C)PIS1t/9 POLICY RESEARCH WORKING PAPER 1477 Cities Without Land How do the spatial dynamics of the socialist city compare M arkets with those of the market city? What happens to a city when all investment decisions are Location and Land Use aeihulnmrts made without land markets? in the Socialist City What are the outcomes when the forces described by Alain Bertaud familiar urban models are not Bertrand Renaud allowed to work? The World Bank Transportation, Water, and Urban Development Department Transport Division and Financial Sector Development Department June 1995 I POLICY RESEARCH WORKING PAPER 1477 Summary findings Bertaud and Renaud describe the structure of Russian distant suburbs. Such a structure tends to maximize the cities after 70 years of Soviet development. This is the economic and social inefficiency of the socialist city as longest socialist experience on record and its results are well as its environmental ill effects. of paramount interest to urban economists. With market-oriented urban reform, real estate prices In the absence of price signals and of economic are now emerging. Their negative gradient signals again incentives to recycle land over time, the administrative- the massive scale of past land misallocation in the Soviet command process has led to a startling pattern of land city. use. Its central feature is a perverse population density The experience of socialist cities is also a powerful gradient, which rises as one moves away from the center warning about the ill effects of public ownership and the of the city. (Driving from the center of Moscow, one allocation of land to achieve the "socialization" of land passes through rings of Stalin-era, Khrushchev-era, and rents. then Brezhnev-era flats.) The Soviet city is also characterized by rusting factories in prime locations and high density residential areas in This paper - a joint product of the Transport Division, Transportation, Water, and Urban Development Department and the Financial Sector Development Department - are the result of a program of technical cooperation carried out between the Russian Federation and the World Bank. Copies of the paper are available free from the World Bank, 1818 H Street NW, Washington, DC 20433. Please contact Laura Lewis, room S6-109, extension 30539 (15 pages). June 1995. The Policy Research Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange of ideas about development issues. An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished. The papers carry the names of the authors and should be used and cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions are the authors' oum and should not be attributed to the World Bank, its Executive Board of Directors, or any of its member countries. Produced by the Policy Research Dissemination Center CITIES WITHOUT LAND MARKETS: LOCATION AND LAND USE IN THE SOCIALIST CITY by Alain BERTAUD* and Bertrand RENAUD** * Principal Urban Planner Infrastructure and Urban Development Department ** Housing Finance Advisor Financial Sector Development Department The World Bank H Street N. W. Washington DC 20433 The empirical findings presented in this paper result from a program of technical cooperation carried out between the Russian Federation and the World Bank. We are especially grateful to Joseph K. Eckert, Natalya V. Kalinina, Mikhail P. Berezin, Olga Kaganova and Oleg Matiukhin for their assistance during this period; particularly to J. Eckert for the use of the price gradient data. CITIES WITHOUT LAND MARKETS: LOCATION AND LAND USE IN THE SOCIALIST CITY 1. INTRODUCTION The rejection of private ownership of capital and of the means of production has been a central tenet of Marxist ideology. To what extent does the socialist city differ from the market city? How does its land use differ from the outcomes of our familiar models of residential and business location based on competitive land markets developed in the tradition of Alonso, Wingo, Muth, Mills and now extended beyond the monocentric city? Also, what happens when public ownership and public allocation of land is the road chosen to solve the long-standing concern with the "capture" of public generated land rents by private owners? What is the systemic impact of the administrative- command system as a substitute to the market? The purpose of this paper is to describe the long-term effects of administrative-command systems which do away with land markets on location and land use in cities. The evidence presented comes from Russian cities which are the urban centers with the longest history of development in the absence of land markets. Except for the old historical centers, almost all of Russian urban growth has taken place during the Soviet era 1917-1991. The fact that urban development took place in a period when land was nationalized and administratively allocated, rather than sold on an open market for a price, has had a very profound impact and negative impact on the internal organization of Russian cities. The combination of Marxist ideology, national institutions, domestic economic system and level of urbanization has produced somewhat different results in each socialist economy. However, it is quite relevant to speak of a "socialist city" wherever urban development is expected to proceed without land markets and land use decisions are made administratively." The socialist city experiments bring out multiple issues of property rights, institutional organization and governance, agency problems, as well as urban planning regulations. This paper focuses only on the striking spatial anomalies and pervasive urban inefficiencies caused by the inability of an administrative-command system to evaluate even very approximately the value of a land site and its opportunity cost in alternative uses and to remedy the grossest land use misallocations. 