -7.7 -19.8 -9.5 -3.2 -26.2 GAS -11.1 -11.7 -11.0 -11.5 -10.0 -21.0 -10.3 AIR -17.9 -16.4 -17.5 -20.7 -15.3 -20.7 -15.2 -21.0 -20.8 -20.8 See table 1 for sector codes. Source: Authors’ estimates. 56 Table 17: Impact on the Regions of Russia of Energy Efficiency Standards to Reduce Carbon Emissions by 20 Percent, with decomposition of carbon emission effects. (Results are Percentage Change from Base Year unless otherwise indicated.) Overall St. North- Far average Moscow Peters. Tumen west North Central South Urals Siberia East Aggregate welfare Welfare (EV as % of consumption) -5.9 -5.5 -5.9 -13.2 -5.5 -6.8 -5.2 -5.9 -5.6 -5.5 -6.5 Welfare (EV as % of GDP) -2.7 -3.0 -2.7 -2.8 -2.5 -2.8 -2.4 -2.8 -2.5 -2.6 -2.9 Carbon Dioxide Emissions and Decomposition CO2 price (ruble per ton of CO2) 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 CO2 emissions, decomposed into: -19.8 -20.2 -21.6 -20.5 -17.8 -18.2 -20.5 -20.7 -20.7 -17.0 -17.4 Output effect (% of CO2) -6.1 -5.5 -6.2 -7.4 -6.1 -6.5 -6.1 -6.1 -6.4 -5.8 -6.1 Composition effect (% of CO2) -6.0 -5.2 -5.8 -10.9 -5.1 -4.7 -5.4 -5.3 -5.9 -4.8 -3.8 Technique effect (% of CO2) -8.2 -10.1 -10.3 -1.9 -7.1 -7.5 -9.6 -9.9 -9.1 -6.9 -7.9 Non-Carbon Dioxide Emissions Sulphur Dioxide -6.9 -18.1 -11.1 -17.3 -11.5 -6.9 -18.7 -18.3 -10.7 -3.8 -5.6 Nitrogen Oxide -16.1 -20.5 -17.8 -10.9 -21.6 -17.0 -23.7 -19.6 -15.1 -13.6 -15.6 Hydrocarbons -6.5 -10.4 -11.4 -4.5 -9.5 -6.3 -9.2 -7.1 -7.7 -6.6 -2.4 Particulate Matter -12.5 -20.2 -19.1 -7.6 -24.4 -14.8 -22.9 -21.5 -13.0 -9.8 -10.2 Volatile Organic Components -6.8 -17.2 -11.8 -3.9 -9.2 -5.1 -16.5 -7.1 -8.1 -13.2 -10.0 Carbon Monoxide -4.7 -7.4 -6.3 -4.0 -5.9 -4.0 -9.8 -6.0 -5.6 -3.2 -3.5 Aggregate trade Regional terms of trade (% change) -1.5 19.9 19.3 16.5 19.4 18.8 19.5 19.7 19.4 19.6 19.4 Regional exports (% change) -7.5 -6.3 -8.5 -7.3 -7.3 -7.6 -7.9 -6.5 -8.3 -8.2 -8.0 Real exchange rate (% change) -0.2 -0.1 -0.3 -1.4 -0.1 -0.5 -0.1 -0.3 -0.2 -0.3 -0.3 International exports (% change) -1.2 -6.2 -4.6 3.3 -8.8 -0.9 -9.1 0.3 -0.9 -3.2 -2.0 Return to primary factors (% change) Unskilled labor 0.0 0.7 0.5 -1.1 0.2 -0.2 0.5 -0.3 0.0 -0.4 0.0 Skilled labor -0.4 0.9 0.5 -4.6 0.5 -0.7 0.2 -0.2 -0.4 -0.4 -0.2 National capital -3.4 -3.2 -3.5 -4.5 -3.3 -3.6 -3.2 -3.5 -3.3 -3.4 -3.4 Regional mobile capital -3.1 -3.6 -3.8 -0.8 -3.9 -3.2 -3.7 -3.1 -3.2 -3.1 -3.5 Crude oil resources -6.4 -7.4 -4.7 -5.1 -5.0 -4.6 -5.4 -4.9 Natural gas resources -32.0 -34.8 3.5 -6.6 -5.2 -2.3 -5.7 -1.1 Coal resources -3.2 -3.5 -2.5 -3.4 -2.8 -3.3 -2.8 Specific capital in domestic firms -2.9 -3.2 -1.8 -3.7 -4.0 -3.5 -3.8 -3.9 -2.5 -2.5 Specific capital in multinational firms -2.7 -2.3 3.3 -2.4 0.0 -0.1 0.9 1.3 1.6 -0.3 Factor adjustments Unskilled labor (% changing sectors) 2.2 2.1 2.4 2.0 2.5 2.2 2.3 2.0 2.2 2.5 2.3 Skilled labor (% changing sector) 2.7 2.2 2.7 4.0 2.7 2.6 2.7 2.2 2.7 2.8 2.8 Source: Authors' estimates 57 Table 17a. Impact of 20 Percent CO2 Reduction through Energy Intensity Standards on Output by Sector and Regional Market. (Results are Percentage Change from Base Year) Good Central Siberia South North Urals Far East Moscow St. Pete. Tumen Northwest NFM 10.0 4.2 7.0 4.0 11.4 8.3 19.1 22.5 81.1 SCI 1.1 0.7 0.3 0.5 0.6 0.8 1.0 1.0 -1.8 1.2 FIN -0.6 -0.7 -0.9 -0.7 -0.7 -0.8 -0.9 -0.7 -1.0 -0.6 TMS -1.5 -2.0 -1.8 -1.7 -1.3 -2.0 -2.2 -1.9 -0.7 -1.8 HEA -1.6 -1.5 -2.0 -1.8 -1.6 -2.0 -2.1 -1.8 -1.7 -1.6 CON -1.2 -1.9 -1.9 -2.2 -1.9 -0.8 -1.3 -1.1 -5.8 -0.5 GAS -1.2 -1.0 -1.5 0.3 0.9 -15.5 2.8 CRU -2.7 -2.4 -2.5 -2.3 -2.4 -3.3 -2.3 COL -2.3 -2.8 -2.9 -2.8 -2.4 -2.4 FOO -1.6 -3.0 -2.8 -4.3 -2.9 -1.8 -1.2 -2.5 -12.7 -1.0 AGR -1.7 -3.9 -4.0 -4.6 -3.5 -2.8 -2.6 -2.8 -13.1 -1.3 PST -4.3 -4.2 -3.9 -4.3 -4.0 -4.1 -3.7 -4.4 -4.0 -4.3 OTI -3.3 -5.0 -3.9 -5.2 -4.0 -3.8 -3.4 -3.8 -9.7 -3.1 RLW -5.4 -5.4 -5.5 -5.7 -5.9 -4.6 -5.0 -5.0 -4.8 -5.3 OTH -4.7 -5.2 -4.6 -6.1 -5.0 -4.5 -6.3 -6.6 -10.8 -3.7 MWO -4.5 -8.8 -6.1 -5.9 -5.8 -5.0 -4.9 -4.5 -10.3 -2.6 HOU -5.5 -5.7 -6.2 -6.5 -5.9 -6.3 -6.0 -5.9 -8.2 -5.6 TRO -6.4 -6.9 -6.0 -6.6 -6.3 -6.7 -6.3 -6.5 -5.6 -6.7 TRD -9.0 -6.9 -5.6 -5.6 -6.2 -6.6 -6.8 -7.8 -1.5 -8.4 TPP -4.7 -9.5 -6.6 -9.1 -5.1 -11.7 -6.7 -6.4 -7.4 -2.6 CLI -5.7 -6.1 -6.5 -7.8 -6.2 -6.8 -5.8 -6.7 -13.5 -5.5 TRK -8.3 -8.0 -7.0 -7.6 -7.5 -8.1 -8.2 -8.3 -4.0 -8.5 MAR -7.8 -8.0 -7.8 -8.5 -6.9 -8.5 -7.9 -9.6 -5.3 -6.4 CNM -6.2 -9.6 -6.3 -8.5 -6.5 -7.7 -10.1 -9.0 -12.0 -8.2 FME -8.4 -11.9 -13.2 -12.5 -10.3 -7.9 -11.2 -18.6 -7.6 PIP -17.0 -15.6 -9.0 -5.2 -10.5 -12.4 -17.8 -14.8 1.0 -18.9 CHM -13.9 -22.5 -16.0 -15.0 -17.0 -13.3 -15.2 -16.8 -31.7 -16.4 OIL -17.9 -20.5 -19.0 -19.6 -18.7 -17.9 -18.8 -16.0 -28.0 ELE -25.3 -23.0 -23.4 -22.8 -24.8 -22.0 -21.0 -23.8 -19.0 -25.4 AIR -25.4 -23.9 -25.0 -31.2 -21.4 -31.2 -21.9 -31.3 -29.8 -30.4 See table 1 for sector codes. Source: Authors’ estimates. 58 Table 18: Impact on the Regions of Russia of WTO Accession and Simultaneous “Cap and Trade” Market Based Emission Control System to Reduce Carbon Emissions by 20 Percent, with decomposition of carbon emission effects. (Results are Percentage Change from Base Year.) Overall St. North- Far average Moscow Peters. Tumen west North Central South Urals Siberia East Aggregate welfare Welfare (EV as % of consumption) 7.2 5.5 9.7 13.7 12.5 9.2 8.4 7.4 6.4 7.5 8.5 Welfare (EV as % of GDP) 3.3 3.0 4.4 2.9 5.8 3.8 3.9 3.5 2.9 3.5 3.8 Carbon Dioxide Emissions and Decomposition CO2 price (ruble per ton of CO2) 112.4 112.4 112.4 112.4 112.4 112.4 112.4 112.4 112.4 112.4 CO2 emissions, decomposed into: -20.0 -19.0 -17.7 -22.0 -18.8 -18.1 -19.1 -17.8 -21.3 -20.8 -18.3 Output effect (% of CO2) 3.6 3.5 5.9 2.3 6.0 5.2 4.0 4.0 2.5 3.8 5.3 Composition effect (% of CO2) -3.6 -1.0 -0.7 -11.4 -2.7 -3.4 -1.3 -1.5 -3.0 -5.2 -2.9 Technique effect (% of CO2) -19.5 -20.8 -21.6 -13.1 -20.9 -19.1 -21.1 -19.7 -20.7 -19.1 -19.8 Non-Carbon Dioxide Emissions Sulphur Dioxide 5.9 1.6 11.7 -2.6 -8.6 7.4 -2.9 2.7 5.3 7.3 5.2 Nitrogen Oxide -1.3 -2.9 0.3 -1.4 1.3 -0.1 -1.9 -1.6 -1.7 0.0 -1.0 Hydrocarbons -3.6 -4.7 0.6 -0.5 1.2 -3.4 -2.0 -1.7 -2.8 -10.7 -16.7 Particulate Matter -0.6 -3.2 -0.4 -0.3 0.1 0.7 -2.1 -2.1 -1.2 1.0 -0.4 Volatile Organic Components 0.8 -1.6 2.2 0.9 17.6 1.4 9.2 1.9 -0.1 -1.5 3.3 Carbon Monoxide 2.2 9.5 6.0 0.7 -9.2 4.1 -3.4 2.3 1.8 5.2 3.1 Aggregate trade Regional terms of trade (% change) 2.8 14.0 15.5 12.6 14.6 14.5 13.7 13.4 12.4 13.0 14.6 Regional exports (% change) 1.4 1.5 2.3 0.9 2.4 1.9 2.5 1.6 1.4 0.4 2.1 Real exchange rate (% change) 2.4 2.5 3.3 1.9 3.5 2.6 3.2 2.6 1.9 1.7 2.6 International exports (% change) 8.2 16.0 13.6 3.9 12.7 9.0 10.0 9.6 8.9 7.2 13.1 Return to primary factors (% change) Unskilled labor 1.6 2.2 4.4 1.0 4.8 2.7 2.2 2.3 0.0 1.0 3.2 Skilled labor 0.3 0.7 3.7 -1.2 3.2 1.3 1.6 1.5 -0.4 -1.8 1.7 National capital 1.6 1.7 2.5 1.1 2.7 1.8 2.4 1.8 1.1 0.9 1.8 Regional mobile capital 3.6 3.4 6.3 4.2 5.8 5.2 3.4 3.7 2.4 3.7 5.7 Crude oil resources 3.8 3.6 5.8 5.3 5.5 3.4 2.9 5.3 Natural gas resources -33.4 -34.1 -28.4 -30.6 -23.9 -26.3 -34.1 -33.6 Coal resources -9.2 -6.5 -4.7 -6.2 -9.9 -10.0 -7.0 Specific capital in domestic firms -29.9 -21.5 -48.5 -21.9 -25.5 -17.4 -25.0 -18.2 -18.8 -27.1 Specific capital in multinational firms 59.3 48.4 217.4 77.4 139.6 113.4 125.9 139.0 159.2 113.6 Factor adjustments Unskilled labor (% changing sectors) 2.1 1.8 2.1 2.5 2.8 2.3 1.8 1.4 2.4 2.6 3.2 Skilled labor (% changing sector) 2.9 2.4 2.6 3.1 3.3 3.4 2.3 1.9 2.7 4.4 4.4 Source: Authors' estimates 59 Table 18a. Impact on Output by Sector and Regional Market of WTO Accession and Simultaneous “Cap and Trade” to Reduce Carbon Emissions by 20 Percent. (Results are Percentage Change from Base Year) Good Central Siberia South North Urals Far East Moscow St. Pete. Tumen Northwest NFM 37.2 15.6 50.8 22.3 47.9 13.5 69.1 48.1 192.6 TMS 14.5 9.0 13.5 20.6 0.9 21.5 -0.6 21.7 10.7 23.3 TRK 5.4 3.3 5.5 8.5 0.6 11.2 1.3 10.0 4.6 11.0 OIL 12.9 0.7 6.9 5.8 3.1 5.7 2.6 4.4 1.4 PST 5.2 3.7 5.0 5.2 3.3 5.4 3.4 5.2 4.6 6.6 TRD 2.6 2.8 3.7 4.4 2.5 5.5 3.1 5.0 4.2 5.5 TPP -4.9 -2.7 -10.9 0.3 -2.5 41.8 -13.3 -2.2 8.9 4.2 CRU 0.9 2.1 2.2 1.0 2.1 1.3 2.0 HEA 1.4 1.2 1.3 1.2 1.1 1.1 0.8 1.3 1.2 1.9 CLI 4.3 -0.2 1.6 1.0 1.8 0.1 0.5 -0.3 1.4 1.2 SCI 0.4 0.9 -0.9 0.7 -1.6 1.8 0.8 7.7 -6.8 6.4 CON 2.1 -1.3 0.1 -1.4 -0.5 -2.1 1.1 -1.2 -1.8 -0.1 Chemicals 2.1 -7.2 -2.4 -10.2 -2.8 -10.1 -6.8 -2.4 -1.1 34.2 HOU -0.4 -1.3 -0.9 -0.6 -1.5 -1.1 -1.9 -0.6 0.1 0.8 MWO -3.9 -6.0 -0.7 -4.8 -7.5 -5.6 12.1 5.6 -6.4 2.8 AGR 3.1 -2.0 0.3 -3.5 1.7 -4.5 -0.2 -4.8 -1.8 -3.1 ELE -1.7 -1.6 -1.7 -1.2 -2.4 -1.4 -2.5 -0.6 -3.1 0.6 OTH 5.7 -3.0 0.0 -3.6 2.5 -5.4 0.8 -6.2 -1.8 -5.7 RLW -2.0 -5.2 -1.3 -2.0 -3.9 -0.3 -1.3 0.0 -1.8 -2.2 OTI -0.1 -6.2 -1.2 -3.8 -2.3 -5.4 2.3 -0.5 -6.0 -1.6 AIR -1.3 -6.4 -4.4 -2.8 -4.7 -4.0 -5.1 -3.8 -5.3 -0.5 FOO -3.4 -5.3 -2.7 -3.1 -4.2 -5.5 -7.3 -5.1 0.9 -4.2 MAR -1.2 -9.1 -4.6 -2.5 -3.8 -0.1 -5.0 -3.2 -8.8 -4.5 FIN -6.1 -6.4 -5.8 -6.2 -6.7 -5.7 -6.0 -5.5 -8.2 -5.0 TRO -6.1 -11.9 -8.1 -3.3 -16.5 -1.2 -19.0 -1.5 -14.9 -0.2 CNM -4.7 -12.4 -5.6 -8.2 -7.5 -9.9 -11.7 -10.8 -4.0 -9.1 Pipelines -10.9 -12.7 -9.6 -11.5 -8.8 -10.2 -23.0 -11.1 -4.2 -25.4 Ferrous Metals -8.5 -21.0 -12.4 -14.8 -19.2 -15.0 -15.7 -6.0 -13.8 Coal -15.2 -18.3 -16.1 -16.2 -18.6 -16.7 GAS -21.4 -16.4 -19.7 -17.4 -21.3 -21.4 -18.9 See table 1 for sector codes. Source: Authors’ estimates. 60 Table 19: Impact on the Regions of Russia of WTO Accession and Simultaneous Emission Intensity Standards to Reduce Carbon Emissions by 20 Percent, with decomposition of carbon emission effects. (Results are Percentage Change from Base Year.) Overall St. North- Far average Moscow Peters. Tumen west North Central South Urals Siberia East Aggregate welfare Welfare (EV as % of consumption) 6.4 5.8 9.4 5.2 10.1 8.1 7.1 7.1 5.3 6.3 8.2 Welfare (EV as % of GDP) 3.0 3.2 4.2 1.1 4.7 3.4 3.3 3.4 2.4 3.0 3.7 Carbon Dioxide Emissions and Decomposition CO2 price (ruble per ton of CO2) 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 CO2 emissions, decomposed into: -19.2 -20.0 -16.7 -24.0 -17.8 -16.8 -18.7 -19.0 -20.1 -15.7 -15.9 Output effect (% of CO2) 2.7 3.1 5.0 0.0 5.2 4.2 3.1 3.2 1.8 2.9 4.6 Composition effect (% of CO2) -0.4 0.8 4.9 -15.1 3.6 0.2 3.6 1.3 1.5 0.3 0.1 Technique effect (% of CO2) -20.3 -23.0 -24.4 -7.0 -24.6 -20.0 -23.9 -22.3 -22.5 -18.0 -19.6 Non-Carbon Dioxide Emissions Sulphur Dioxide 7.1 10.2 28.0 3.1 7.8 9.1 13.2 13.1 9.4 4.9 8.9 Nitrogen Oxide 5.1 7.5 7.9 0.9 12.9 6.6 9.7 7.7 3.8 4.7 5.8 Hydrocarbons -2.6 -8.9 -2.5 -1.1 -1.4 -1.2 -4.0 -3.4 -3.7 -3.3 0.8 Particulate Matter 4.3 7.1 10.2 1.1 13.2 7.0 9.0 8.6 4.0 3.7 3.5 Volatile Organic Components 1.1 2.3 0.4 0.9 15.8 1.7 5.9 1.7 0.6 1.7 3.6 Carbon Monoxide 3.0 11.4 10.8 0.8 4.6 4.1 12.9 4.0 2.7 3.1 4.0 Aggregate trade Regional terms of trade (% change) 2.2 16.0 17.6 13.9 17.3 16.3 16.1 15.5 14.8 14.8 16.7 Regional exports (% change) 1.4 1.9 2.2 0.2 2.0 2.2 1.7 1.2 1.3 1.1 2.3 Real exchange rate (% change) 1.5 1.7 2.4 0.9 1.9 1.8 1.8 1.6 0.9 1.0 2.1 International exports (% change) 7.5 7.9 13.7 4.8 14.4 7.0 14.5 7.7 7.8 6.7 8.3 Return to primary factors (% change) Unskilled labor 3.6 4.1 6.2 2.4 5.7 4.6 3.8 4.3 2.2 3.4 5.4 Skilled labor 3.9 3.7 7.1 1.3 7.1 5.2 5.2 5.0 2.9 3.4 5.9 National capital 2.4 2.6 3.3 1.8 2.9 2.7 2.7 2.5 1.8 1.9 3.0 Regional mobile capital 4.9 4.6 7.9 5.1 8.0 6.0 5.2 5.0 3.9 4.6 6.3 Crude oil resources 1.6 1.6 1.7 3.4 2.9 0.9 1.3 4.4 Natural gas resources -44.2 -44.6 -51.2 -39.5 -37.8 -41.5 -43.3 -38.6 Coal resources -0.7 1.7 0.2 -0.1 -2.5 -1.4 2.3 Specific capital in domestic firms -30.7 -23.1 -49.0 -22.3 -25.8 -18.0 -25.5 -17.9 -20.2 -27.4 Specific capital in multinational firms 58.6 46.0 209.4 76.2 137.2 111.4 123.1 136.3 156.3 111.8 Factor adjustments Unskilled labor (% changing sectors) 2.1 1.9 2.6 2.5 3.7 2.1 2.2 1.7 2.2 2.0 2.2 Skilled labor (% changing sector) 2.8 2.8 3.6 3.4 4.0 2.9 2.9 2.3 2.6 2.5 3.0 Source: Authors' estimates 61 Table 19a. Impact on Output by Sector and Regional Market of WTO Accession and Simultaneous Emissions Intensity Standards to Reduce Carbon Emissions by 20 Percent Impact. (Results are Percentage Change from Base Year) Good Central Siberia South North Urals Far East Moscow St. Pete. Tumen Northwest FME 18.1 6.6 23.3 17.2 5.7 19.9 28.5 210.6 5.7 CHM 9.7 22.0 10.2 2.6 11.6 6.4 7.2 12.8 14.5 31.7 TMS 12.1 7.3 11.7 18.8 -0.8 20.0 -2.0 19.8 8.5 20.0 NFM 8.6 4.7 19.6 10.3 15.2 8.8 31.0 4.0 -10.6 ELE 10.7 8.6 9.9 9.1 8.7 9.1 8.0 10.7 3.3 14.5 TRK 5.2 2.8 4.7 7.2 0.4 8.8 0.6 9.3 3.9 9.7 TRD 2.4 2.0 2.3 2.9 1.6 3.3 1.8 4.0 3.6 4.7 SCI 1.8 2.0 0.3 1.9 -0.2 6.1 1.3 8.1 -6.2 7.4 PST 1.7 1.3 2.1 2.6 0.5 3.0 1.0 2.3 1.8 2.3 CRU 0.9 1.6 2.1 0.7 2.5 1.4 0.7 OIL 3.9 -0.4 1.9 3.6 -0.5 5.9 -1.8 0.0 -0.8 HOU 1.2 0.9 1.5 1.6 0.4 1.8 1.1 1.6 -1.1 1.8 HEA 1.0 0.9 1.1 1.0 0.8 1.1 0.9 1.2 0.3 1.3 RLW 1.0 -1.0 -0.6 -0.3 -1.0 0.3 -1.3 3.2 -2.0 1.4 CON -0.1 -1.1 -0.2 -0.3 -0.5 0.1 1.3 -1.9 -0.5 -4.0 COL -0.9 -1.7 -1.0 0.6 -2.5 0.8 MWO -5.0 -1.8 -1.1 -1.2 -6.3 2.5 7.7 2.9 -4.4 -5.6 OTI -1.8 -4.1 -1.5 -1.4 -2.7 -1.8 1.6 -0.4 -6.4 -3.3 CLI -1.1 -2.7 -1.5 -1.2 -2.1 -1.1 -2.0 -3.7 -2.6 -5.0 AGR -2.1 -2.7 -2.1 -3.0 -1.2 -3.4 -1.4 -6.8 -2.8 -8.9 CNM -2.8 -5.3 -2.2 -1.8 -3.6 -1.9 -4.9 -5.5 -0.6 -8.0 TPP -7.8 -9.2 -12.0 -2.7 -4.2 7.3 -12.9 -8.6 9.0 -11.2 FIN -5.7 -6.3 -5.7 -6.1 -6.5 -5.5 -5.9 -5.1 -8.4 -4.3 OTH -4.4 -7.7 -5.8 -5.5 -3.9 -7.0 -2.6 -10.3 -3.6 -14.9 FOO -9.3 -8.3 -8.0 -5.6 -7.8 -8.2 -11.9 -9.0 -4.2 -12.6 TRO -6.3 -11.3 -8.3 -3.4 -16.9 -1.5 -19.9 -1.2 -15.6 -0.5 MAR -12.7 -15.7 -15.0 -12.0 -12.0 -10.6 -15.0 -12.8 -15.1 -15.1 PIP -15.0 -13.0 -11.0 -11.7 -9.9 -10.5 -24.8 -13.6 -3.3 -28.4 GAS -20.5 -17.3 -18.2 -19.4 -17.8 -21.2 -26.0 AIR -21.7 -22.0 -21.5 -22.5 -20.5 -22.6 -19.5 -24.0 -23.3 -23.9 See table 1 for sector codes. Source: Authors’ estimates. 