1/ Our initial interest in the structure of socialist cities started with field work in China in 1988, see Renaud and Bertaud, 1989. A seminal influence were the papers in French and Hamilton, 1979. Qualitative results comparable to those presented here for Moscow and St. Petersburg have also been obtained in the case of other socialist cities such as Warsaw in Poland and Beijing, Shanghai and Tianjin in China, see Bertaud, 1994. II. LAND ALLOCATION IN CITIES WITHOUT MARKETS In Soviet Russia, and other socialist cities as well, administrative decisions based on "needs" and norms govern the use and quantity of land consumed. By contrast, in a market economy, land price differentials constitute the most important factors determining quantity and location of land consumed. These divergent principles governing land allocation and land use could be expected to produce different spatial and efficiency outcomes. A quantitative land use analysis of Moscow and St. Petersburg reveals that there are indeed major differences between Russian cities and market economy cities in the distribution and consumption of land.2 Inspection of land use maps or satellite photos of other Russian cities confirms that these are systemic features of the socialist city.3 A. Absence of Incentives to Recycle Land in Soviet and Other Socialist Cities As their economy and their population grow, cities expand through the progressive addition of concentric rings, similar to the process for trees in successive growing seasons. New rings are added to the periphery as the city grows. Within each ring, land use reflects the combined effects of demography, technology, and the economy at the time when the ring was developed. While this organic incremental growth is common to all cities, in a market city changing land prices exert their pressure simultaneously in all areas of the city, not just at the periphery. Land prices exert a powerful influence to recycle already developed land in the inner rings when the type and intensity of the existing use is too different from the land's optimuLm economic use. Thus, changing land values bring a built-in urban dynamistn as continuous variations in land prices trigger land use changes by putting a constant pressure on the existing uses of land. By contrast, under Russia's command economy, the absence of land prices removed all incentives to redevelop built-up areas. Once land was allocated, it was almost never recycled. Without price signals, it was administratively simpler to respond to current land demand pressure by developing 2 The methodology used is based on the measurement of population density in the built-up area, i.e. the population within two concentric rings at I km interval divided by the built-up area within this interval. This built-up area does not include large parks, physical obstacles to land use such as rivers and lakes, and any undeveloped area. These densities are derived from digitaized land use maps, satellite photographs and detailed databases related to land uses by type of users. These data bases are routinely maintained by local urban planning offices. The geocoded data was analyzed with a graphics-based GIS software. 3 In Chinese cities, however, the socialist land use system has a much shorter and more recent history than Russia. Also, Russia has completed its urbanization but China is just entering its phase of most massive urban growth. As a result, the historical Chinese urban core which was developed under a market economy has kept a much larger relative importance than in Russia. Moreover, in China, the absence of large urban infrastructure and public transport investment plus severe underinvestment in housing between 1949 and 1979 has led to more compact cities and reinforced the population density at the center. But now, under the rapid urban investment of the last decade, administrative processes operating without land markets are again generating outcomes similar to those of Soviet cities: new residential floor area ratios follow the Russian pattern and are higher in the periphery than in the center. (For more comparative data, see Bertaud, 1994). 2 at the periphery than to redevelop well-located areas with obsolete land uses. While the city expanded outward, land use in already developed areas remained unchanged. One striking illustration of this phenomenon is the persistence and uniformity of housing types in successive rings around Moscow. Each type is usually designated by the period in which it was built. Thus, driving from the center of Moscow, one passes through rings of Stalin, Khrushchev, and then Brezhnev flats. This socialist land use process creates sizable enclaves of "fallow" or "dead land" areas which combine low levels of economic activity withi negative environmental qualities. The Soviet administrative command economy has generated an urbani development process with two characteristic features of large land use inefficiencies: (1) Areas with obsolete land use occupy large amounts of the total city area; and, (2) Households tend to be concentrated in the periphery with increasing densities further from the center and "historically" low densities in central areas. This pattern tends to increase transport costs and pollutioni by requiring higher energy expeniditures without providing better amenities such as larger plot size or a better environiment that would be the nonnal trade-off for increasing commuting distance in a market economy. B. Why Rusting Factories in Prime Urban Locations? The failure to recycle land occupied by old activities of little value yields several spatial outcomes: centrally located industrial belts, large total amount of urban industrial area, low job density in the industrial belts, and central land areas fragmented by dense railway networks. There are four major consequenices. First, of these pathologies, the most startling are the old industrial belts that ring Moscow and St. Petersburg. Developed during the 1930's and 1950's. these belts are still spread between 4 and 8 kilometers trom the city centers. These industrial land use bottlenecks have never been recycled, even thoughi the land values would have been prohibitively expensive for these enterprises had market land prices been used. The absence of market signals resulted in a land use freeze that pushied residential areas further toward the city periphery thanl in market cities. Meanwhile, obsolete and low density activities have remained as enclaves on accessible and well serviced land.4 The absence of land prices and the dominance of industrial planning in government thinking and policies explains the second phenomenon. Not only are Moscow and St. Petersburg characterized by centrally-located industrial belts, but also the total industrial land area within these cities is extraordlintarilv lalrge. For example, in Moscow, 31.5% of the total built-up area is used by industries, compared with 5% in Paris, 6% in Seoul, and 5% for Hong Kong. In the industrial belt from 7 to 8 kilometers trom the center of Moscow, 67% of land is used by industries. (See FIGURE l.a). The extensive use of prime, centrally-located urban land for industries is particularly inefficienit in Russia because of socialist industrial organization whicih requires most industries to hold large 4 FThe almost Dickensiani character of centrally located Ifactories in the Soviet Union and China also reflects a very low rate of techniological chan(ge, especially compared to those of today's "emnerging markets'" in Asia. See the discussion of high growth rates withi little or zero productivity gains under central planning in Renaud, 1990. 3 inventories of materials in order to survive in the socialist system. These industries therefore use large areas of landfor warehousing and heavy transport infrastructure -- a peculiar constraint on industrial land use that results in a low ratio ofjobs per unit of land. In a market economy, such a low job-to-land ratio would be incompatible with the central location of these industries. Third, the distribution of jobs by distance to the city center shows that both Moscow and Saint Petersburg, are still monocentric cities with a high concentration of jobs in the city center, a feature common with most market economy cities. (See FIGURE l.b). As the transition to markets progresses, many industrial jobs will disappear and more service jobs will be created. The majority of these jobs will be located in the city center further reinforcing the monocentric characters of these cities. The histograms of the geographical distribution of jobs for Moscow ( FIGURE .1 .b) and Saint Petersburg (not shown) confirm that the industrial zones do not significantly increase the number of jobs to justify their prime location so close to the city center. No data were available to conduct a more detailed analysis of present land use and floor space. But the very high spot prices reached by new office space in Moscow and Saint Petersburg are indicative of an acute supply constraint for land and floor space dedicated to services in the city center, a typical shortage in socialist economies in transition. Fourth, obsolete forms of intercity transport further solidify this frozen land use pattern. The land of the industrial belt of Moscow is serviced by a dense network of railways which have the effect of further fragmenting the land and making land on the exterior side of the industrial belt expensive to service. Only a small part of the volume of traffic on the rail network within Moscow Municipal boundary is used for passenger and commuter traffic; most of it is used for freight. This fragmentation further reduces the usability of land adjacent to centrally-located industrial areas and increases significantly the cost of the primary infrastructure network which has to be developed to service it. This fragmentation of urbanized land by railroads is linked to the Soviet Union's extraordinarily high dependence on rail transport compared to any other country which is nine times higher than in Western Europe, and to the industrial bias of Soviet economic and urban planning. This problem is encountered in most Soviet cities and other socialist economies. C. Dynamics of Housing and Residential Development in the Socialist City The prevalence of unrecycled large-scale industrial belts in Moscow and St. Petersburg is a subset of a larger set of spatial distortions found in Russian cities. The process of development of housing projects under the administrative command-system and the activities of real estate developers in market cities follow different motivations and yields totally different outcomes from those predicted by market models of location and land use. The key to understanding these larger distortions also provides a tool to design policies for reducing inefficiencies. In a market, housing developers are value maximizers while in a supply-driven command economy bureaucratic housing builders are cost minimizers with little interest in final users satisfaction since these are not the direct clients which are other administrations. 4 FIGURE 1 INDUSTRIAL LAND USE AND JOB DENSITY PATTERNS Figure l.a MOSCOW - LAND USE Percentage of Industrial Land within Built-up Area 70%- 950% V 40%- 30%- 0 20% 10% 0% 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 1718S 19 2021 Dlatt,c* from Ciy CnerW (km) h: f m Date Eour.: Inat.tute ot The Mat*r Plan ot Mo..ow Figure 1.b MOSCOW - LAND USE ANALYSIS Job Density 25 200- -.---. ------* g1o0 -. -. 50 Dgtwice fron City center (kn) -ED- 3rOSS Job danity M Dendty I Bt* | Source: Institute of Master Plan of Moscow 1992 In a market economily, private developers compete for the same location. The winning bid will go to the activity estimated to be mnost profitable at that site. Land prices exert their pressure on the whole supply of land, includinig the already built land. This is the key to economically efficient cities and lies at the core of our ulban models. As the city expands, land prices tend to rise throughout the city. Land prices stay the highiest in the most accessible areas around the city center and along transport corridors. This was already Von ThCinen's fundamental insight. SucIh pricing triggers density increases in those areas. The rise in density triggered by relative price changes is due to the compounded effects of two pheniomilenia: (1) Floor-to-land area ratios (FAR) increase in central locations because of land recycling through demolition and