62 Table 20: Impact on the Regions of Russia of WTO Accession and Simultaneous Energy Efficiency Standards to Reduce Carbon Emissions by 20 Percent, with decomposition of carbon emission effects. (Results are Percentage Change from Base Year.) Overall St. North- Far average Moscow Peters. Tumen west North Central South Urals Siberia East Aggregate welfare Welfare (EV as % of consumption) 0.6 0.3 3.3 -3.2 4.2 0.7 1.5 1.0 -0.6 0.9 1.8 Welfare (EV as % of GDP) 0.3 0.2 1.5 -0.7 2.0 0.3 0.7 0.5 -0.3 0.4 0.8 Carbon Dioxide Emissions and Decomposition CO2 price (ruble per ton of CO2) 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 CO2 emissions, decomposed into: -19.7 -21.6 -18.9 -20.7 -13.9 -17.5 -18.9 -20.9 -21.7 -16.3 -16.0 Output effect (% of CO2) -3.0 -2.1 -1.1 -4.2 -0.8 -2.6 -2.9 -2.5 -4.4 -2.7 -1.3 Composition effect (% of CO2) -6.5 -7.1 -3.9 -12.7 -3.3 -5.3 -4.1 -6.1 -6.7 -4.8 -4.1 Technique effect (% of CO2) -10.6 -12.9 -14.0 -3.0 -9.9 -9.9 -12.3 -12.7 -11.3 -9.2 -10.7 Non-Carbon Dioxide Emissions Sulphur Dioxide -1.3 -15.5 9.2 -16.6 -4.1 -1.6 -12.0 -11.7 -2.0 0.5 -0.4 Nitrogen Oxide -16.4 -22.2 -17.0 -10.0 -19.9 -17.5 -25.2 -20.2 -15.7 -13.5 -15.4 Hydrocarbons -6.4 -14.8 -10.2 -3.4 -7.5 -4.3 -9.0 -7.1 -9.6 -5.6 5.6 Particulate Matter -12.0 -22.1 -18.1 -6.2 -24.6 -14.4 -24.7 -22.8 -12.6 -8.8 -9.5 Volatile Organic Components -5.8 -19.1 -11.9 -1.8 -2.0 -4.0 -14.2 -5.4 -8.6 -14.6 -7.5 Carbon Monoxide -1.2 2.9 3.1 -1.9 2.4 -1.1 2.6 -1.9 -2.1 0.1 0.0 Aggregate trade Regional terms of trade (% change) 0.9 24.5 25.4 20.1 25.5 22.7 23.9 23.7 22.6 22.7 24.6 Regional exports (% change) -6.2 -4.4 -6.6 -5.7 -5.5 -6.1 -6.4 -5.3 -7.5 -7.3 -5.9 Real exchange rate (% change) 1.6 1.8 2.4 0.4 2.2 1.6 2.1 1.7 1.1 1.0 2.1 International exports (% change) 6.3 4.6 9.9 6.6 5.1 5.4 6.5 8.5 7.3 3.1 6.8 Return to primary factors (% change) Unskilled labor 3.1 4.2 6.2 1.6 5.4 3.9 3.7 3.4 1.7 2.5 4.9 Skilled labor 2.5 3.0 6.0 -1.7 6.1 3.9 3.8 3.5 1.2 2.8 5.1 National capital -0.8 -0.5 0.0 -1.9 -0.1 -0.7 -0.2 -0.6 -1.2 -1.3 -0.3 Regional mobile capital 1.5 1.1 3.9 3.2 3.7 2.1 1.3 1.6 0.4 1.2 2.6 Crude oil resources -3.3 -3.9 -1.3 -1.3 -1.0 -2.8 -3.7 -0.2 Natural gas resources -33.1 -35.2 -19.9 -12.4 -9.4 -11.8 -18.9 -11.1 Coal resources 5.0 7.2 7.9 6.6 4.6 4.2 8.4 Specific capital in domestic firms -32.9 -25.6 -49.1 -24.6 -26.6 -20.6 -28.1 -20.7 -21.5 -29.3 Specific capital in multinational firms 55.1 43.9 216.2 73.3 122.9 109.5 122.1 135.0 155.3 111.5 Factor adjustments Unskilled labor (% changing sectors) 2.9 2.8 3.2 2.6 3.4 2.9 2.8 2.4 2.9 3.3 3.1 Skilled labor (% changing sector) 3.5 3.4 4.0 3.4 4.0 3.3 3.7 2.9 3.6 3.8 4.0 Source: Authors' estimates 63 Table 20a. Impact on Output by Sector and Regional Market of WTO Accession and Simultaneous Energy Intensity Standards to Reduce Carbon Emissions by 20 Percent Impact. (Results are Percentage Change from Base Year) Good Central Siberia South North Urals Far East Moscow St. Pete. Tumen Northwest NFM 25.4 11.4 39.1 13.1 38.8 17.6 63.6 32.3 85.9 FME 12.6 -7.1 10.8 0.5 -3.1 7.5 15.0 170.0 2.2 TMS 11.1 5.5 10.4 17.5 -1.6 19.1 -3.5 19.1 9.5 19.6 COL 5.3 2.7 4.5 4.9 3.3 5.6 SCI 2.6 2.6 0.4 7.2 0.4 6.4 2.0 9.0 -6.6 8.2 CRU -1.5 0.0 -0.4 -1.0 0.4 -1.1 -0.5 HEA -0.6 -0.6 -0.8 -0.9 -0.8 -0.8 -1.2 -0.7 -0.8 -0.3 PST -1.3 -2.1 -0.6 -1.1 -2.4 -0.2 -1.6 -1.0 -0.7 -0.6 TRK -2.1 -4.5 -1.4 -0.6 -6.0 1.3 -6.0 1.6 0.1 1.8 CON -0.7 -3.3 -1.5 -2.8 -1.9 -1.8 0.1 -2.7 -4.4 -3.6 TRD -4.8 -4.1 -2.3 -2.3 -3.7 -2.2 -3.5 -2.4 1.4 -1.9 RLW -3.3 -6.3 -5.2 -5.9 -6.4 -3.6 -5.8 -1.7 -5.1 -2.6 HOU -5.2 -5.4 -5.4 -6.0 -6.2 -5.2 -5.8 -5.2 -7.1 -4.5 OTI -4.7 -9.1 -4.8 -7.6 -6.2 -6.4 -1.8 -4.1 -10.1 -5.3 AGR -2.9 -6.0 -4.7 -6.3 -3.6 -6.1 -4.1 -9.3 -11.1 -9.0 GAS -7.3 -2.9 -4.4 -3.9 -3.7 -15.7 -8.0 FIN -6.4 -7.1 -6.6 -7.6 -7.2 -6.5 -6.9 -6.1 -8.8 -5.0 MWO -8.7 -10.0 -5.9 -17.8 -10.9 -3.9 2.9 -1.0 -11.1 -6.0 CLI -5.4 -7.7 -6.7 -8.3 -6.9 -7.3 -6.9 -9.4 -11.9 -8.6 FOO -9.1 -9.8 -8.2 -8.2 -9.1 -8.5 -11.5 -10.3 -10.5 -11.2 OTH -6.0 -12.2 -7.3 -11.4 -6.3 -11.2 -7.2 -14.8 -10.6 -15.4 TPP -12.1 -16.1 -17.5 -11.1 -8.5 -1.2 -19.4 -14.0 5.2 -10.4 TRO -12.0 -17.4 -13.4 -10.0 -21.8 -7.8 -24.5 -7.4 -19.4 -7.0 CNM -11.5 -18.5 -10.7 -13.9 -12.3 -13.9 -18.9 -18.4 -11.6 -18.9 MAR -13.7 -19.4 -15.8 -14.4 -13.7 -13.9 -17.2 -16.2 -12.6 -13.3 PIP -19.8 -20.7 -12.0 -9.3 -13.9 -15.8 -23.4 -19.2 1.3 -21.6 CHM -13.2 -20.5 -15.0 -20.2 -16.0 -15.9 -17.8 -17.1 -22.4 -3.6 OIL -14.8 -24.0 -16.8 -18.1 -21.6 -14.9 -20.2 -16.1 -27.0 ELE -26.6 -24.1 -24.3 -24.0 -26.6 -22.3 -22.3 -24.2 -18.5 -25.0 AIR -32.5 -32.1 -31.9 -37.8 -29.0 -37.4 -28.6 -38.0 -35.9 -37.0 See table 1 for sector codes. Source: Authors’ estimates. 64 Table 21: Summary of Our Seven Policy Scenarios for Overall Impacts from our central model with FDI and IRTS (Results are Percentage Change from Base Year.) WTO Accession plus Carbon Reduction Policies Alone WTO carbon emissions energy emissions energy accession emissions intensity intensity emissions intensity intensity alone trading standards standards trading standards standards Aggregate welfare Welfare (EV as % of consumption) 8.6 7.2 6.4 0.6 -1.1 -1.7 -5.9 Welfare (EV as % of GDP) 4.0 3.3 3.0 0.3 -0.5 -0.8 -2.7 Carbon Dioxide Emissions and Decomposition CO2 price (ruble per ton of CO2) 112.4 96.0 CO2 emissions, decomposed into: 4.3 -20.0 -19.2 -19.7 -20.0 -20.0 -19.8 Output effect (% of CO2) 4.9 3.6 2.7 -3.0 -1.0 -1.8 -6.1 Composition effect (% of CO2) 1.0 -3.6 -0.4 -6.5 -3.1 -1.0 -6.0 Technique effect (% of CO2) -1.6 -19.5 -20.3 -10.6 -16.3 -17.1 -8.2 Non-Carbon Dioxide Emissions Sulphur Dioxide 6.2 5.9 7.1 -1.3 -0.1 1.0 -6.9 Nitrogen Oxide 2.8 -1.3 5.1 -16.4 -3.3 2.0 -16.1 Hydrocarbons 1.7 -3.6 -2.6 -6.4 -4.2 -3.6 -6.5 Particulate Matter 3.0 -0.6 4.3 -12.0 -2.9 1.1 -12.5 Volatile Organic Components 2.7 0.8 1.1 -5.8 -1.5 -1.4 -6.8 Carbon Monoxide 4.5 2.2 3.0 -1.2 -1.7 -1.2 -4.7 Aggregate trade Regional terms of trade (% change) 2.9 2.8 2.2 0.9 -0.1 -0.6 -1.5 Regional exports (% change) 3.0 1.4 1.4 -6.2 -1.2 -1.3 -7.5 Real exchange rate (% change) 1.8 2.4 1.5 1.6 0.4 -0.3 -0.2 International exports (% change) 8.1 8.2 7.5 6.3 0.4 -0.4 -1.2 Return to primary factors (% change) Unskilled labor 3.7 1.6 3.6 3.1 -1.7 0.0 0.0 Skilled labor 3.7 0.3 3.9 2.5 -2.6 0.3 -0.4 National capital 3.8 1.6 2.4 -0.8 -1.7 -1.1 -3.4 Regional mobile capital 5.8 3.6 4.9 1.5 -1.8 -0.7 -3.1 Crude oil resources 4.4 3.8 1.6 -3.3 -0.6 -2.4 -6.4 Natural gas resources 7.0 -33.4 -44.2 -33.1 -32.9 -42.7 -32.0 Coal resources 9.7 -9.2 -0.7 5.0 -13.6 -7.9 -3.2 Factor adjustments Unskilled labor (% changing sectors) 2.0 2.1 2.1 2.9 0.9 0.7 2.2 Skilled labor (% changing sector) 2.6 2.9 2.8 3.5 1.5 1.1 2.7 Source: Authors' estimates 65 Table 22: Sensitivity Analysis—Summary of Constant Returns to Scale Model Results of Our Seven Policy Scenarios. (Percentage Change from Base Year.) o WTO Accession plus Carbon Reduction Policies Alone WTO carbon emissions energy emissions energy accession emissions intensity intensity emissions intensity intensity alone trading standards standards trading standards standards Aggregate welfare Welfare (EV as % of consumption) 1.1 0.7 0.0 -3.5 -0.4 -1.0 -4.1 Welfare (EV as % of GDP) 0.5 0.3 0.0 -1.6 -0.2 -0.4 -1.9 Carbon Dioxide Emissions and Decomposition CO2 price (ruble per ton of CO2) 107.8 103.4 CO2 emissions, decomposed into: 1.0 -20.0 -20.4 -20.2 -20.0 -19.9 -19.9 Output effect (% of CO2) 1.1 0.4 -0.4 -4.7 -0.7 -1.4 -5.3 Composition effect (% of CO2) 0.4 -2.4 -0.9 -6.2 -2.5 -1.2 -6.1 Technique effect (% of CO2) -0.4 -18.0 -18.6 -9.7 -17.2 -17.3 -8.8 Non-Carbon Dioxide Emissions Sulphur Dioxide 4.6 4.5 5.2 -4.7 -0.4 0.6 -8.9 Nitrogen Oxide 0.9 -2.1 3.1 -16.5 -2.9 2.1 -16.4 Hydrocarbons 0.1 -4.5 -3.8 -7.1 -4.3 -3.6 -6.7 Particulate Matter 1.1 -1.4 2.4 -12.5 -2.5 1.2 -12.9 Volatile Organic Components 0.1 -1.1 -1.0 -6.7 -1.1 -1.1 -6.4 Carbon Monoxide 1.9 0.5 0.6 -3.6 -1.4 -1.2 -5.2 Aggregate trade Regional terms of trade (% change) 1.0 1.1 0.7 0.1 0.1 -0.3 -0.8 Regional exports (% change) 0.2 -0.9 -1.0 -7.7 -1.1 -1.1 -7.4 Real exchange rate (% change) 0.2 0.7 0.0 0.4 0.4 -0.2 0.2 International exports (% change) 2.1 2.0 1.7 -0.1 -0.1 -0.4 -2.0 Return to primary factors (% change) Unskilled labor 1.2 -0.3 1.7 2.7 -1.5 0.5 1.5 Skilled labor 1.6 -0.9 2.4 2.5 -2.4 0.8 0.9 National capital 1.4 -0.1 0.7 -1.2 -1.5 -0.7 -2.4 Regional mobile capital 1.9 0.2 1.6 -0.3 -1.6 -0.2 -1.9 Crude oil resources 0.2 -0.1 -1.6 -5.8 -0.3 -1.7 -5.7 Natural gas resources 0.4 -35.4 -45.9 -35.2 -33.8 -43.0 -32.8 Coal resources 0.6 -12.2 -7.6 -0.5 -12.2 -7.3 -0.9 Factor adjustments Unskilled labor (% changing sectors) 0.8 0.9 1.2 2.5 0.7 0.7 2.3 Skilled labor (% changing sector) 0.9 1.4 1.5 3.0 1.3 1.0 2.7 Source: Authors' estimates 66 Table 23a. Piecemeal Sensitivity Analysis -- Welfare Impacts as a percent of GDP by Region from WTO Accession (percentage change from base year) Overall Far St. Parameter being changed average Central East North Siberia South Urals Moscow Peters. Tumen Northwest Central Results for reference 4.0 4.1 4.8 4.4 3.9 4.4 3.2 4.2 5.2 2.9 5.6 esubc = 0.5 3.6 3.7 4.4 4.1 3.6 4.0 3.0 3.9 4.3 2.7 5.2 esubc = 1.5 4.1 4.2 4.9 4.6 4.0 4.5 3.3 4.4 5.4 2.9 5.7 esub = 2 3.9 4.1 5.1 4.6 3.7 4.3 2.9 4.2 5.8 2.7 6.1 esub = 4 3.8 3.9 4.5 4.2 3.8 4.2 3.2 4.1 4.8 2.8 5.2 esubs = 0.5 3.1 3.2 3.7 3.4 3.1 3.5 2.5 3.4 4.1 2.2 4.4 esubs = 2.0 5.3 5.6 6.5 6.1 5.3 5.8 4.3 5.6 6.2 4.0 7.6 esubva = 0.5 4.0 3.9 4.9 4.2 3.9 4.4 3.1 4.3 5.1 2.9 5.3 esubva = 1.5 4.0 4.1 4.7 4.4 3.9 4.3 3.2 4.2 5.2 2.9 5.7 etad = 10 4.1 4.1 5.1 4.6 3.9 4.5 3.2 4.5 5.5 2.8 5.7 etad = 5 3.8 4.1 4.4 4.2 3.9 4.2 3.2 3.8 4.8 2.9 5.5 etadx = 3 3.9 4.0 4.7 4.1 3.9 4.3 3.2 4.1 5.1 3.0 5.5 etadx = 7 4.0 4.1 4.8 4.4 3.9 4.4 3.2 4.3 5.3 2.8 5.6 etaf = 12.5 3.4 3.5 4.3 3.9 3.3 3.8 2.7 3.7 4.7 2.4 5.0 etaf = 17.5 4.5 4.6 5.2 4.9 4.4 4.9 3.7 4.7 5.6 3.3 6.1 sigmadm = 4 3.9 4.0 4.6 4.3 3.9 4.2 3.2 4.1 4.9 2.9 5.3 sigmadm = 2 3.9 4.0 5.0 4.5 3.7 4.3 2.9 4.1 5.6 2.6 5.9 Source: Authors' calculations. Notes: a. The piecemeal sensitivity analysis employs central values for all parameters (see below) other than the tested parameter. b. Hicksian equivalent variation as a percent of the value of consumption in the benchmark equilibrium. Parameter Central Definitions of the parameter (see figures, especially figure 5) value for more precise elasticity structure). esubc 1.25 Elasticity of substitution in consumer demand esubs 1.25 Elasticity of substitution between value-added and business services sigmadm 3 "Armington" elasticity of substitution between imports and domestic goods etaf 15 Elasticity of multinational service firm supply with respect to price of output etad 7.5 Elasticity of Russian service firm supply with respect to price of output esub 3 Elasticity of substitution between firm varieties in imperfectly competitive sectors esubva 1 Elasticity of substitution between primary factors of production in value added etadx 5 Elasticity of transformation (domestic output versus exports) 67 Table 23b. Piecemeal Sensitivity Analysis – Carbone Dioxide Emissions by Region from WTO Accession (percentage change from base year) Overall Far St. Parameter being changed average Central East North Siberia South Urals Moscow Peters. Tumen Northwest Central Results for reference 4.3 6.1 4.9 5.2 4.6 4.4 3.3 2.4 8.9 3.7 8.2 esubc = 0.5 4.3 5.9 5.0 5.2 4.6 4.3 3.3 2.6 9.3 3.7 8.0 esubc = 1.5 4.3 6.2 4.9 5.2 4.6 4.5 3.3 2.3 8.9 3.7 8.2 esub = 2 3.6 5.3 4.8 5.0 3.6 3.8 2.6 1.8 7.9 3.2 8.2 esub = 4 4.4 6.3 4.7 5.1 4.9 4.5 3.6 2.5 9.0 3.7 8.0 esubs = 0.5 3.0 4.8 3.0 3.3 3.3 3.1 2.5 1.4 6.2 2.2 6.0 esubs = 2.0 6.3 8.4 8.1 8.4 6.6 6.5 4.6 3.9 10.8 6.0 12.1 esubva = 0.5 4.3 6.0 5.0 4.7 4.8 4.5 3.4 2.3 8.4 3.6 7.8 esubva = 1.5 4.3 6.2 4.9 5.2 4.5 4.4 3.3 