reconstruction, and (2) The consumption of land space per job or per resident decreases because the more efficient land users out-bid less efficient land users who theni move to more peripheral locations where land is cheaper. Over time. the interaction of these eff'ects produces a population density profile that is negatively sloped from the high-population center to the sparsely-populated periphery. The driving force behind this density gradient is not master planining by city planiners, but the individual decisions of real estate developers who want to maximize the difference between production costs and the market value of the Final product. As a city grows larger and richer, recycling land in already built-up areas offers the opportullity to maximilze this difference. This is an incremental and decentralized process but it is not slow. In advanced industrial economies, about 2% to 5% of allL urban jobs within an urban area relocate every year, depending on economic growth conditions. In a market economy like the US, families relocate about every five years, but 80% of moves are withint the same urbani area. By contrast, under the administrativc-comiliand economy, housing construction organizations are typically integrated into housing komnhinat.%' and they respond to very different incentives. A kombinat's performanice is measured bv its ability to reduce input costs while meeting quantitative prodLictioll targets. The costs have to bie miniimized while the value of the final product is irrelevant. Land may' be l'ree, but it must be allocated from vwhat is available. Due to the lack of incentive for land recycling, the supply of' land is limited to the new areas developed that year in the outer fringe. As a conseqLuenice, kiombinats have to meet their production targets using land that is almost exclusively at the periphery. 'I'he density of the newly built area (defined as the unit of floor space divided by unit of land() will then reflect the ratio between the developed land available and the amount of floor space to be built to meet the productioni quota. As the socialist city expands, the land at the periphery becomes less and less desirable and more expensive to develop because primary infrastructure -- and metro lines in the case of Moscow and St. Petersburg -- have to be expanded. But in a command economy, housing is entirely supply- driven and, if the supply ol' serviced land is lagging behind the floor space production target, the building density in the outer rings will tend to rise. Over tine, Soviet housinig kombinats have been stacking up more floor space on the more distant land. The f'ailure to price land is compounded here by 6 artificially low energy prices. The dynamics of suchi a system do not tend to produce the resource- preserving, more ef'ficient negative density gradient of market cities.5 C. The Socialist City Compared With the Market City: Moscow versus Paris The comparison of densith profiles between Moscow and Paris is revealing (see FIGURF, 2.a). Both metropolitan regions hlave a population of about 9 million. They are strongly radio-concentric, and hiave similar peak densities. However, the way densities are distributed geographically is strikingly different. Paris shows the typical density profile of a market economy city. with a negativelj sloped gradient. In slharp contrast, Moscow has a positivelv sloped density gradient. The net density of Moscow at 1 5 kilometers from the city center is twice as higih than in the center. The density of Moscow suburbs at 1 5 kilometers from the center is the same as in the center of Paris. One should note the drop of density at 6 kilometers from the center in Moscow. This drop of density is due to the unrecycled industrial land use producing the enclaves of "dead land" in the city fabric. The dlegree ofpopulation dispersion can be measured in a rough maniner by comparing the median distance to the center per person. FIGURE 2.b shows the cumulative population distribution curve of Moscow. St. Petersburg and Paris. The cumulative curves of Moscow and Paris intersect each other at Kilometer 14, corresponding to a population of about 6 millioni people. This means that within a circle of a 14 kilometers radius. Moscow and Paris serve the same population. and as a consequence hiave the same average density. However, because of the difference in the density profile between the two cities, the median distance per person to the center is 7 km for Paris and 10 km for Moscow, a 42% greawler- dispersion in the case oJ Moscow. Is the land use and the density profiles of socialist cities like Moscow or St.-Petersburg a mere curiosity' for land use specialists? Emphatically not. It matters a great deal to the Russian urban economy' where three-fourth of the population lives, for the following reasons: 1. Average densities being equal. the population of a city with a positively sloped density profile is more dispersed than one located in a city with a negatively sloped profile. This implies higher transport costs, higher primary infrastructure costs, highler urban operating costs. and a greater share of labor time wasted in travel, these distortions are paid for in the form of lower levels of economic development. Note that the artificially low socialist cash wage (see Renaud, 1991) compounds residential land use distortions. In market cities, behavioral studies show that urban residents tend to value their time traveling to work as a significant proportion between one-third and one have of the hourly-wage equivalent of their salary (see Chapter 8 in Meyer and Gomez-lbafnez, 198 1 ). In socialist cities, the distorting effects on land use allocation of the lack of land prices are further masked by the artificially low value that urban residents are placing on their time. Price and wage liberalization are now triggering massive shifts in relative prices that are deeply disruptive, as discussed furthier in Part IV. 7 FIGURE 2 THE SOCLALIST CITY COMPARED TO THE MARKET CITY Moscow Compared to Paris Figure 2.a COMPARATIVE POPULATION DENSITY GRADIENT Between Moscow and Paris Built-up Area 300_ 250- Oituce Ira Cit cets a Source: Instut of Master Plan of Moscow 1992 Figure 2.b MOSCOW - LAND USE ANALYSIS Comparative Population Distribution 9 7,000,000- , ............ .. : j,X.; ........ ;.; 000000- ............. . . .. Fi0u00 2.b 6,000,000- . ,000,000 - - - ,i - .,..; . .. a2 . 6 . 4,000,000 Usyldt' a. n frtajnii Ba~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~.... ...... 3,000,000- Souse:Infitte f astr Pn f Msco 192,StPetersburg Isiueo raitcTel Pari Cenus 99 1,000,000 -.- 0 1 3 5 7 '11 3 1'5 1?7 1'9' 21 3 25 2~7 29~ '31 33 5 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24 26 28 30 32 34 Distace from City cenmer (kmi) -8~- Moscow -*r- St Petesburs --w*- PwS Souac: Institute of Master Plan of Moscow 1992, St Petersburg lnstitute of Urbanistic Theory Paris Census 1990 2. A large amount of floor space has been developed where there is little demand for it, that is, in the suburbs with less accessibility. When transport subsidies are progressively removed and full wages restored, demand -- and consequently land prices -- for this type of high density housing far from the city center will drop even further. Prices could well drop below replacement costs and trigger abandonment. 3. The fully-serviced, underused land close to the city center has a high opportunity cost. IH. EMERGING PROPERTY MARKETS AND REAL ESTATE PRICES For seventy years, Soviet Russia has used its great natural resources to built an urban system of doubtful efficiency and sustainability. More generally, the socialist city has inordinately high capital/output ratios and requires more resources for less urban output that market cities. Urban land markets are therefore a very important part of overall economic reforms. The allocation of land should be driven by its current opportunity cost. However, the value of a specific land parcel in its highest and best use can prove difficult to estimate even in a stable fully developed urban land market. The next best prices are actual market transactions which are the result of private valuation of investors looking at the future and risking their own-resources. Since 1990, urban laws and constitutional reforms promoting individual ownership and decisions have been enacted in Russia (Butler and O'Leary, 1994), as well as other socialist countries, including China (Kerzner 1993). Consistent with Kornai's insight (1990), such reforms were initially attempted for narrow bureaucratic reasons. A. Synthetic Land Price Gradients and Normative Prices During the late 1980's, under Gorbachev's perestroika, local governments resources had become severely constrained. Local mechanisms to finance the production of serviced land had to be found to complement the inadequate resource transfers from the central government. It was therefore decided to create a land use tax to finance local infrastructure. In the peculiar logic of an administrative-command system, officially land has no value in construction projects. Yet everyone agreed that different locations have very different economic values. The solution chosen was to estimate normative land prices on which taxes could be based. For the first time, various research institutes began building models to calculate synthetic land price maps according to which taxes would be raised, and from which land price gradients could be derived. These institutes have attempted to map normative values of land calculated on the basis of weighted coefficients representing amenities such as transport, infrastructure, environmental quality, etc. Typically, demand factors were not included, and price estimates were based on the arbitrary and highly distorted accounting prices of the late 1 980s. Regardless of these fundamental flaws, land value maps were produced from which one can infer a city's normative, land price gradient. The resulting normative land price gradients of Moscow and St. Petersburg were negatively sloped. Moscow's gradient was somewhat flatter than St. Petersburg. The normative price variation between the center and the periphery in Moscow was only 2.5 to I (from Rb 4,000 at km 0 to Rb 1,600 at 22 km in the now irrelevant 1990 prices). Both curves are much too flat. In market cities, 9 in the absence of major topographical and legal constraints, the ratio between the land price in the central business district and at the fringe of the built-up periphery is usually on the order of 10 to 1. In spite of their correct slope, the profile of these normative curves was highly arbitrary as nobody knew either the highest nor the lowest values. Such normative prices could greatly improve the traditional urban master plans made in Russia. but they would be of' no value for the choice of a specific location for a given investmenit. B. Housing Privatization and Rapidly Emerging Implicit Land Price Gradients With the beginning of housing reforms. actual apartment sales transactions between private parties have been taking place in Moscow since 199 1. Privatization and opportunities to trade ullits are now rising dramatically.|! A preliminary empirical analysis of 2.000 transactions carried in the first trimester of 1992 and of another group of transactions in the fourthi trimester of the same year provides an important first look at emerging real estate and land prices. The study analyzed the residuals from an apartment sales model that uses only building-specific variables based on resales of privatized apartments. It is possible to construct a land price gradient by plotting the residual as a functioni of distance from the center of the city as show in FIGURE 3. These preliminary results provide sonie critical informationi. First, the emerging price gradient is downward sloping from the ceenter. Clearly. housinig kombinats are not providing the housing that household value the most. As FIGURE 3.a shows, the land price index decreases from 100% in the center to 70% at 25 km. -- a negative price gradient -- with the greatest decreases coming in the first 8 km. This model suggests that, at present. imputed land prices are only about 1.5 times higher at the center