2.4 9.1 3.7 8.3 etad = 10 4.1 6.1 4.7 4.9 4.3 4.2 3.0 2.2 9.6 3.5 7.8 etad = 5 4.6 6.3 5.2 5.7 5.0 4.8 3.9 2.7 8.2 4.0 8.8 etadx = 3 3.9 5.6 4.8 4.3 4.3 4.0 2.9 2.3 7.7 3.6 7.5 etadx = 7 4.6 6.6 5.1 5.5 5.0 4.8 3.7 2.4 10.2 3.7 8.7 etaf = 12.5 3.6 5.3 4.2 4.4 3.6 3.7 2.6 1.9 7.6 3.1 7.3 etaf = 17.5 5.0 6.9 5.4 5.8 5.5 5.0 4.0 2.8 10.0 4.2 8.9 sigmadm = 4 4.5 6.4 4.8 5.2 4.9 4.5 3.6 2.5 9.2 3.7 8.4 sigmadm = 2 3.7 5.4 4.7 4.9 3.7 3.8 2.6 1.9 7.8 3.3 7.8 Source: Authors' calculations. Notes: a. The piecemeal sensitivity analysis employs central values for all parameters (see below) other than the tested parameter. Parameter Central Definitions of the parameter (see figures, especially figure 5) value for more precise elasticity structure). esubc 1.25 Elasticity of substitution in consumer demand esubs 1.25 Elasticity of substitution between value-added and business services sigmadm 3 "Armington" elasticity of substitution between imports and domestic goods etaf 15 Elasticity of multinational service firm supply with respect to price of output etad 7.5 Elasticity of Russian service firm supply with respect to price of output esub 3 Elasticity of substitution between firm varieties in imperfectly competitive sectors esubva 1 Elasticity of substitution between primary factors of production in value added etadx 5 Elasticity of transformation (domestic output versus exports) 68 Table 23c. Piecemeal Sensitivity Analysis – Sulphur Dioxide Emissions by Region from WTO Accession (percentage change from base year) Overall Far St. Parameter being changed average Central East North Siberia South Urals Moscow Peters. Tumen Northwest Central Results for reference 6.2 11.2 4.7 7.7 4.1 10.6 9.2 4.5 28.8 3.5 10.1 esubc = 0.5 6.5 11.0 5.1 8.0 4.1 10.5 9.2 5.2 35.5 3.5 10.0 esubc = 1.5 6.2 11.2 4.6 7.6 4.1 10.6 9.2 4.3 28.7 3.5 10.1 esub = 2 5.2 8.8 4.2 6.4 3.6 7.9 7.2 2.9 20.9 3.1 9.7 esub = 4 6.7 11.9 5.1 8.5 4.4 11.7 10.2 5.3 31.9 3.5 10.0 esubs = 0.5 5.7 9.7 4.5 6.9 3.8 9.5 8.9 3.8 25.5 2.3 8.0 esubs = 2.0 7.0 13.7 5.3 9.0 4.5 12.5 9.7 5.8 31.3 5.4 13.8 esubva = 0.5 5.8 10.9 4.1 5.4 3.7 10.6 8.9 4.2 26.4 3.5 9.7 esubva = 1.5 6.4 11.3 5.0 7.9 4.2 10.6 9.4 4.7 29.9 3.5 10.2 etad = 10 6.7 11.8 4.8 8.1 4.4 11.3 10.0 5.0 33.7 3.3 9.5 etad = 5 5.7 10.6 4.8 7.3 3.7 9.8 8.4 3.9 23.0 3.7 11.2 etadx = 3 5.8 9.8 4.3 5.7 4.0 9.4 8.6 4.6 24.9 3.6 8.5 etadx = 7 6.6 12.4 5.2 8.0 4.1 11.7 9.8 4.6 33.6 3.4 11.6 etaf = 12.5 6.1 9.9 5.4 7.7 4.3 9.6 8.7 4.1 25.4 2.9 8.9 etaf = 17.5 6.3 12.3 4.2 7.6 3.8 11.4 9.8 4.9 32.0 4.0 11.0 sigmadm = 4 6.7 11.8 5.1 8.1 4.4 11.4 10.0 5.1 32.1 3.5 10.5 sigmadm = 2 5.4 9.4 4.3 6.9 3.8 8.5 7.8 3.4 22.2 3.1 9.4 Source: Authors' calculations. Notes: a. The piecemeal sensitivity analysis employs central values for all parameters (see below) other than the tested parameter. Parameter Central Definitions of the parameter (see figures, especially figure 5) value for more precise elasticity structure). esubc 1.25 Elasticity of substitution in consumer demand esubs 1.25 Elasticity of substitution between value-added and business services sigmadm 3 "Armington" elasticity of substitution between imports and domestic goods etaf 15 Elasticity of multinational service firm supply with respect to price of output etad 7.5 Elasticity of Russian service firm supply with respect to price of output esub 3 Elasticity of substitution between firm varieties in imperfectly competitive sectors esubva 1 Elasticity of substitution between primary factors of production in value added etadx 5 Elasticity of transformation (domestic output versus exports) 69 Table 23d. Piecemeal Sensitivity Analysis – Nitrogen Oxide Emissions by Region from WTO Accession (percentage change from base year) Overall Far St. Parameter being changed average Central East North Siberia South Urals Moscow Peters. Tumen Northwest Central Results for reference 2.8 3.0 2.9 3.7 2.8 3.6 2.4 1.7 4.6 2.8 6.8 esubc = 0.5 2.8 3.0 3.0 3.8 2.8 3.6 2.4 2.2 3.4 2.8 6.8 esubc = 1.5 2.8 3.0 2.9 3.7 2.8 3.6 2.4 1.5 4.6 2.8 6.8 esub = 2 2.4 2.6 3.1 3.6 2.4 3.1 1.8 1.2 4.6 2.6 6.7 esub = 4 2.9 3.0 2.7 3.7 2.9 3.7 2.6 1.8 4.5 2.8 6.8 esubs = 0.5 1.5 1.7 0.8 1.8 1.7 2.1 1.4 0.7 2.1 1.6 4.5 esubs = 2.0 4.8 5.2 6.5 7.0 4.7 6.0 4.0 3.3 6.9 4.8 11.1 esubva = 0.5 2.8 3.0 2.9 2.6 2.8 3.7 2.5 1.7 4.5 2.9 6.6 esubva = 1.5 2.8 3.0 2.9 3.7 2.8 3.6 2.4 1.7 4.7 2.8 6.9 etad = 10 2.7 3.0 2.6 3.5 2.8 3.5 2.3 1.8 4.8 2.6 6.9 etad = 5 3.0 3.0 3.3 4.0 2.9 3.8 2.7 1.6 4.6 3.2 6.8 etadx = 3 2.7 2.9 2.8 2.5 2.8 3.4 2.4 1.8 4.5 2.9 6.7 etadx = 7 2.9 3.0 3.0 3.8 2.9 3.8 2.5 1.7 4.8 2.8 6.9 etaf = 12.5 2.4 2.5 2.7 3.4 2.5 3.1 2.0 1.4 4.1 2.4 6.2 etaf = 17.5 3.2 3.4 3.0 4.0 3.1 4.0 2.9 2.0 5.1 3.2 7.3 sigmadm = 4 2.9 3.1 2.8 3.7 3.0 3.7 2.6 1.8 4.7 2.9 7.2 sigmadm = 2 2.4 2.5 2.9 3.6 2.4 3.1 1.8 1.3 4.4 2.6 6.3 Source: Authors' calculations. Notes: a. The piecemeal sensitivity analysis employs central values for all parameters (see below) other than the tested parameter. Parameter Central Definitions of the parameter (see figures, especially figure 5) value for more precise elasticity structure). esubc 1.25 Elasticity of substitution in consumer demand esubs 1.25 Elasticity of substitution between value-added and business services sigmadm 3 "Armington" elasticity of substitution between imports and domestic goods etaf 15 Elasticity of multinational service firm supply with respect to price of output etad 7.5 Elasticity of Russian service firm supply with respect to price of output esub 3 Elasticity of substitution between firm varieties in imperfectly competitive sectors esubva 1 Elasticity of substitution between primary factors of production in value added etadx 5 Elasticity of transformation (domestic output versus exports) 70 Table 23e. Piecemeal Sensitivity Analysis – Hydrocarbon Emissions by Region from WTO Accession (percentage change from base year) Overall Far St. Parameter being changed average Central East North Siberia South Urals Moscow Peters. Tumen Northwest Central Results for reference 1.7 2.6 8.6 4.1 2.7 1.8 -0.1 -2.0 4.5 1.9 4.8 esubc = 0.5 1.2 1.1 9.1 3.3 2.3 0.6 -0.6 -3.4 2.8 1.8 3.3 esubc = 1.5 1.9 3.1 8.5 4.4 2.9 2.2 0.1 -1.5 5.3 2.0 5.4 esub = 2 1.8 2.9 7.4 4.2 2.3 2.1 0.4 0.4 5.0 1.8 5.3 esub = 4 1.6 2.4 8.8 4.1 2.8 1.6 -0.4 -3.1 4.3 1.9 4.7 esubs = 0.5 -0.5 -2.1 7.5 0.9 0.4 -1.6 -2.2 -5.7 -2.1 0.7 -1.1 esubs = 2.0 5.2 10.5 10.1 9.5 6.5 7.3 3.1 3.9 11.2 3.9 15.8 esubva = 0.5 1.9 2.8 8.8 3.7 3.1 2.0 0.1 -1.5 4.6 2.0 5.0 esubva = 1.5 1.6 2.5 8.5 4.0 2.6 1.7 -0.2 -2.2 4.4 1.9 4.8 etad = 10 1.2 1.6 8.8 3.5 2.3 0.9 -0.6 -2.7 3.5 1.6 3.9 etad = 5 2.4 4.1 8.5 5.0 3.4 3.0 0.6 -0.8 6.1 2.4 6.4 etadx = 3 1.7 2.4 8.3 3.6 2.7 1.9 0.0 -1.8 4.5 2.0 5.0 etadx = 7 1.7 2.6 9.1 4.1 2.8 1.6 -0.2 -2.3 4.3 1.9 4.5 etaf = 12.5 1.3 2.1 7.4 3.4 1.9 1.3 -0.2 -1.6 3.7 1.6 4.3 etaf = 17.5 2.1 3.0 9.7 4.7 3.5 2.1 0.0 -2.4 5.2 2.2 5.3 sigmadm = 4 1.6 2.5 8.9 4.1 2.7 1.6 -0.4 -3.1 4.4 1.9 5.1 sigmadm = 2 1.8 2.9 7.5 4.1 2.4 2.1 0.4 0.1 4.7 1.8 4.8 Source: Authors' calculations. Notes: a. The piecemeal sensitivity analysis employs central values for all parameters (see below) other than the tested parameter. Parameter Central Definitions of the parameter (see figures, especially figure 5) value for more precise elasticity structure). esubc 1.25 Elasticity of substitution in consumer demand esubs 1.25 Elasticity of substitution between value-added and business services sigmadm 3 "Armington" elasticity of substitution between imports and domestic goods etaf 15 Elasticity of multinational service firm supply with respect to price of output etad 7.5 Elasticity of Russian service firm supply with respect to price of output esub 3 Elasticity of substitution between firm varieties in imperfectly competitive sectors esubva 1 Elasticity of substitution between primary factors of production in value added etadx 5 Elasticity of transformation (domestic output versus exports) 71 Table 23f. Piecemeal Sensitivity Analysis –Particulate Matter Emissions by Region from WTO Accession (percentage change from base year) Overall Far St. Parameter being changed average Central East North Siberia South Urals Moscow Peters. Tumen Northwest Central Results for reference 3.0 2.6 2.5 4.0 2.9 2.9 3.1 1.5 5.9 2.8 5.0 esubc = 0.5 3.0 2.7 2.6 4.2 2.9 3.1 3.1 2.0 6.2 2.8 5.1 esubc = 1.5 3.0 2.6 2.5 3.9 2.9 2.9 3.2 1.3 5.8 2.8 4.9 esub = 2 2.5 2.3 2.8 3.7 2.5 2.5 2.3 1.0 5.1 2.4 5.0 esub = 4 3.1 2.6 2.3 4.1 3.0 3.0 3.4 1.6 6.0 2.9 4.8 esubs = 0.5 2.0 1.4 0.7 2.7 1.9 1.7 2.3 0.5 3.8 2.0 3.0 esubs = 2.0 4.6 4.7 5.8 6.2 4.4 4.9 4.5 3.1 7.7 4.1 8.6 esubva = 0.5 3.0 2.6 2.5 2.9 2.8 3.0 3.2 1.5 5.6 2.8 4.8 esubva = 1.5 3.0 2.6 2.5 4.0 2.9 2.9 3.1 1.5 6.0 2.8 5.0 etad = 10 3.0 2.7 2.3 4.0 2.9 2.9 3.1 1.6 6.4 2.7 5.0 etad = 5 3.1 2.6 3.0 4.1 2.9 3.1 3.3 1.4 5.3 3.0 5.1 etadx = 3 2.9 2.6 2.5 2.9 2.8 2.8 3.1 1.6 5.5 2.9 5.0 etadx = 7 3.1 2.6 2.6 4.1 2.9 3.1 3.3 1.4 6.4 2.8 5.0 etaf = 12.5 2.6 2.2 2.4 3.7 2.6 2.5 2.7 1.2 5.1 2.4 4.5 etaf = 17.5 3.3 3.0 2.6 4.2 3.1 3.3 3.6 1.8 6.5 3.2 5.4 sigmadm = 4 3.2 2.7 2.4 4.1 3.1 3.0 3.5 1.6 6.2 2.9 5.3 sigmadm = 2 2.5 2.2 2.7 3.8 2.5 2.5 2.4 1.1 5.0 2.5 4.6 Source: Authors' calculations. Notes: a. The piecemeal sensitivity analysis employs central values for all parameters (see below) other than the tested parameter. Parameter Central Definitions of the parameter (see figures, especially figure 5) value for more precise elasticity structure). esubc 1.25 Elasticity of substitution in consumer demand esubs 1.25 Elasticity of substitution between value-added and business services sigmadm 3 "Armington" elasticity of substitution between imports and domestic goods etaf 15 Elasticity of multinational service firm supply with respect to price of output etad 7.5 Elasticity of Russian service firm supply with respect to price of output esub 3 Elasticity of substitution between firm varieties in imperfectly competitive sectors esubva 1 Elasticity of substitution between primary factors of production in value added etadx 5 Elasticity of transformation (domestic output versus exports) 72 Table 23g. Piecemeal Sensitivity Analysis –Volatile Organic Components Emissions by Region from WTO Accession (percentage change from base year) Overall Far St. Parameter being changed average Central East North Siberia South Urals Moscow Peters. Tumen Northwest Central Results for reference 2.7 6.2 4.5 2.9 3.0 3.5 1.8 3.8 1.8 2.8 13.3 esubc = 0.5 2.5 5.7 4.1 2.7 2.6 3.3 1.7 3.8 0.0 2.8 12.9 esubc = 1.5 2.7 6.3 4.6 2.9 3.1 3.6 1.9 3.8 1.9 2.8 13.5 esub = 2 2.2 5.7 4.7 2.9 2.3 3.0 1.2 2.0 2.7 2.3 12.1 esub = 4 2.8 6.2 4.3 2.8 3.1 3.6 2.0 4.6 1.4 2.9 14.0 esubs = 0.5 1.9 4.9 2.9 1.8 1.2 2.6 1.0 3.1 -0.7 2.4 11.8 esubs = 2.0 3.8 8.4 7.1 4.6 5.7 5.1 3.1 4.9 3.9 3.3 16.4 esubva = 0.5 2.7 5.8 4.4 2.2 3.1 3.7 2.0 3.1 1.8 2.8 12.8 esubva = 1.5 2.6 6.3 4.5 2.8 2.9 3.5 1.8 4.1 1.8 2.8 13.6 etad = 10 2.5 6.3 4.2 2.6 2.6 3.4 1.7 3.2 1.1 2.7 15.4 etad = 5 2.8 5.8 4.8 3.1 3.5 3.8 2.0 4.5 2.7 2.8 10.9 etadx = 3 2.7 6.3 4.1 2.3 2.7 3.6 1.9 3.3 2.4 2.9 14.3 etadx = 7 2.6 6.0 4.8 2.8 3.3 3.5 1.8 4.4 1.1 2.7 12.6 etaf = 12.5 2.1 5.5 4.0 2.4 2.0 3.0 1.3 2.9 1.6 2.4 12.8 etaf = 17.5 3.1 6.6 4.9 3.2 3.8 4.0 2.3 4.6 1.9 3.1 13.8 sigmadm = 4 2.8 6.5 4.7 2.8 3.1 3.7 1.9 4.5 1.3 2.9 14.5 sigmadm = 2 2.2 5.7 4.2 2.8 2.4 3.1 1.4 2.6 2.6 2.3 11.9 Source: Authors' calculations. Notes: a. The piecemeal sensitivity analysis employs central values for all parameters (see below) other than the tested parameter. Parameter Central Definitions of the parameter (see figures, especially figure 5) value for more precise elasticity structure). esubc 1.25 Elasticity of substitution in consumer demand esubs 1.25 Elasticity of substitution between value-added and business services sigmadm 3 "Armington" elasticity of substitution between imports and domestic goods etaf 15 Elasticity of multinational service firm supply with respect to price of output etad 7.5 Elasticity of Russian service firm supply with respect to price of output esub 3 Elasticity of substitution between firm varieties in imperfectly competitive sectors esubva 1 Elasticity of substitution between primary factors of production in value added etadx 5 Elasticity of transformation (domestic output versus exports) 73 Table 23h. Piecemeal Sensitivity Analysis –Carbon Monoxide Emissions by Region from WTO Accession (percentage change from base year) Overall Far St. Parameter being changed average Central East North Siberia South Urals Moscow Peters. Tumen Northwest Central Results for reference 4.5 17.0 3.5 4.8 3.4 5.8 4.4 9.9 13.6 2.7 9.8 esubc = 0.5 4.5 16.5 3.5 4.9 3.4 5.5 4.4 10.4 14.6 2.7 9.7 esubc = 1.5 4.5 17.2 3.6 4.8 3.4 5.9 4.5 9.7 13.7 2.7 9.8 esub = 2 3.6 13.4 3.5 4.3 3.1 4.5 3.3 6.0 10.8 2.3 9.4 esub = 4 4.8 18.3 3.5 5.2 3.6 6.2 