than at 25 km. This is still a very weak price dif'ferential to trigger the urban restructuring that Russian cities need. Various factors can explain this flat price gradient inclLiding the collapsing economy, ambiguities about land values. and the disequilibrium state of an emerging market. What is rathet striking and unanticipated is that the land price gradient seems to be rotating very rapidly during the transition to market.7 The analysis for the second period in Moscow shows that the slope of the price gradient has steepened from I 00 percent in the center to 58 percent at only 1 5 kilometers from tile center. This a real adjustment of 20 percent in less than a year. It can be expected that, withi new legal clarifications of land ownership rights in December 1992, privatization, as well as continuiLig relative price changes regarding energy the gradient will continue to rotate For reference. it is estimated that about 125,000 housing units were exchanged or sold in 1992. Since there are about 3.1 million apartments in Moscow, this represents a rate of about 4 percent of the housing stock. In a market city. the annial ratio of housing trades is often of the order of 15 percent of the stock. A major social change is taking place with the rapid privatization housing units by their occupants. Between late 1992 and the end of 1993, 35.5% of the state stock was privatized in Moscow and 26% in Russia. By the end of 1994, the share of privately owned Moscow units was expected to reach 55 %, in dramatic contrast to a ratio of less than one percent in 1990. This Muscovite rate of privatization remains much higher than other cities. Privatization of housing units has been particularly rapid in Moscow and St. Petersburg. By the end of 1994. The share of privately owned units in Moscow has risen dramatically from less than one percent in 1990 to more than 55 percent by the end of 1994. 10 rapidly. This expectation is also fed by a similar analysis of land prices in Krakow, Poland which shows that in that city the land price differential has already reached a market city differential of about 10 to 1. Polish urban reforms, in particular the restoration of private land ownership rights has been more thorough that what has been done so far in Russia. At this early stage in the development of the land market, location values are not yet being fully capitalized into property values. A morc normal price differential will only emerge when investors have more certainty about land tenure. when real estate information institutions become more proficient. and when economic and political conditions stabilize. FIGURE 3 EMERGING MARKET LAND PRICE GRADIENTS in Moscow and Krakow, Poland 100 s I 9$... S.. .. ... . ....... ... . ...... . . .. .. .. . . ... . ........ .. .... ... . ...... .. ............ .... - .-....... . . ....... .. . ..... . .. ....... .......... .. . . .. ...... .. . 1 90 j~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~ .. K X-_..... .. ....... ... ....... .......... ......... ...... ... .. .. ... ..... ...... . ....... ... . .... .... . .......... .... ...... ... ............. ..... .......... ............................. 10X . - -. - - .-- ----------- 80 - ........... .. . . ........... ......... .......... ................................ ............... . l \ - + Me, 1992 ...... -. - -- - -. 1h rWr-- 7 5 .. .. ...... .. ......... .... . ....... ... . . ................ . ... .. ..... ....... .. E 60 _ - Uuscaw.-t99 - ~............. . .....................-.- ---- ---- ---- 70 5 . ..f...... .....ur............h.... 50... . . ...... .... .5. . . . ...... . 4 0 .- ........- . ........ 30. . . .... .. 25 -. . .......... 7......... - .- 20 _ ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~KSkow. Pohni 2 0 -.......-............................ 15 * *4. .4 lW - -2 - - 12 5 - - ..... .... ............. ..... .... .. ........... ...... ................... ....... ....... .............................. ............. ............................_ .................... ............. ......................... ........_ 10- 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 Distance from City Center (Km) (Source: Joseph K. Eckert) 8/ This rapid rotation is confirmed in the analysis of different Moscow housing price data by G.S. Madalla, Y. Toda, and N.N. Nozdrina in "The Price of Apartments Auctioned in Moscow: A Heeding Approach" (unpublished draft paper, May 1993). 11 IV. THE TRANSITION TO MARKETS: IS THE SOVIET CITY SUSTAINABLE? Urban land markets are expected to raise the efficiency of the socialist city, but what happens during the transition, especially in Russia? For seven decades, Soviet planners have made urban investment decisions under four greatly distorted prices: land had not site value, interest on capital was not recognized, energy prices were only a small fraction of world prices, and cash wages bore no relation to the marginal productivity of labor. The emergence of markets will lead to sharp shifts in relative prices. In cities, the process is likely to be seriously disruptive. We can only point here at some of the management issues during this transition to markets.9 What will be the outcome of the interactions between the negatively sloped land price gradient with the positively sloped population density gradient? What will happen to: (I) the land occupied by existing enterprises, and (2) to the pricing of dwelling units, both rents and sale prices? A. Market Prices and Affordability of Land Currently Occupied by Enterprises Land reform administrators are presented with a difficult dilemma: if enterprises are asked to pay the market price (as defined above) for the land they occupy -- in the form of rent or land use tax -- most of them would not be able to afford it, and some would have to be declared bankrupt. Alternatively, if the financially weaker enterprises are given a reprieve or a waiver on the cost of land they occupy, this will perpetuate the status quo. The urban community will lose the opportunity cost of the land. New infrastructure would have to be developed elsewhere, while the costly