4.9 12.1 14.7 2.8 9.7 esubs = 0.5 3.8 15.5 2.5 3.9 2.9 4.9 3.9 9.8 10.6 2.3 8.0 esubs = 2.0 5.4 19.7 5.5 6.4 4.3 7.2 5.3 10.2 16.1 3.3 12.9 esubva = 0.5 4.3 16.7 3.2 3.4 3.2 5.9 4.4 8.6 12.7 2.7 9.5 esubva = 1.5 4.5 17.2 3.7 4.9 3.5 5.7 4.4 10.5 14.1 2.7 9.9 etad = 10 4.6 18.0 3.3 4.9 3.6 5.9 4.6 10.9 15.4 2.7 9.1 etad = 5 4.3 16.1 4.0 4.8 3.3 5.6 4.3 8.8 11.7 2.8 11.0 etadx = 3 4.3 14.8 3.3 3.6 3.4 5.5 4.3 9.8 12.2 2.8 8.1 etadx = 7 4.7 19.1 3.9 4.9 3.4 6.1 4.6 10.3 15.5 2.6 11.3 etaf = 12.5 4.1 15.2 3.8 4.7 3.5 5.1 3.9 9.4 12.1 2.3 8.6 etaf = 17.5 4.8 18.7 3.3 5.0 3.3 6.3 4.9 10.4 15.1 3.1 10.8 sigmadm = 4 4.8 18.0 3.6 5.0 3.7 6.1 4.8 11.6 14.9 2.8 10.1 sigmadm = 2 3.8 14.5 3.5 4.5 3.1 4.8 3.6 7.1 11.2 2.3 9.1 Source: Authors' calculations. Notes: a. The piecemeal sensitivity analysis employs central values for all parameters (see below) other than the tested parameter. Parameter Central Definitions of the parameter (see figures, especially figure 5) value for more precise elasticity structure). esubc 1.25 Elasticity of substitution in consumer demand esubs 1.25 Elasticity of substitution between value-added and business services sigmadm 3 "Armington" elasticity of substitution between imports and domestic goods etaf 15 Elasticity of multinational service firm supply with respect to price of output etad 7.5 Elasticity of Russian service firm supply with respect to price of output esub 3 Elasticity of substitution between firm varieties in imperfectly competitive sectors esubva 1 Elasticity of substitution between primary factors of production in value added etadx 5 Elasticity of transformation (domestic output versus exports) 74 Figures Figure 1. Demand for Representative CRTS good g in Region r Armington Aggregate Demand for CRTS good g in RM r CES σ = sigmadm a/ Russia goods Rest of World Imports CES σ = 1.5 * sigmadm Own Regional Market Other Russian Imports CES σ = 2 * sigmadm Imports from Imports from Imports from Regional Market 1 Regional Market q Regional Market m a/ sigmadm = 3 in CRTS sectors, except in OTH (other goods producing sectors). For OTH we rely on estimates from Ivanova (2005). 75 Figure 2. Demand for Representative Dixit-Stiglitz (IRTS) good g in Regional Market r Dixit-Stiglitz Aggregate of IRTS good g in RMr CES a/ σ = 3 = esub Imports of g from Goods g from Goods g from Goods g from Rest of World RM q RM 1 RM m CES CES CES CES σ =3 σ =3 σ =3 σ = 3 = esub Rest of World firms Firms in RM m Firms in RM 1 Firms in RM q selling g in RMr selling g in RM selling g in RMr selling g in RM a/ We take σ = 3, except based on Ivanova (2005), we take σ = 3.1 in MWO; σ = 2.6 in TPP; σ = 2.5 in CNM; and σ = 1.8 in OTI. 76 Figure 3. Demand for Representative Business Service s (Dixit-Stiglitz) Sectors in Regional Market (RM) m Business Service s CES σ =1, 5 Rest of World Own Regional Market Services Cross Border Services CES σ =3 = esub Multinational Service Russian Service Providers in RM m Providers in RM m CES σ =3 = esub CES σ =3 = esub Multinational firms in RMm Russian firms from RMm 77 Figure 4. Sales for Constant Returns to Scale Sectors: Determined by Constant Elasticity of Transformation Production Structure Russia sales Oblast r sales (not oblast r) Rest of world sales σT = 5 CET Output (CRTS good g in Oblast r) *The elasticity of transformation is equal to 4 in crude oil, natural gas and coal; otherwise 5. 78 Figure 5: Structure of Production (other than fossil fuels) Leontief σ= 0 Composite of Value-added (incl. Business Services) and Energy Composite of Other Goods and Services Leontief CES σ = 0.5 σ=0 Coal Other …. Other Good and Service Good and Service Value-added and Business Services Energy Composite CES σ = 1.25 Cobb-Douglas σ=1 Business Services …. Value-added Electricity Cobb-Douglas Gas-Oil Composite Cobb-Douglas σ=1 σ=1 Business Service …. Business Sector Capital Unskilled Skilled CES σ =3 Service Specific Labor Labor Resources GAS OIL (refined) 79 Figure 6: Structure of Production in fossil fuels 80 Figure 7: CO2 emissions across sectors and final demand (label “c”) for 2001 (in million tons of CO2) 400 350 300 250 200 150 100 50 0 HEA FME COL CON CRU TPP SCI OTI AGR TRK OTH ELE GAS trd PIP c TRO TMS OIL HOU AIR NFM FIN CNM RLW CLI PST MWO CHM FOO MAR 81 Figure 8: Base-year CO2 emission intensities from fossil fuel combustion (direct) and indirect emissions from electricity inputs (ELE) (in kg per ruble)* 0.9 direct ELE 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 HEA CON FME TPP OTI SCI CRU COL AGR TRD OTH ELE TRK TRO c TMS GAS mean all PIP NFM OIL HOU AIR FIN RLW CLI PST CNM MWO CHM MAR FOO * Key: mean – average across all sectors; all – average across all sectors including final consumption; c – final consumption 82 Figure 9: Base-year pollution intensities – other than CO2 (in grams per ruble) 83 Figure 10: Energy cost shares across industries 84 Appendix: Environmental Database of the Model: Documentation of the Sources and Construction A.1. Non-CO2 emission accounting 1.1. The environmental component of the data for the WTO model consists of emissions of seven air pollutants: PM, SO2, CO, NOx, CnHm, VOC, and CO2, which constitute the most commonly observed source of air pollution in the Russian Federation (Table A1). Data on non-CO2 emissions comes from the SUST-RUS database, which in turn relies on several publications of the government of Russia as explained below. The CO2 emission accounting is based on fuel-specific emission intensity and is discussed in part 0. Table A1. Pollutants (p) in the model Pollutant Abbreviation Environmental impacts Health effects Particulate Soiling and damage to Lung cancer, asthma, PM matter materials, smog birth defects Acid rain, atmospheric Asthmatic, alterations Sulphur dioxide SO2 particulates in the lungs Leads to increased Carbon Headache, nausea, CO concentrations of methane monoxide dizziness, seizures and tropospheric ozone Difficulty breathing, Acid rain, eutrophication Nitrogen oxide NOx fluid build-up in the in coastal waters lungs Smog, leads to increased Affects the central Hydrocarbons CnHm concentrations of nervous system tropospheric ozone Volatile organic Damage to soil and Damage to liver, VOC components groundwater cancer, headaches High concentration: Climate change, ocean Carbon dioxide CO2 rapid heart rate, acidification clumsiness Source: SUST-RUS 2012(a); EPA: Health Effects of Air Pollution 85 1.2. The SUST-RUS database contains data on air pollution for 32 industries of 7 Federal Districts of the Russian Federation in year 2006. The industry list (s) is presented in Table A2, while set of regions (r) (Federal Districts) is presented in Table A3. 1.3. Total emissions of non-CO2 pollutants ( ∈ 2 , ℎ 2 = {, 2 , , , , }) by industries at national level (, ) are presented in Table A4. These are data for year 2006, by industry and type of pollutant from industrial stationary and mobile sources in thousands of tons. The main source of these data is Ministry of Natural Resources and Environment of the Russian Federation (2007). 1.4. Aggregate regional emissions by the type of non-CO2 pollutants (, ) are presented in Table A5. 1.5. Non-CO2 pollution is assumed to be process-based and varies with output. Values of industrial output in the SUST-RUS database (, ) by Federal Districts of the RF, measured in millions of rubles of 2006, are presented in Table A6. Sources of values of industrial output in the SUST-RUS database are discussed in SUST-RUS (2012c, 3.1.5 Regional output statistics): “The origin of the regional output data is the Rosstat online database,” available at: (http://www.gks.ru/dbscripts/Cbsd/DBInet.cgi). 1.6. The authors calculate an emission intensity index of non-CO2 pollutants ( ∈ 2 ) at the regional level (,, ) for the SUST-RUS pollution data. It is estimated according to an output-weighted least-squares procedure (Equation 1), subject to total regional emissions (Equation 2) and national sectoral emissions (Equation 3). The procedure ensures that emissions by pollutant, sector, and region are close to average national sectoral emissions intensity index ( �, ), deviating from the mean for more polluted regions proportionally with regional output (, ). Equation 1 2 �, � , subject to min,, ∑∈2 ,, , ∗ �,, − Equation 2 � ,, ∗ , = , Equation 3 � ,, ∗ , = , 1.7. The average national sectoral emissions intensity index ( �, ) for the SUST-RUS data is presented in Table A7, measured in thousand tons of pollutant per trillion rubles of output, in nominal prices of 2006. 1.8. The resulting regional emissions intensity indices of non-CO2 emissions ( ∈ 2 ) at the regional level (,, ) for the SUST-RUS sectoral classification are presented in Table A9 - Table A14. 1.9. The model’s (“the WTO model’s”) sectoral and regional lists differ from those of SUST-RUS. The industry list (g) of the WTO model is presented in Table A15, while set of regions (reg) of the WTO model is presented in 86 1.10. Table A16. 1.11. The concordance ((, )) between the WTO model industry list (g) and the SUST-RUS industries (s) is presented in Table A17. We do not have a one to one mapping between the WTO model industry list and the SUST-RUS industry list. Differences in the underlying industry classifications are fundamental, as the model’s (“the WTO model”) industry list is based on the old Russian OKONH classification, which is production process-centric; but the SUST-RUS industry classification is based on the standard international industry classification (ISIC/NACE or, the Russian version, OKVED), which is activity-centric. In the presence of classification differences, the authors establish a many-to-one mapping from the WTO model industry list to the SUST-RUS list. For each industry from the WTO model industry list there is a corresponding industry from SUST-RUS’s list. There are several WTO industries that maps to the same SUST-RUS industry. For example, there is only one SUST-RUS industry that corresponds to transport services I_trn, which is defined as an aggregate of all of the following types of transport services: land transport; transport via pipelines; water transport; air transport; supporting and auxiliary transport activities; activities of travel agencies. The WTO model’ industry list is very detailed in transport services: there are six different industries related to transport services: maritime transportation (MAR), railway transportation (RLW), truck transportation (TRK), pipeline transportation (PIP), air transportation (AIR), and other transportation (TRO). According to our mapping, all six types of transport services in the WTO model are mapped to one type of transport services in the SUST-RUS dataset. The concordance ((, )) doesn’t use every SUST-RUS industry, only those which are associated with any of the WTO model’s industries. Only 20 out of 32 SUST-RUS industries are used in the mapping. In the case, when SUST-RUS is more detailed in representing certain production sectors than the WTO model, only one industry from the SUST-RUS’s industry list is chosen to represent the WTO-model industry. For example, there are two sectors of light industry “Manufacture of textiles and textile products” (DB) and “Manufacture of leather and leather products” (DC) in the SUST-RUS industry list, but there is only one industry “Textiles and apparel” (CLI) in the WTO model. In this case, the concordance ((, )) associates “Textiles and apparel” (CLI) from the WTO model only with “Manufacture of textiles and textile products” (DB) of the SUST-RUS list, leaving “Manufacture of leather and leather products” (DC) industry unused in the concordance. 1.12. The mapping ((, )) between the WTO models regions list (reg) and the SUST-RUS regions (r) is presented in Table A18. A detailed list of all the WTO model’s regions and Federal Districts of the Russian Federation is presented in Table A19. 1.13. The geographical mapping ((, )) between the WTO model’s regions list (reg) and the SUST-RUS regions (r) is many to one, since the WTO model’s regions list is more detailed than the list of SUST-RUS. There is no exact mapping between Federal Districts regional division used in the SUST-RUS database and ten geographical regions of the WTO model. The authors examine the sensitivity of the results to the regional mapping. 1.14. The model’s dataset is based on the 2001 Russian Input-output data. The emission data are based on 2006 data of the SUST-RUS database and should be scaled to match the total emission level of 2001. Values of emissions by different types of non-CO2 pollutants for 2001 ( 2001 ) are presented in Table A20. 1.15. The adjusted regional emission intensity index of non-CO2 emissions in the WTO model region and sector list (,, ) is calculated in three steps. In the first step (Equation 4) the regional emission intensity index of non-CO2 emissions in 0 the WTO model (,, ) is set to equal to values of the regional emission 87 intensity index of non-CO2 emissions in the SUST-RUS data (,, ) for those SUST-RUS industries (s) and regions (r) that correspond with the WTO model industries (g) and regions (reg). For example, the initial value of regional emission intensity index of SO2 (Sulphur dioxide) emissions for the WTO-model industry 0 ELE (“Electricity”) in region MSC (“Moscow”) (2 , , ) is equal to the value of SUST-RUS emissions intensity index of SO2 (Sulphur dioxide) for SUST- RUS industry E_ely (Production and distribution of electricity) in the region reg1 (“Central Federal District”) (X SO2,E_ely,reg1 ) . Equation 4 ∀ ∈ 2 ∀ ∈ ∀ ∈ , 0 ,, = ,, , (, ) ∈ (, ) (, ) ∈ (, ). 1.16. In the second stage (Equation 5), authors calculate the adjustment coefficient 2001 ( ) to rescale reference values of total emissions in 2001 ( ). For each pollutant (p), adjustment coefficient (k ) equals ratio of total volume of emissions of 2001 the pollutant (p) in 2001 ( ) and estimated volume of emissions with initial values of regional emission intensity index of non-CO2 emissions in the WTO model. Estimated volume of emissions equals to product of initial values of regional 0 emission intensity index of non-CO2 emissions in the WTO model � ,, � 2001 and 2001 production levels ( , ). Equation 5 2001 = 0 2001 ∑ ∑ ,, ∗ , 1.17. In the final, third stage of estimation of the adjusted regional emission intensity index of non-CO2 (,, ), the adjustment coefficient is applied to initial values of the intensity index (emitint 0 p,g,reg ) (Equation 6). Equation 6 0 ,, = ∗ ,, 1.18. Values of regional emission intensity index of non-CO2 emissions in the WTO model region and sector list (,, ) are presented in Table A21-Table A30. 1.19. Average regional emissions intensity index of non-CO2 emissions, WTO model's sectoral classification (thousands tons of emission per billion of 2001 rubles of output) is presented in Table A31. 88 A.2. CO2 emissions accounting 1.20. CO2 emissions are generated by fossil fuel combustion. There are three types of fossil fuels (ff) in the model: fluid (natural gas), solid (coal), and liquid (oil). Based on the input-output tables, the model contains data at the sector and region level of how intensively each sector in each region uses each fossil fuel; that is, we have the cost share of each fossil fuel for each sector and region. We lack, however, detailed data on differences in emission intensity across sectors and regions for a given value of fossil fuel use. Due to lack of detailed data on CO2 emissions intensity per ruble of expenditure on fossil fuel, by industry and regional level, aggregated data for CO2 emissions for each type of fuel in 2001 was used for emission intensity per ruble of expenditure. We assume that all sectors and regions that spend 1 billion rubles on a given fossil fuel, will emit the same amount of CO2. Differences in CO2 emissions per ruble of output in the WTO model are therefore only due to the differences in the intensity of fossil fuel use across sectors and regions, not due to the efficiency with which a sector in a given region controls its emission of CO2. 1.21. Aggregated CO2 emissions for 2001 for each type of fuel (SRCO22001 ff ) is presented in Table A32. The source of CO2 emission data in year 2001 is Rosgidromet (2013, page 36, Table A3.3). 1.22. CO2 emission intensity index (2 ) for a fuel (ff) is defined as total CO2 emissions of this type of fuel (measured in billions of tons, also called gigatons) divided by total demand for this type of fuel (in billions of rubles of 2001). More specifically, let 0,, equal demand for a particular fossil fuel by a given sector in one of the model’s regions in billions of 2001 rubles. The CO2 emission intensity index (2 ) is presented in Equation 7: it equals ratio of aggregated CO2 emissions by a specific type of fuel ( SRCO22001 ff ) and total value of fossil fuels demand in 2001 aggregated over regions and sectors, in billions of 2001 rubles. Equation 7 2001 2 2 = ∑ ∑ 0,, 1.23. Values of CO2 emission intensity index (2 ) are presented in Table A33. 1.24. See figures 7 and 8 for emissions intensity at the sector level in our model. These figures combine the emission intensities of Table A33, with the different cost shares of fossil fuels across sectors based on the input-output tables. Since our regional input-output tables exhibit identical cost shares for a given sector across our ten regions, the national average for CO2 emission intensity of a sector applies to all ten regions. Appendix References 1. SUST-RUS. 2012(a). Deliverable 2.2: The spatial-economic-environmental database for the model, SUST-RUS project web site, accessed at May 28, 2014, http://sust-rus.org/wp-content/uploads/2010/08/regionalsam_sust-rus.xls 89 2. EPA: Health Effects of Air Pollution, accessed at May 28, 2014, http://www.epa.gov/region7/air/quality/health.htm . 3. Ministry of Natural Resources and Environment of the Russian Federation. 2007. State Report On the State of Environmental Protection in the Russian Federation in 2006 (in Russian), accessed at May 28, 2014, http://www.mnr.gov.ru/regulatory/list.php?part=1269 4. SUST-RUS. 2012 (b). SUST-RUS Deliverable 5: Description of the environmental, international and social part of the model, SUST-RUS project web site, accessed at May 28, 2014, http://sust-rus.org/wp- content/uploads/2012/03/d5-description-of-the-environmental-international-and- social-part-of-the-model.pdf 5. Rosgidromet. 2013. State inventory report of anthropogenic emissions by sources and removals by sinks of greenhouse gases not controlled by the Montreal Protocol for 1990 - 2011 years, Part 1, Moscow 2013. 6. SUST-RUS. 2012 (c). SUST-RUS Deliverable 2.1: Description of the constructed database, data quality and data collection methods, SUST-RUS project web site, accessed at May 28, 2014,http://sust-rus.org/wp- content/uploads/2010/08/deliverable-2.pdf 90 Table A2. The industry list of the SUST-RUS database. # Code in SUST- NACE Description RUS classification 1 A Section A Agriculture, hunting and forestry 2 B Section B Fishing 3 CA_col CA.10 Mining of coal and lignite; extraction of peat 4 CA_gas CA.11.10.2-3 Extraction of natural gas; service activities incidental to gas extraction, excluding surveying 5 CA_oil CA.11.10.1 Extraction of crude petroleum; service activities incidental to oil extraction, excluding surveying 6 CB Subsection CB Mining and quarrying, except of energy producing materials 7 DA Subsection DA Manufacture of food products, beverages and tobacco 8 DB Subsection DB Manufacture of textiles and textile products 9 DC Subsection DC Manufacture of leather and leather products 10 DD Subsection DD Manufacture of wood and wood products 11 DE Subsection DE Manufacture of pulp, paper and paper products; publishing and printing 12 DF Subsection DF Manufacture of coke, refined petroleum products and nuclear fuel 13 DG Subsection DG Manufacture of chemicals, chemical products and man-made fibres 14 DH Subsection DH Manufacture of rubber and plastic products 15 DI Subsection DI Manufacture of other non-metallic mineral products 91 # Code in SUST- NACE Description RUS classification 16 DJ Subsection DJ Manufacture of basic metals and fabricated metal products 17 DK Subsection DK Manufacture of machinery and equipment n.e.c. 18 DL Subsection DL Manufacture of electrical and optical equipment 19 DM Subsection DM Manufacture of transport equipment 20 DN Subsection DN Manufacturing n.e.c. 21 E_distr 41 + 40.2 + 40.3 Collection, purification and distribution of water; Manufacture of gas; distribution of gaseous fuels through mains; Steam and hot water supply 22 E_ely 40.1 Production and distribution of electricity 23 F Section F Construction 24 G Section G Wholesale and retail trade; repair of motor vehicles, motorcycles and personal and household goods 25 H Section H Hotels and restaurants 26 I_cmn 64 Post and telecommunications 27 I_trn 60 + 61 + 62 + 63 Land transport; transport via pipelines; Water transport; Air transport; Supporting and auxiliary transport activities; activities of travel agencies 28 J Section J Financial intermediation 29 LO Section L and O Public administration and defense; compulsory social security; Other community, social and personal service activities 30 K Section K Real estate, renting and business activities 92 # Code in SUST- NACE Description RUS classification 31 M Section M Education 32 N Section N Health and social work Source: SUST-RUS. 2012(a). Table A3. Regions of the SUST-RUS model Region number Federal Districts of the Russian Federation Reg1 Central Federal District Reg2 North-Western Federal District Reg3 Southern Federal District Reg4 Volga Federal District Reg5 Urals Federal District Reg6 Siberian Federal District Reg7 Far Eastern Federal District Source: SUST-RUS. 2012(a). 93 Table A4. Total emissions in 2006, by industry and by type of pollutant from industrial stationary and mobile sources (thousands of tons) Particulate Sulphur Carbon Nitrogen Hydrocarb Volatile organic matter dioxide monoxide oxide ons components PM SO2 CO NOx CnHm VOC A Agriculture, hunting and forestry 38,60 7,30 44,50 8,90 7,50 3,40 B Fishing - - - - - - CA_col Mining of coal and lignite; extraction of peat 60,60 13,50 39,20 12,50 776,20 1,00 CA_gas Extraction of natural gas; service activities 27,30 8,58 257,05 8,29 104,88 67,30 incidental to gas extraction, excluding surveying CA_oil Extraction of crude petroleum; service activities 244,10 84,14 2 236,38 74,02 508,25 984,70 incidental to oil extraction, excluding surveying CB Mining and quarrying, except of energy producing 138,10 101,60 235,00 34,00 1,90 5,20 materials DA Manufacture of food products, beverages and 25,90 20,90 63,20 16,90 1,40 10,70 tobacco DB Manufacture of textiles and textile products 3,20 2,20 5,80 2,00 0,10 0,50 DC Manufacture of leather and leather products 1,40 1,83 0,06 0,18 - 0,03 DD Manufacture of wood and wood products 17,00 3,90 54,10 5,40 0,10 3,10 DE Manufacture of pulp, paper and paper products; 46,60 47,00 39,20 22,90 0,30 4,80 publishing and printing 94 Particulate Sulphur Carbon Nitrogen Hydrocarb Volatile organic matter dioxide monoxide oxide ons components PM SO2 CO NOx CnHm VOC DF Manufacture of coke, refined petroleum products 27,20 132,64 136,33 32,17 65,40 328,66 and nuclear fuel DG Manufacture of chemicals, chemical products and 40,40 44,10 124,70 40,50 16,00 76,70 man-made fibres DH Manufacture of rubber and plastic products 1,30 0,40 2,90 1,60 1,50 9,30 DI Manufacture of other non-metallic mineral 215,80 20,30 144,60 82,20 1,40 8,70 products DJ Manufacture of basic metals and fabricated metal 369,60 2 642,10 1 585,80 133,80 2,60 14,20 products DK Manufacture of machinery and equipment n.e.c. 22,80 10,50 41,60 14,80 0,60 9,90 DL Manufacture of electrical and optical equipment 7,00 5,10 28,10 5,50 1,20 5,60 DM Manufacture of transport equipment 18,90 13,80 41,90 11,90 1,80 25,00 DN Manufacturing n.e.c. 7,20 0,90 7,50 1,40 0,20 2,80 E_distr Collection, purification and distribution of water; 316,40 260,80 407,40 161,00 27,50 4,20 Manufacture of gas; distribution of gaseous fuels through mains; Steam and hot water supply E_ely Production and distribution of electricity 956,80 1 165,90 173,10 801,70 3,20 3,70 95 Particulate Sulphur Carbon Nitrogen Hydrocarb Volatile organic matter dioxide monoxide oxide ons components PM SO2 CO NOx CnHm VOC F Construction - - - - - - G Wholesale and retail trade; repair of motor vehicles, motorcycles and personal and household goods H Hotels and restaurants - - - - - - I_cmn Post and telecommunications - - - - - - I_trn Land transport; transport via pipelines; Water 222,40 86,69 439,20 183,10 1 258,30 123,00 transport; Air transport; Supporting and auxiliary transport activities; activities of travel agencies J Financial intermediation - - - - - - LO Public administration and defense; compulsory 7,00 3,40 9,70 1,60 33,10 3,40 social security; Other community, social and personal service activities K Real estate, renting and business activities 20,97 87,10 168,01 45,14 13,20 49,38 M Education - - - - - - N Health and social work - - - - - - Source: SUST-RUS. 2012(a), 2012 (b). 