existing infrastructure would remain underused. If the objective is to improve land use efficiency as rapidly as possible, one approach for responding to the above dilemma is to grant to existing enterprises explicit property rights in the land they now occupy. Then the enterprise will have the incentive to use this land as equity in planning to relocate to more affordable, appropriate land. The value of the land resources involved in industrial land recycling -- even under the emerging low and still flat price gradient estimated for 1992 in FIGURE 3-- is very large. If we assume that the percentage of industrial land of Moscow could be reduced from the present 32% to 10% -- still a high ratio by international standards -- then about 100 square kilometers of already developed land could be recovered. Current Russian discussions of the affordability problem of non-residential land are a false problem which ignores the necessity of land use transition. By definition, the market price of land is affordable to new users. The industrial land may not be affordable, however, to existing users who are asked to pay for it retroactively, but these existing users are precisely those who are using land in an inefficient manner. The affordability dilemma can be solved by recognizing the land equity interest of present land users and then allowing these users to trade freely the land they occupy. B. Impact of the Transition to Markets on Housing and Services Areas 9 For details, see Bertaud and Renaud (I 994). 12 The basic price of a housing unit depends on three main parameters: (1) location, (2) floor area, and (3) land area. Households, when shopping for housing, have to make trade-ofs between those three parameters. For a given shelter price, suppliers are theoretically able to provide a dwelling unit in any location. This is possible by allocating different combinations of values to the three basic parameters: location, floor and land. Thus, the floor-to-land-area ratio of different housing unit types may varies widely within the same city. The net land area required to build one square meter of floor space may vary from 0.10 square meter for high rise apartments to 15 square meters for detached houses. Urban regulations and the many-dimensional features of housing demand impose a limit to the theoretically infinite number of permutations between location, floor area and land area. With housing privatization which has been taking place very rapidly in Moscow and St. Petersburg, a housing market is emerging in Russia. Households are gaining ownership interest in the units they currently occupy, but different units of the housing stock at different locations within each city have very different values. The larger part of the housing stock built in the periphery of Moscow and St. Petersburg and the 150 largest cities of Russia (nationally about 55%) consists of prefabricated, reinforced-concrete, large-panel, high-rise apartments of 5, 9, 12, 15 and 22 floors. The actual economic value of such units and not their resource cost will be revealed by household preferences for the first time. High rise apartments at the periphery have four problems. (1) Operating and maintenance costs -- defined to include the cost of maintenance and operations of elevators and lift pumps, cost of central heating caused by the bad insulation of panel buildings, costs of frequent structural repairs required by the building technology used, and the cost of maintenance of large common open space. At present, rents no longer cover much if anything beyond the sharply increased energy costs. (2) The space standards measured according to room dimensions and height of ceiling which did not vary between central and suburban locations. (3) The quality of amenities including distance to shops and a variety of services may be lower than in central locations. (4 Transport costs formerly expressed only in time to work, are rising rapidly in financial terms as energy costs and other costs rise and transport subsidies decrease. The market price which will emerge as land and real estate markets develop may turn out to be much below the replacement cost of such a unit. Most importantly, the market price of suchl units expressed in terms of market rent, might not even cover maintenance costs. Viewed through the prism of emerging market prices, much of the housing stock in periphery apartment buildings may have a discounted present market value of less than zero -- a sobering issue for privatization policy and for future housing investment programs. In the case of Moscow, as can be seen in FIGURE 2.a, the units at risk would be those located in residential areas with densities above the density line for Paris between kilometer 9 and kilometer 22. Given the current housing shortage, transition policies of preferential treatment in terms of transportation subsidies, higher quality maintenance may ease the burdens on residents. But it will remain a fact that these parts of the housing stock have very low and mostly negative transitory economic value. The high accessibility of some parts of the suburban areas (around metro stations for instance) should provide the opportunity for the emergence of secondary employment centers. Such centers would contribute to restoring the economic value of some of the residential areas. For this to happen, land use regulations and local administrative practices should show enough flexibility and speedy responsiveness to allow land conversion wherever firms of all 13 sizes choose to use this location opportunity. Allowing this type of land use transformation to proceed should be a high urban policy priority. It should be clear from the quantitative analysis presented that the suburban housing crisis which is looming in the cities of Russia cannot be attributed to the transition to markets, but to the legacy of the past. This crisis is the result of the administrative-command which disregarded the practical needs and preferences of the final users and lacked means of self-correction. The economic value of the housing that was produced did not match