96 Table A5. Regional Emissions by type of the Pollutant in 2006 Volatile Particulate Sulphur Carbon Nitrogen Hydrocarbons organic matter dioxide monoxide oxide components Federal Districts of the Russian Federation PM SO2 CO NOx CnHm VOC FD1-Central Central Federal District 232,7 214,5 583 267,9 125,6 108,9 FD2-Northwest North-West Federal District 290,4 590,2 685 170,5 409,3 134,4 FD3-South South Federal District 90,4 140,8 265,5 122,1 173,2 81,9 FD4-Volga Volga Federal District 229,5 508,4 885,3 289,2 589,4 518,5 FD5-Urals Urals Federal District 878,5 579,3 2653,9 413,8 868,7 873,6 FD6-Siberian Siberian Federal District 811,7 2536,3 1051,4 339,8 651,4 134,2 FD7-FarEast Far Eastern Federal District 309,8 195,3 214,2 99,8 9 11,7 Source: SUST-RUS. 2012(a), 2012 (b). 97 Table A6. Regional and sectoral output (mln RUB, 2006) Federal Districts of the Russian Federation FD1-Central FD2-Northwest FD3-South FD4-Volga FD5-Urals FD6-Siberian FD7-FarEast A 368 289,00 96 458,00 367 871,00 436 079,00 131 192,00 249 916,00 61 477,00 B 640,00 44 306,63 5 026,23 342,42 839,74 366,88 81 536,60 CA_col 106 709,18 127 135,77 38 986,57 14 094,12 70 582,45 267 696,51 80 650,42 CA_gas 5 053,99 13 390,99 145 773,25 1 327 768,23 836,14 1 306,07 CA_oil 25 511,08 8 165,33 476 401,42 580 550,49 1 542,35 1 797,04 CB 78 199,59 56 836,94 7 024,68 32 771,35 48 643,37 58 861,64 146 917,68 DA 654 896,22 298 465,22 207 019,12 266 014,91 80 567,66 169 907,16 51 000,78 DB 72 004,30 11 781,52 11 829,66 23 244,02 4 648,13 5 480,88 1 152,56 DC 13 715,10 1 309,06 2 218,06 2 582,67 1 549,38 1 370,22 288,14 DD 44 574,09 49 744,20 4 436,12 23 244,02 13 944,40 26 034,16 4 610,24 DE 168 010,02 108 651,81 14 787,08 51 653,38 9 296,27 34 255,48 3 601,75 DF 651 467,44 53 671,38 122 732,76 550 108,50 342 412,54 206 903,07 12 101,88 DG 216 012,89 81 161,60 48 797,36 309 920,28 26 339,43 79 472,70 2 881,40 DH 96 005,73 15 708,70 14 787,08 90 393,42 13 944,40 23 293,72 2 305,12 DI 229 727,99 64 143,84 56 190,90 92 976,08 71 271,39 45 217,23 11 669,67 DJ 404 595,57 301 083,34 121 993,41 286 676,26 718 911,39 565 900,45 17 288,40 98 Federal Districts of the Russian Federation FD1-Central FD2-Northwest FD3-South FD4-Volga FD5-Urals FD6-Siberian FD7-FarEast DK 229 727,99 66 761,96 46 579,30 136 881,46 79 018,28 54 808,76 7 491,64 DL 250 300,65 100 797,47 21 441,27 129 133,45 48 030,72 47 957,67 4 610,24 DM 205 726,56 111 269,93 49 536,72 529 447,15 58 876,36 53 438,54 17 432,47 DN 192 011,46 44 507,97 17 005,14 90 393,42 80 567,66 56 178,98 7 635,71 E_distr 432 695,86 143 469,33 80 757,51 205 916,99 173 817,13 127 188,46 58 543,97 E_ely 232 554,23 58 182,54 89 847,66 204 195,36 94 444,54 144 957,49 55 949,09 F 858 498,82 437 818,94 283 882,31 426 834,45 371 505,35 261 617,21 210 678,51 G 4 143 285,55 517 927,98 424 564,12 672 835,63 996 788,33 439 567,72 194 754,17 H 160 374,23 38 580,21 46 359,91 52 744,21 61 517,44 36 329,59 16 935,51 I_cmn 164 244,23 65 355,58 50 751,75 80 429,06 95 905,87 68 781,08 32 450,74 I_trn 1 105 512,87 439 902,43 341 605,38 541 360,64 645 533,61 462 959,17 218 084,60 J 1 026 038,75 47 232,14 17 687,30 52 634,57 154 513,13 24 930,87 11 386,42 LO 1 140 675,07 378 710,68 315 226,85 436 068,27 362 382,77 389 550,13 229 126,93 K 1 697 320,66 308 834,91 188 960,73 419 435,41 588 173,66 259 078,32 122 454,11 M 240 250,04 103 744,17 89 169,03 148 128,27 116 202,90 129 762,60 58 811,29 N 363 523,35 171 676,78 135 007,83 203 868,61 200 703,92 187 389,36 78,25 Source: SUST-RUS. 2012(a), 2012 (c). 99 Table A7. Average pollution intensity by sector in SUST-RUS 2006 data (thousands tons of emission per trillion RUB of output) Volatile Carbon Particula Sulphur Nitrogen Hydrocar organic monoxid te matter dioxide oxide bons compone e nts PM SO2 CO NOx CnHm VOC A Agriculture, hunting and forestry 22,56 4,27 26,00 5,20 4,38 1,99 CA_col Mining of coal and lignite; extraction of peat 85,85 19,13 55,54 17,71 1 099,66 1,42 Extraction of natural gas; service activities incidental to gas 18,27 5,74 172,04 5,55 70,20 45,04 CA_gas extraction, excluding surveying Extraction of crude petroleum; service activities incidental to 223,13 76,91 2 044,28 67,66 464,59 900,12 CA_oil oil extraction, excluding surveying CB Mining and quarrying, except of energy producing materials 321,72 236,69 547,46 79,21 4,43 12,11 DA Manufacture of food products, beverages and tobacco 14,99 12,10 36,58 9,78 0,81 6,19 DB Manufacture of textiles and textile products 24,59 16,91 44,57 15,37 0,77 3,84 DC Manufacture of leather and leather products 60,78 79,45 2,61 7,82 1,30 DD Manufacture of wood and wood products 102,05 23,41 324,76 32,42 0,60 18,61 Manufacture of pulp, paper and paper products; publishing 119,41 120,43 100,45 58,68 0,77 12,30 DE and printing DF Manufacture of coke, refined petroleum products and nuclear 14,03 68,39 70,30 16,59 33,72 169,47 100 Volatile Carbon Particula Sulphur Nitrogen Hydrocar organic monoxid te matter dioxide oxide bons compone e nts PM SO2 CO NOx CnHm VOC fuel Manufacture of chemicals, chemical products and man-made 52,84 57,68 163,10 52,97 20,93 100,32 DG fibres DH Manufacture of rubber and plastic products 5,07 1,56 11,31 6,24 5,85 36,27 DI Manufacture of other non-metallic mineral products 377,80 35,54 253,15 143,91 2,45 15,23 DJ Manufacture of basic metals and fabricated metal products 152,95 1 093,38 656,25 55,37 1,08 5,88 DK Manufacture of machinery and equipment n.e.c. 36,70 16,90 66,96 23,82 0,97 15,94 DL Manufacture of electrical and optical equipment 11,62 8,47 46,66 9,13 1,99 9,30 DM Manufacture of transport equipment 18,43 13,45 40,85 11,60 1,76 24,37 DN Manufacturing n.e.c. 14,75 1,84 15,36 2,87 0,41 5,73 Collection, purification and distribution of water; Manufacture of gas; distribution of gaseous fuels through mains; Steam and 258,84 213,35 333,28 131,71 22,50 3,44 E_distr hot water supply E_ely Production and distribution of electricity 1 087,11 1 324,69 196,68 910,89 3,64 4,20 I_trn Land transport; transport via pipelines; Water transport; Air 59,23 23,09 116,97 48,76 335,10 32,76 101 Volatile Carbon Particula Sulphur Nitrogen Hydrocar organic monoxid te matter dioxide oxide bons compone e nts PM SO2 CO NOx CnHm VOC transport; Supporting and auxiliary transport activities; activities of travel agencies Public administration and defense; compulsory social security; 2,15 1,05 2,98 0,49 10,18 1,05 LO Other community, social and personal service activities K Real estate, renting and business activities 5,85 24,30 46,87 12,60 3,68 13,78 Source: Authors’ calculations based on SUST-RUS data 102 Table A8. Regional emissions intensity index of non-CO2 emissions, Central Federal District, SUST-RUS sectoral classification (thousands tons of emission per trillion nominal RUB of output of 2006) Volatile Carbon Nitrogen Particulate Sulphur Central FD Hydrocarbons organic monoxide oxide matter dioxide components CnHm CO NOx PM SO2 VOC CA_col 829,19 CB 457,13 15,03 DB 6,72 DD 258,62 DE 33,35 20,66 DF 6,12 131,39 DG 186,49 12,09 71,17 DH 10,80 DI 220,37 102,78 170,32 DJ 572,40 194,46 E_distr 305,73 85,05 4,84 E_ely 146,34 859,92 821,11 584,03 I_trn 33,58 28,91 Source: Authors’ calculations based on SUST-RUS data 103 Table A9. Regional emissions intensity index of non-CO2 emissions, North-Western Federal District, SUST-RUS sectoral classification (thousands tons of emission per trillion nominal RUB of output of 2006) Volatile North- Carbon Nitrogen Particulate Sulphur Hydrocarbons organic Western FD monoxide oxide matter dioxide components CnHm CO NOx PM SO2 VOC A 44,55 5,96 CA_col 1 302,67 34,77 1,45 1,93 CA_gas 46,17 170,18 616,60 43,11 CA_oil 446,27 2 269,31 60,46 287,39 709,08 945,20 CB 610,48 83,16 297,77 59,68 29,28 DA 77,93 13,62 16,61 DB 160,06 44,14 62,25 17,76 DC 18,91 202,21 101,47 DD 411,96 39,09 103,34 32,78 DE 186,70 88,79 247,82 63,61 29,58 DF 37,61 159,46 21,21 236,19 DG 17,79 339,84 80,22 117,92 175,96 DH 16,34 6,01 115,60 104 Volatile North- Carbon Nitrogen Particulate Sulphur Hydrocarbons organic Western FD monoxide oxide matter dioxide components CnHm CO NOx PM SO2 VOC DI 373,71 170,91 637,47 37,38 DJ 725,74 49,83 111,93 1 353,18 6,28 DK 152,86 38,27 10,22 40,02 DL 111,94 10,87 25,46 DM 138,03 28,76 88,91 DN 8,76 12,57 E_distr 25,86 459,08 153,18 471,99 346,59 7,11 E_ely 299,68 928,05 1 288,26 1 742,76 10,91 I_trn 507,05 182,26 62,77 11,16 62,06 K 102,30 11,47 35,39 LO 4,86 1,14 Source: Authors’ calculations based on SUST-RUS data 105 Table A10. Regional emissions intensity index of non-CO2 emissions, Southern Federal District, SUST-RUS sectoral classification (thousands tons of emission per trillion nominal RUB of output of 2006) Southern Carbon Nitrogen Particulate Sulphur Volatile organic Hydrocarbons FD monoxide oxide matter dioxide components CnHm CO NOx PM SO2 VOC CA_col 1 162,63 CA_gas 106,02 32,62 CA_oil 306,23 2 205,15 36,52 934,71 CB 546,32 59,23 18,79 DA 13,77 6,12 DB 95,91 20,20 7,28 DD 347,81 15,15 22,29 DE 122,54 64,86 19,10 DF 95,31 225,70 DG 275,68 56,28 165,48 DH 105,11 DI 309,56 146,97 198,80 26,90 DJ 661,59 25,89 499,40 DK 88,71 14,33 29,53 DL 47,79 14,98 106 Southern Carbon Nitrogen Particulate Sulphur Volatile organic Hydrocarbons FD monoxide oxide matter dioxide components CnHm CO NOx PM SO2 VOC DM 73,87 4,83 78,42 DN 2,09 E_distr 394,92 129,25 33,32 E_ely 235,53 904,12 849,59 888,98 I_trn 367,02 118,10 38,83 51,57 K 38,15 24,90 Source: Authors’ calculations based on SUST-RUS data 107 Table A11. Regional emissions intensity index of non-CO2 emissions, Volga Federal District, SUST-RUS sectoral classification (thousands tons of emission per trillion nominal RUB of output of 2006) Carbon Nitrogen Particulate Sulphur Volatile organic Volga FD Hydrocarbons monoxide oxide matter dioxide components Row Labels CnHm CO NOx PM SO2 VOC A 4,09 CA_col 1 317,14 CA_gas 60,63 20,85 CA_oil 460,73 1 727,42 33,13 113,33 833,40 CB 5,11 68,59 55,84 DB 16,81 DD 11,76 DE 61,47 DF 52,08 124,38 DG 32,26 52,89 64,16 DH 8,56 3,80 DI 0,49 143,58 258,74 DJ 183,86 22,50 757,44 DK 10,94 DL 0,62 108 Carbon Nitrogen Particulate Sulphur Volatile organic Volga FD Hydrocarbons monoxide oxide matter dioxide components Row Labels CnHm CO NOx PM SO2 VOC DM 0,87 1,43 E_distr 40,33 125,86 93,25 E_ely 1,30 900,73 909,53 1 147,02 I_trn 521,52 35,44 K 2,92 LO 19,33 Source: Authors’ calculations based on SUST-RUS data 109 Table A12. Regional emissions intensity index of non-CO2 emissions, Urals Federal District, SUST-RUS sectoral classification (thousands tons of emission per trillion nominal RUB of output of 2006) Carbon Nitrogen Particulate Sulphur Volatile organic Urals FD Hydrocarbons monoxide oxide matter dioxide components CnHm CO NOx PM SO2 VOC A 15,57 65,95 26,10 40,63 13,02 CA_col 1 328,62 56,16 37,68 89,11 8,99 CA_gas 72,11 191,57 6,24 20,41 50,17 CA_oil 472,21 2 290,71 96,69 405,09 13,35 952,26 CB 16,59 631,87 119,39 415,46 36,34 DA 6,18 99,32 49,86 36,97 23,67 DB 10,34 181,46 80,37 179,95 24,82 DC 55,14 319,91 14,28 DD 3,07 433,36 75,32 221,04 39,84 DE 7,57 208,09 125,02 365,52 36,64 DF 63,56 180,86 57,44 23,59 243,25 DG 43,74 361,23 116,45 235,62 183,02 DH 20,04 37,74 42,24 122,66 DI 11,97 395,11 207,14 755,17 44,44 DJ 2,41 747,14 86,06 229,62 657,45 13,34 110 Carbon Nitrogen Particulate Sulphur Volatile organic Urals FD Hydrocarbons monoxide oxide matter dioxide components CnHm CO NOx PM SO2 VOC DK 4,84 174,26 74,50 127,92 47,08 DL 12,10 133,34 47,11 35,99 32,52 DM 12,35 159,43 64,99 109,04 95,97 DN 1,82 30,16 11,96 21,20 19,63 E_distr 51,81 480,48 189,42 589,69 14,17 E_ely 12,78 321,08 964,29 1 405,96 1 047,03 17,97 I_trn 533,00 203,65 99,00 128,86 69,12 K 14,40 123,70 47,70 42,45 LO 30,81 4,30 8,20 Source: Authors’ calculations based on SUST-RUS data 111 Table A13. Regional emissions intensity index of non-CO2 emissions, Siberian Federal District, SUST-RUS sectoral classification (thousands tons of emission per trillion nominal RUB of output of 2006) Volatile Carbon Nitrogen Particulate Sulphur Siberian FD Hydrocarbons organic monoxide oxide matter dioxide components Row Labels CnHm CO NOx PM SO2 VOC A 14,70 119,10 21,91 103,40 29,21 4,47 CA_col 1 327,75 109,31 33,49 151,88 50,43 0,45 CA_gas 71,24 244,72 83,18 1 700,75 41,63 CA_oil 471,34 2 343,85 92,50 467,86 1 793,23 943,72 CB 15,72 685,02 115,21 478,23 1 143,84 27,80 DA 5,31 152,47 45,67 99,74 123,01 15,13 DB 9,47 234,60 76,18 242,72 401,40 16,28 DC 43,79 50,95 382,68 1 185,63 5,74 DD 2,20 486,51 71,13 283,81 149,80 31,30 DE 6,70 261,24 120,84 428,29 1 147,77 28,10 DF 62,69 234,01 53,26 86,36 641,07 234,71 DG 42,87 414,38 112,26 298,39 554,91 174,48 DH 19,17 90,88 38,05 49,22 17,17 114,12 DI 11,10 448,26 202,95 817,94 448,94 35,90 112 Volatile Carbon Nitrogen Particulate Sulphur Siberian FD Hydrocarbons organic monoxide oxide matter dioxide components Row Labels CnHm CO NOx PM SO2 VOC DJ 1,54 800,28 81,87 292,39 2 437,34 4,80 DK 3,97 227,40 70,31 190,69 191,58 38,54 DL 11,23 186,48 42,92 98,76 106,34 23,98 DM 11,48 212,57 60,81 171,81 258,24 87,42 DN 0,95 83,30 7,77 83,97 16,02 11,09 E_distr 50,94 533,62 185,23 652,46 1 430,74 5,63 E_ely 11,91 374,22 960,10 1 468,73 2 826,92 9,43 I_trn 532,13 256,80 94,81 191,63 187,25 60,58 K 13,53 176,84 43,51 49,37 336,19 33,91 LO 29,94 24,90 0,11 4,87 8,73 Source: Authors’ calculations based on SUST-RUS data 113 Table A14. Regional emissions intensity index of non-CO2 emissions, Far Eastern Federal District, SUST-RUS sectoral classification (thousands tons of emission per trillion nominal RUB of output of 2006) Volatile Far Eastern Carbon Nitrogen Particulate Sulphur Hydrocarbons organic FD monoxide oxide matter dioxide components Row Labels CnHm CO NOx PM SO2 VOC A 29,05 120,80 CA_col 111,59 19,27 8,56 169,28 CA_gas 154,67 100,58 767,10 CA_oil 2 253,81 67,57 485,26 859,58 907,98 CB 594,97 90,28 495,63 210,19 DA 62,43 20,74 117,14 DB 144,56 51,25 260,12 DC 400,08 251,98 DD 396,46 46,20 301,20 DE 171,20 95,91 445,68 214,12 DF 143,96 28,33 103,75 198,97 DG 324,34 87,33 315,78 138,74 DH 13,12 66,61 78,38 DI 358,21 178,02 835,34 114 Volatile Far Eastern Carbon Nitrogen Particulate Sulphur Hydrocarbons organic FD monoxide oxide matter dioxide components Row Labels CnHm CO NOx PM SO2 VOC DJ 710,24 56,94 309,79 1 503,69 DK 137,36 45,38 208,08 2,80 DL 96,44 17,99 116,15 DM 122,53 35,87 189,21 51,69 DN 101,37 E_distr 443,58 160,30 669,85 497,09 E_ely 284,18 935,17 1 486,13 1 893,27 I_trn 166,76 69,88 209,03 24,84 K 86,80 18,58 66,77 LO 22,27 Source: Authors’ calculations based on SUST-RUS data 115 Table A15. List of sectors in the WTO model Code Description ELE "Electricity" CRU "Oil" OIL "Oil processing" GAS "Gas" COL "Coal" FME "Ferrous metals" NFM "Non-ferrous metals" CHM "Chemical and petrochemical products" MWO "Machinery" TPP "Forestry - wood - pulp -paper" CNM "Construction materials" OTI "Other industrial products" CLI "Textiles and apparel" FOO "Food industry" AGR "Agricultural products" MAR "Maritime transportation (*)" RLW "Railway transportation (*)" TRK "Truck transportation (*)" 116 Code Description PIP "Pipelines transportation (*)" AIR "Air transportation (*)" TRO "Other transportation (*)" TRD "Wholesale and retail trade" CON "Construction" TMS "Telecommunications (*)" PST "Post (*)" OTH "Other goods and services" HOU "Housing and other communal services" HEA "Public health, sports, social security, education, culture and arts" SCI "Science, geology, mineral exploration, geodesy and hydrometeorology " FIN "Financial intermediaries, insurance, management and public organizations" Source: Authors’ mapping based on the Russian input-output table of 2001. See the main text for details. 117 Table A16. Regions of the WTO model Regions Name of the macro-region msc "Moscow" stp "Saint-Petersburg" tmn "Tumenskaya region" vgd "Northwest" nor "North" cen "Central" sou "South" url "Urals and near east" sib "Siberia" far "Far East" Source: Authors’ mapping, see table 2 of the Tables section. 118 Table A17. Concordance between WTO model industry list (g) and the SUST-RUS industries (s) WTO sector SUST-RUS sector Description ELE E_ely "Electricity" CRU CA_oil "Oil" OIL DF "Oil processing" GAS CA_gas "Gas" COL CA_col "Coal" FME DJ "Ferrous metals" NFM DJ "Non-ferrous metals" CHM DG "Chemical and petrochemical products" MWO DK "Machinery" TPP A "Forestry - wood - pulp -paper" CNM DI "Construction materials" OTI DN "Other industrial products" CLI DB "Textiles and apparel" FOO DA "Food industry" AGR A "Agricultural products" MAR I_trn "Maritime transportation (*)" RLW I_trn "Railway transportation (*)" TRK I_trn "Truck transportation (*)" 119 WTO sector SUST-RUS sector Description PIP I_trn "Pipelines transportation (*)" AIR I_trn "Air transportation (*)" TRO I_trn "Other transportation (*)" TRD G "Wholesale and retail trade" CON F "Construction" TMS I_cmn "Telecommunications (*)" PST I_cmn "Post (*)" OTH DN "Other goods and services" HOU K "Housing and other communal services" HEA N "Public health, sports, social security, education, culture and arts" SCI M "Science, geology, mineral exploration, geodesy and hydrometeorology " "Financial intermediaries, insurance, management and public FIN J organizations" /; Source: Authors’ estimations 120 Table A18. Mapping between WTO model regions list (reg) and the SUST-RUS regions (r) Regional code in the RUS- Regions of the SUST-RUS model Name of the macro-region ENV (WTO model) msc FD1-Central "Moscow" stp FD2-Northwest "Saint-Petersburg" tmn FD5-Urals "Tumenskaya region" vgd FD4-Volga "Northwest" nor FD2-Northwest "North" cen FD1-Central "Central" sou FD3-South "South" url FD5-Urals "Urals and near east" sib FD6-Siberian "Siberia" far FD7-FarEast "Far East" Source: Authors’ estimations Table A19. Detailed list of subjects of the Russian Federation corresponding to WTO 10-regions macro-regions and Federal Districts of the Russian Federation (coincides with regional division in the SUST-RUS model) Subject of the Russian WTO 10- WTO subj SR FD Federal District Russian Name Federation reg code of RF code code 121 Subject of the Russian WTO 10- WTO subj SR FD Federal District Russian Name Federation reg code of RF code code Central Federal District Moscow Oblast msc msk г. Москва reg1 Central Federal District Moscow msc mos Московская область reg1 Central Federal District Belgorod Region cen bel Белгородская область reg1 Central Federal District Bryansk Region cen bry Брянская область reg1 Central Federal District Vladimir Region cen vla Владимирская область reg1 Central Federal District Voronezh Region cen vor Воронежская область reg1 Central Federal District Ivanovo Region cen iva Ивановская область reg1 Central Federal District Kaluga Region cen kal Калужская область reg1 Central Federal District Kostroma Region cen kos Костромская область reg1 Central Federal District Kursk Region cen krs Курская область reg1 Central Federal District Lipetsk Region cen lip Липецкая область reg1 Central Federal District Oryol Region cen orl Орловская область reg1 Central Federal District Ryazan Region cen rya Рязанская область reg1 Central Federal District Smolensk Region cen smo Смоленская область reg1 Central Federal District Tambov Region cen tam Тамбовская область reg1 Central Federal District Tver Region cen tve Тверская область reg1 Central Federal District Tula Region cen tul Тульская область reg1 Central Federal District Yaroslavl Region cen yar Ярославская область reg1 122 Subject of the Russian WTO 10- WTO subj SR FD Federal District Russian Name Federation reg code of RF code code North-West Federal District Vologda Region vgd vol Вологодская область reg2 North-West Federal District Kaliningrad Region vgd klg Калининградская область reg2 North-West Federal District Novgorod Region vgd nov Новгородская область reg2 North-West Federal District Pskov Region vgd psk Псковская область reg2 North-West Federal District Republic of Karelia nor krl Республика Карелия reg2 North-West Federal District Komi Republic nor kom Республика Коми reg2 North-West Federal District Arkhangelsk Region nor arh Архангельская область reg2 North-West Federal District Murmansk Region nor mur Мурманская область reg2 North-West Federal District Leningrad Region stp len Ленинградская область reg2 123 Subject of the Russian WTO 10- WTO subj SR FD Federal District Russian Name Federation reg code of RF code code North-West Federal District St. Petersburg stp spb г. Санкт-Петербург reg2 South Federal District Republic of Adygea sou ady Республика Адыгея reg3 South Federal District Republic of Kalmykia sou klr Республика Калмыкия reg3 South Federal District Krasnodar Krai sou kdk Краснодарский край reg3 South Federal District Astrakhan Region sou ast Астраханская область reg3 South Federal District Volgograd Region sou vlg Волгоградская область reg3 South Federal District Rostov Region sou ros Ростовская область reg3 South Federal District Dagestan Republic sou dag Республика Дагестан reg3 South Federal District Republic of Ingushetia sou ing Республика Ингушетия reg3 South Federal District Kabardino-Balkar Republic sou kab Кабардино-Балкарская Республика reg3 South Federal District KarachayÐCherkessia sou kar Карачаево-Черкесская Республика reg3 Republic of North Ossetia- Республика Северная Осетия - South Federal District Alania sou sev Алания reg3 South Federal District Chechen Republic reg3 South Federal District Stavropol Krai sou sta Ставропольский край reg3 Volga Federal District Saratov Region sou sar Саратовская область reg4 Volga Federal District Republic of Bashkortostan url bas Республика Башкортостан reg4 124 Subject of the Russian WTO 10- WTO subj SR FD Federal District Russian Name Federation reg code of RF code code Volga Federal District Republic of Mari El url mar Республика Марий Эл reg4 Volga Federal District Republic of Mordovia url mor Республика Мордовия reg4 Volga Federal District Republic of Tatarstan url tat Татарстан reg4 Volga Federal District Udmurt Republic url udm Удмуртская Республика reg4 Volga Federal District Chuvash Republic url chv Чувашская Республика reg4 Volga Federal District Perm Krai url per Пермская область reg4 Volga Federal District Kirov Region url kir Кировская область reg4 Volga Federal District Nizhny Novgorod Region url niz Нижегородская область reg4 Volga Federal District Orenburg Region url ore Оренбургская область reg4 Volga Federal District Penza Region url pen Пензенская область reg4 Volga Federal District Samara Region url sam Самарская область reg4 Volga Federal District Ulyanovsk Region url ulo Ульяновская область reg4 Ural Federal District Kurgan Region url krg Курганская область reg5 Ural Federal District Sverdlovsk Region url sve Свердловская область reg5 Ural Federal District Chelyabinsk Region url chl Челябинская область reg5 Ural Federal District Tyumen Region tmn tum Тюменская область reg5 Siberian Federal District Altai Republic sib alr Республика Алтай reg6 Siberian Federal District Republic of Buryatia sib bur Республика Бурятия reg6 125 Subject of the Russian WTO 10- WTO subj SR FD Federal District Russian Name Federation reg code of RF code code Siberian Federal District Republic of Tuva sib tyv Республика Тыва reg6 Siberian Federal District Republic of Khakassia sib hak Республика Хакасия reg6 Siberian Federal District Altai Krai sib alt Алтайский край reg6 Siberian Federal District Krasnoyarsk Krai sib kra Красноярский край reg6 Siberian Federal District Kemerovo Region sib kem Кемеровская область reg6 Siberian Federal District Novosibirsk Region sib nvs Новосибирская область reg6 Siberian Federal District Omsk Region sib oms Омская область reg6 Siberian Federal District Tomsk Region sib tom Томская область reg6 Siberian Federal District Irkutsk Region sib irk Иркутская область reg6 Trans-Baikal Krai (Zabaikalskii Siberian Federal District Krai) far chi Читинская область reg6 Far East Federal District Republic of Sakha (Yakutia) sib sah Республика Саха (Якутия) reg7 Far East Federal District Kamchatka sib kam Камчатская область reg7 Far East Federal District Magadan Region sib mag Магаданская область reg7 Far East Federal District Chukotka Autonomous District sib chu Чукотский автономный округ reg7 Far East Federal District Primorsky Krai far pri Приморский край reg7 Far East Federal District Khabarovsk Krai far hab Хабаровский край reg7 Far East Federal District Amur Region far amu Амурская область reg7 126 Subject of the Russian WTO 10- WTO subj SR FD Federal District Russian Name Federation reg code of RF code code Far East Federal District Sakhalin Region far sao Сахалинская область reg7 Far East Federal District Jewish Autonomous Region far eao Еврейская автономная область reg7 Source: Authors’ estimations Table A20. Total emissions in 2001 and 2006, by type of pollutant from industrial stationary (thousands tons) Pollutant Abbreviation 2001 2006 Particulate matter PM 2 973,20 2 836,60 Sulphur dioxide SO2 5 254,00 4 764,70 Carbon monoxide CO 5 148,00 6 285,30 Nitrogen oxide NOx 1 678,90 1 701,50 Hydrocarbons CnHm 2 723,60 2 826,60 Volatile organic components VOC 1 130,80 1 745,30 Source: Ministry of Natural Resources and Environment of the Russian Federation (2007). 127 Table A21. Regional emissions intensity index of non-CO2 emissions, North-west region, WTO model's sectoral classification (thousands tons of emission per billion 2001 RUB of output) Carbon Nitrogen Particulate Sulphur Volatile organic "Northwest" Hydrocarbons monoxide oxide matter dioxide components Row Labels CnHm CO NOx PM SO2 VOC MAR 1 639,63 68,44 AGR 12,86 AIR 1 639,63 68,44 CHM 101,41 102,15 77,72 CLI 32,47 CNM 1,53 277,30 509,68 col 4 141,01 CRU 1 448,52 2 882,35 63,98 257,36 1 009,50 ELE 4,09 1 739,56 1 791,64 2 604,70 FME 306,78 43,46 1 720,03 gas 190,62 47,35 HOU 9,18 MWO 21,13 NFM 306,78 43,46 1 720,03 oil 163,73 150,67 128 PIP 1 639,63 68,44 RLW 1 639,63 68,44 TPP 12,86 TRK 1 639,63 68,44 TRO 1 639,63 68,44 Source: Authors’ estimations Table A22. Regional emissions intensity index of non-CO2 emissions, Urals and Near East region, WTO model's sectoral classification (thousands tons of emission per billion 2001 RUB of output) "Urals and Carbon Nitrogen Particulate Sulphur Volatile organic Hydrocarbons near east" monoxide oxide matter dioxide components Row Labels CnHm CO NOx PM SO2 VOC MAR 1 675,72 339,81 191,19 253,84 83,73 AGR 48,95 110,05 50,40 80,04 15,77 AIR 1 675,72 339,81 191,19 253,84 83,73 CHM 137,51 602,75 224,89 464,13 221,70 CLI 32,52 302,78 155,22 354,48 30,07 CNM 37,62 659,28 400,05 1 487,57 53,83 129 "Urals and Carbon Nitrogen Particulate Sulphur Volatile organic Hydrocarbons near east" monoxide oxide matter dioxide components Row Labels CnHm CO NOx PM SO2 VOC col 4 177,10 93,72 72,77 175,54 10,89 CRU 1 484,61 3 822,24 186,73 797,97 30,31 1 153,48 ELE 40,19 535,75 1 862,30 2 769,54 2 377,65 21,77 FME 7,57 1 246,67 166,21 452,33 1 492,98 16,16 FOO 19,43 165,73 96,28 72,83 28,67 gas 226,72 319,66 12,06 40,20 60,77 HOU 45,27 206,40 92,12 51,42 MWO 15,22 290,77 143,88 251,98 57,02 NFM 7,57 1 246,67 166,21 452,33 1 492,98 16,16 oil 199,82 301,78 110,94 46,46 294,65 OTH 5,72 50,33 23,09 41,77 23,78 OTI 5,72 50,33 23,09 41,77 23,78 PIP 1 675,72 339,81 191,19 253,84 83,73 RLW 1 675,72 339,81 191,19 253,84 83,73 TPP 48,95 110,05 50,40 80,04 15,77 TRK 1 675,72 339,81 191,19 253,84 83,73 130 "Urals and Carbon Nitrogen Particulate Sulphur Volatile organic Hydrocarbons near east" monoxide oxide matter dioxide components Row Labels CnHm CO NOx PM SO2 VOC TRO 1 675,72 339,81 191,19 253,84 83,73 Source: Authors’ estimations 131 Table A23. Regional emissions intensity index of non-CO2 emissions, Tumenskaya region, WTO model's sectoral classification (thousands tons of emission per billion 2001 RUB of output) Volatile "Tumenskaya Carbon Nitrogen Particulate Sulphur Hydrocarbons organic region" monoxide oxide matter dioxide components Row Labels CnHm CO NOx PM SO2 VOC MAR 1 675,72 339,81 191,19 253,84 83,73 AGR 48,95 110,05 50,40 80,04 15,77 AIR 1 675,72 339,81 191,19 253,84 83,73 CHM 137,51 602,75 224,89 464,13 221,70 CLI 32,52 302,78 155,22 354,48 30,07 CNM 37,62 659,28 400,05 1 487,57 53,83 col 4 177,10 93,72 72,77 175,54 10,89 CRU 1 484,61 3 822,24 186,73 797,97 30,31 1 153,48 ELE 40,19 535,75 1 862,30 2 769,54 2 377,65 21,77 FME 7,57 1 246,67 166,21 452,33 1 492,98 16,16 FOO 19,43 165,73 96,28 72,83 28,67 gas 226,72 319,66 12,06 40,20 60,77 HOU 45,27 206,40 92,12 51,42 MWO 15,22 290,77 143,88 251,98 57,02 132 Volatile "Tumenskaya Carbon Nitrogen Particulate Sulphur Hydrocarbons organic region" monoxide oxide matter dioxide components Row Labels CnHm CO NOx PM SO2 VOC NFM 7,57 1 246,67 166,21 452,33 1 492,98 16,16 oil 199,82 301,78 110,94 46,46 294,65 OTH 5,72 50,33 23,09 41,77 23,78 OTI 5,72 50,33 23,09 41,77 23,78 PIP 1 675,72 339,81 191,19 253,84 83,73 RLW 1 675,72 339,81 191,19 253,84 83,73 TPP 48,95 110,05 50,40 80,04 15,77 TRK 1 675,72 339,81 191,19 253,84 83,73 TRO 1 675,72 339,81 191,19 253,84 83,73 Source: Authors’ estimations 133 Table A24. Regional emissions intensity index of non-CO2 emissions, Saint-Petersburg region, WTO model's sectoral classification (thousands tons of emission per billion 2001 RUB of output) Volatile "Saint- Carbon Nitrogen Particulate Sulphur Hydrocarbons organic Petersburg" monoxide oxide matter dioxide components Row Labels CnHm CO NOx PM SO2 VOC MAR 1 594,15 304,11 121,22 21,99 75,17 AGR 74,34 7,21 AIR 1 594,15 304,11 121,22 21,99 75,17 CHM 55,94 567,05 154,92 232,28 213,14 CLI 267,08 85,24 122,63 21,52 CNM 623,58 330,07 1 255,73 45,28 col 4 095,53 58,01 2,80 2,34 CRU 1 403,05 3 786,54 116,76 566,12 1 610,21 1 144,93 ELE 500,05 1 792,33 2 537,69 3 957,55 13,22 FME 1 210,96 96,23 220,48 3 072,88 7,61 FOO 130,03 26,31 20,12 gas 145,15 283,95 1 400,20 52,22 HOU 170,70 22,14 42,86 MWO 255,07 73,90 20,13 48,47 134 Volatile "Saint- Carbon Nitrogen Particulate Sulphur Hydrocarbons organic Petersburg" monoxide oxide matter dioxide components Row Labels CnHm CO NOx PM SO2 VOC NFM 1 210,96 96,23 220,48 3 072,88 7,61 oil 118,25 266,08 40,97 286,10 OTH 14,62 15,23 OTI 14,62 15,23 PIP 1 594,15 304,11 121,22 21,99 75,17 RLW 1 594,15 304,11 121,22 21,99 75,17 TPP 74,34 7,21 TRK 1 594,15 304,11 121,22 21,99 75,17 TRO 1 594,15 304,11 121,22 21,99 75,17 Source: Authors’ estimations 135 Table A25. Regional emissions intensity index of non-CO2 emissions, South region, WTO model's sectoral classification (thousands tons of emission per billion 2001 RUB of output) Volatile Carbon Nitrogen Particulate Sulphur "South" Hydrocarbons organic monoxide oxide matter dioxide components Row Labels CnHm CO NOx PM SO2 VOC MAR 1 153,88 197,06 74,99 62,47 AIR 1 153,88 197,06 74,99 62,47 CHM 460,00 108,70 200,44 CLI 160,03 39,02 8,81 CNM 516,53 283,85 391,61 32,58 col 3 655,26 CRU 962,77 3 679,49 70,53 1 132,22 ELE 393,00 1 746,10 1 673,57 2 018,74 FME 1 103,92 50,01 1 134,07 FOO 22,98 7,41 gas 176,90 39,51 HOU 63,65 30,16 MWO 148,02 27,68 35,77 NFM 1 103,92 50,01 1 134,07 136 Volatile Carbon Nitrogen Particulate Sulphur "South" Hydrocarbons organic monoxide oxide matter dioxide components Row Labels CnHm CO NOx PM SO2 VOC oil 159,03 273,39 OTH 2,53 OTI 2,53 PIP 1 153,88 197,06 74,99 62,47 RLW 1 153,88 197,06 74,99 62,47 TRK 1 153,88 197,06 74,99 62,47 TRO 1 153,88 197,06 74,99 62,47 Source: Authors’ estimations 137 Table A26. Regional emissions intensity index of non-CO2 emissions, Siberia region, WTO model's sectoral classification (thousands tons of emission per billion 2001 RUB of output) Volatile Carbon Nitrogen Particulate Sulphur "Siberia" Hydrocarbons organic monoxide oxide matter dioxide components Row Labels CnHm CO NOx PM SO2 VOC MAR 1 672,99 428,49 183,11 377,49 425,22 73,38 AGR 46,22 198,72 42,32 203,69 66,33 5,42 AIR 1 672,99 428,49 183,11 377,49 425,22 73,38 CHM 134,77 691,43 216,81 587,78 1 260,11 211,35 CLI 29,78 391,46 147,13 478,13 911,51 19,72 CNM 34,89 747,95 391,96 1 611,22 1 019,49 43,49 col 4 174,37 182,39 64,68 299,18 114,52 0,54 CRU 1 481,88 3 910,92 178,65 921,61 4 072,17 1 143,13 ELE 37,45 624,43 1 854,22 2 893,18 6 419,51 11,43 FME 4,83 1 335,34 158,12 575,97 5 534,84 5,82 FOO 16,69 254,40 88,20 196,48 279,33 18,32 gas 223,98 408,33 163,85 3 862,16 50,42 HOU 42,54 295,08 84,03 97,25 763,44 41,07 MWO 12,48 379,44 135,79 375,62 435,04 46,68 138 Volatile Carbon Nitrogen Particulate Sulphur "Siberia" Hydrocarbons organic monoxide oxide matter dioxide components Row Labels CnHm CO NOx PM SO2 VOC NFM 4,83 1 335,34 158,12 575,97 5 534,84 5,82 oil 197,09 390,46 102,86 170,11 1 455,78 284,30 OTH 2,99 139,00 15,01 165,42 36,38 13,44 OTI 2,99 139,00 15,01 165,42 36,38 13,44 PIP 1 672,99 428,49 183,11 377,49 425,22 73,38 RLW 1 672,99 428,49 183,11 377,49 425,22 73,38 TPP 46,22 198,72 42,32 203,69 66,33 5,42 TRK 1 672,99 428,49 183,11 377,49 425,22 73,38 TRO 1 672,99 428,49 183,11 377,49 425,22 73,38 Source: Authors’ estimations 139 Table A27. Regional emissions intensity index of non-CO2 emissions, North region, WTO model's sectoral classification (thousands tons of emission per billion 2001 RUB of output) Volatile Carbon Nitrogen Particulate Sulphur "North" Hydrocarbons organic monoxide oxide matter dioxide components Row Labels CnHm CO NOx PM SO2 VOC MAR 1 594,15 304,11 121,22 21,99 75,17 AGR 74,34 7,21 AIR 1 594,15 304,11 121,22 21,99 75,17 CHM 55,94 567,05 154,92 232,28 213,14 CLI 267,08 85,24 122,63 21,52 CNM 623,58 330,07 1 255,73 45,28 col 4 095,53 58,01 2,80 2,34 CRU 1 403,05 3 786,54 116,76 566,12 1 610,21 1 144,93 ELE 500,05 1 792,33 2 537,69 3 957,55 13,22 FME 1 210,96 96,23 220,48 3 072,88 7,61 FOO 130,03 26,31 20,12 gas 145,15 283,95 1 400,20 52,22 HOU 170,70 22,14 42,86 MWO 255,07 73,90 20,13 48,47 140 Volatile Carbon Nitrogen Particulate Sulphur "North" Hydrocarbons organic monoxide oxide matter dioxide components Row Labels CnHm CO NOx PM SO2 VOC NFM 1 210,96 96,23 220,48 3 072,88 7,61 oil 118,25 266,08 40,97 286,10 OTH 14,62 15,23 OTI 14,62 15,23 PIP 1 594,15 304,11 121,22 21,99 75,17 RLW 1 594,15 304,11 121,22 21,99 75,17 TPP 74,34 7,21 TRK 1 594,15 304,11 121,22 21,99 75,17 TRO 1 594,15 304,11 121,22 21,99 75,17 Source: Authors’ estimations 141 Table A28. Regional emissions intensity index of non-CO2 emissions, Moscow region, WTO model's sectoral classification (thousands tons of emission per billion 2001 RUB of output) Volatile Carbon Nitrogen Particulate Sulphur "Moscow" Hydrocarbons organic monoxide oxide matter dioxide components Row Labels CnHm CO NOx PM SO2 VOC MAR 105,56 48,24 AIR 105,56 48,24 CHM 311,18 23,34 86,20 CLI 11,21 CNM 367,70 198,49 335,51 col 2 606,94 ELE 244,18 1 660,75 1 617,47 1 326,25 FME 955,09 441,58 NFM 955,09 441,58 oil 10,21 159,16 PIP 105,56 48,24 RLW 105,56 48,24 TRK 105,56 48,24 TRO 105,56 48,24 142 Source: Authors’ estimations Table A29. Regional emissions intensity index of non-CO2 emissions, Far East region, WTO model's sectoral classification (thousands tons of emission per billion 2001 RUB of output) Volatile Carbon Nitrogen Particulate Sulphur "Far East" Hydrocarbons organic monoxide oxide matter dioxide components Row Labels CnHm CO NOx PM SO2 VOC MAR 278,25 134,96 411,75 30,09 AGR 48,48 237,96 AIR 278,25 134,96 411,75 30,09 CHM 541,18 168,66 622,05 168,06 CLI 241,22 98,98 512,39 CNM 597,71 343,81 1 645,49 col 350,85 32,15 16,54 333,45 CRU 3 760,67 130,50 955,88 1 951,99 1 099,84 ELE 474,18 1 806,07 2 927,45 4 299,33 FME 1 185,10 109,97 610,24 3 414,66 FOO 104,16 40,05 230,75 gas 258,09 198,12 1 741,98 143 Volatile Carbon Nitrogen Particulate Sulphur "Far East" Hydrocarbons organic monoxide oxide matter dioxide components Row Labels CnHm CO NOx PM SO2 VOC HOU 144,84 35,88 131,52 MWO 229,20 87,64 409,89 3,39 NFM 1 185,10 109,97 610,24 3 414,66 oil 240,22 54,71 204,38 241,01 OTH 199,68 OTI 199,68 PIP 278,25 134,96 411,75 30,09 RLW 278,25 134,96 411,75 30,09 TPP 48,48 237,96 TRK 278,25 134,96 411,75 30,09 TRO 278,25 134,96 411,75 30,09 Source: Authors’ estimations 144 Table A30. Regional emissions intensity index of non-CO2 emissions, Central region, WTO model's sectoral classification (thousands tons of emission per billion 2001 RUB of output) Volatile Carbon Nitrogen Particulate Sulphur "Central" Hydrocarbons organic monoxide oxide matter dioxide components Row Labels CnHm CO NOx PM SO2 VOC MAR 105,56 48,24 AIR 105,56 48,24 CHM 311,18 23,34 86,20 CLI 11,21 CNM 367,70 198,49 335,51 col 2 606,94 ELE 244,18 1 660,75 1 617,47 1 326,25 FME 955,09 441,58 NFM 955,09 441,58 oil 10,21 159,16 PIP 105,56 48,24 RLW 105,56 48,24 TRK 105,56 48,24 TRO 105,56 48,24 145 Source: Authors’ estimations Table A31. Average regional emissions intensity index of non-CO2 emissions, WTO model's sectoral classification (thousands tons of emission per billion 2001 RUB of output) Average Volatile Carbon Nitrogen Particulate Sulphur Russian Hydrocarbons organic monoxide oxide matter dioxide region components Row Labels CnHm CO NOx PM SO2 VOC MAR 1 259,33 270,18 131,83 180,23 62,74 59,51 AGR 22,01 67,42 21,48 62,69 10,22 5,77 AIR 958,96 213,96 96,35 130,02 50,04 44,49 CHM 78,64 490,39 147,82 270,51 143,46 174,89 CLI 11,62 172,03 70,91 173,05 106,77 12,39 CNM 13,39 519,00 295,47 863,74 96,84 25,95 col 3 693,30 145,83 52,08 265,96 84,97 0,86 CRU 1 423,09 3 808,23 173,39 725,07 195,00 1 150,30 ELE 19,21 432,92 1 781,79 2 313,84 2 806,44 10,04 FME 3,67 1 044,61 98,21 261,25 1 745,68 7,57 FOO 5,24 82,52 32,17 46,23 29,45 10,77 gas 219,65 316,29 11,53 40,39 45,97 59,89 146 Average Volatile Carbon Nitrogen Particulate Sulphur Russian Hydrocarbons organic monoxide oxide matter dioxide region components Row Labels CnHm CO NOx PM SO2 VOC HOU 17,54 116,01 37,98 16,61 92,62 25,14 MWO 7,13 185,72 80,41 148,30 28,42 33,16 NFM 4,58 1 276,13 143,69 483,98 4 010,49 7,64 oil 129,97 248,84 71,43 58,89 251,99 265,18 OTH 2,76 41,29 11,56 46,63 5,08 13,15 OTI 1,38 19,66 5,73 20,79 2,09 7,14 PIP 1 349,39 286,83 145,06 194,62 44,78 65,77 RLW 1 121,30 242,15 114,19 155,81 61,85 51,76 TPP 17,71 77,95 16,65 59,85 10,73 6,09 TRK 1 083,34 236,05 110,72 149,12 52,92 50,75 TRO 1 075,02 233,86 109,74 146,82 49,96 50,42 Source: Authors’ estimations 147 Table A32. Total CO2 emissions from combustion of fossil fuels in 2001, Gigatons (Gt). Abbreviation Type of fossil fuel WTO model Rosgidromet data Oil Liquid fuel 0,35 0,33 Gaz Fluid fossil fuel 0,75 0,74 Col Solid fossil fuels 0,31 0,31 Source: Authors’ estimations and Rosgidromet (2013Table A). Table A33. CO2 emission intensities from combustion of fossil fuels in 2001, Gt/bln RUB 2001 Abbreviation Type of fossil fuel WTO model Oil Liquid fossil fuel 8,20E-04 Gaz Fluid fossil fuel 9,98E-03 Col Solid fossil fuels 4,46E-03 Source: Authors’ estimations 148