the true economic cost of the resources used. This cost was masked by distorted accounting prices which provided no meaningful guidance to decision makers who resorted to inadequate or perverse physical and administrative criteria. The scissors effect between low rents and low wages on one hand, and rising operation and maintenance costs on the other is not sustainable. Restoration of an economic balance could result from abandonment of the least attractive part of the stock combined with increasing crowding of remaining units and much higiler rent to income ratios. CONCLUSIONS The absence of land markets has profoundly impaired the ability to allocate and recycle urban land and has had a very negative impact on the intemal efficiency, productivity, environmental quality, and livability of the socialist city. The extent of land use misallocation and the degree ot rigidity encountered in the Russian economy which is by now fully urbanized is startling. The consequence is that the socialist city tends to have very high capital/output ratios and consumes more resources per unit of output. A second important lesson of the failed socialist experiment is that the well-meaning attempt to socialize the collection of the land rent through public ownership and administrative allocation of land has not achieved the intended results. There is nothing presented in this paper that would call into questionl the social goals of any community. Rather, it is the allocation of land by administrative means in the name of equity and efficiency which has demonstrably failed on an inordinate scale. A broad variety of social goals can be accommodated under market conditions. Soviet cities remind US that what is most valuable in urban land market institutions is their ability to signal through prices how the currenit and future use of land is valued by individuals and society-- and to reveal how site valuation shiftS tIp or down over time. Finally, the evidence suggests that the social and economic transition costs of moving to markets will be the highest in economies such as Russia that are most highly urbanized and where cities are moving to market during a period of sharp economic contraction. Urban reforms are particularly urgent and most feasible in the socialist economies of Asia where economies are growing and the greatest wave of ulbaniization still lies ahead. In order to move to markets, the main components of the needed urban reform are: clear and tradable property rights; efficient and market- oriented informiationi systems: a taxation system consistent with efficient land use; and, last but not least. the timely' publicity arid contestability of urban planning decisions (see Bertaud, Renaud, 1994). 14 BIBLIOGRAPHY 1. BERTAUD, A. (1994), "Land Markets, Urban Form, and the Environment" paper presented at the Annual World Bank Conference on Environmentally Sustainable Development, Washington DC, September. 2. and B. RENAUD (1994), Cities Without Land Markets, Lessons of the Failed Socialist Experiment, World Bank Discussion Papers Series No. 227, March. 3. BUTLER, S. B. and S. O'LEARY (1994), Laws Relating to Housing and Urban Development in the Russian Federation, Washington DC: The Urban Institute, March. 4. ECKERT, J. K. (1993) "The Use of Automated Real Estate Databases to Stimulate the Development of Property Markets and Facilitate Privatization" in V. RENARD and R. ACOSTA eds. Land Tenure and Property Development in Eastern Europe, Paris: Pirvil-CNRS and ADEF. 5. FRENCH R.A. and F.E.I. HAMILTON eds., The Socialist City, Spatial Structure and Urban Policy, Chichester, U.K.: John Wiley, 1979. 6. KERZNER, D.S. (1993) "The Commercial Real Estate Laws of the People's Republic of China and Shenzhen: An Overview" Vanderbilt Journal of Transnational Law, Vol. 26, 581-631. 7. KORNAI, J. (1990) "The Affinity Between Ownership Forms and Coordination Mechanisms" Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 4, No.3. 8. MEYER, J. R. and J. GOMEZ-IBANEZ (1981) Autos, Transit and Cities, Cambridge: Harvard U. Press. 9. RENAUD, B. (1990). "China's 1988 Urban Housing Reforms: Origins, Scope, and Major Obstacles" in G.C. Lim and W. Chang (eds), Dynamic Transformation. Korea, NICs, and Beyond, Seoul, Korea: Myung Bo Publishing Co. 10. , (1991b). Housing Reform in Socialist Economies, World Bank Discussion Papers Series No. 125, June. II. , (1992). "The Housing System of the Former Soviet Union: Why Do the Soviets Need Housing Markets", Washington DC: Fannie Mae, Housing Policy Debate, Vol.3, Issue 3, November. 12. , (1995) "The Real Estate Economy and the Design of Russian Housing Reforms" , Urban Studies, Vol. 32, Nos 8 and 12, October and December (forthcoming). 13. and A. BERTAUD, (1989), "Urban Housing Reforms: The City experiments and the 1988 Reform Plan", paper presented at the Joint China-World Seminar on the Urban Housing Reforms System Reforms, Beijing, PRC. 14. WORLD BANK,(1994), Russia.: Housing Reform and Privatization. Strategy and Transition Issues, Vol.1: Main Report, xlviii and 198 pages; Vol.2: Annexes, 175 pages. March. 15 Policy Research Working Paper Series Contact Title Author Date for paper WPS1450 Social Safety Net and the Poor Fareed M. A. Hassan May 1995 F. Smith during the Transition: The Case of R. Kyle Peters, Jr. 36072 Bulgaria WPS1451 Tunisia's Insurance Sector Dimitri Vittas May 1995 P. Infante 37642 WPS1452 The 1985-94 Global Real Estate Bertrand Renaud May 1995 R. Garner Cycle: Its Causes and Consequences 37670 WPS1453 Air Pollution and Mortality: Results Bart Ostro May 1995 C. Bernardo from Santiago, Chile Jose Miguel Sanchez 37699 Carlos Aranda Gunnar S. Eskeland WPS1454 Child Labor: A Review Christiaan Grootaert May 1995 M. Youssef Ravi Kanbur 34614 WPS1455 Tentative First Steps: An Assessment Bernard Hoekman May 1995 F. Hatab of the Uruguay Round Agreement 35835 on Services WPS1456 Equity Markets, Transaction Costs, Valerie R. Bencivenga May 1995 P. Sintim-Aboagye and Capital Accumulation: An Bruce D. Smith 38526 Illustration Ross M. Starr WPS1457 Does Decentralization Increase Antonio Estache May 1995 WDR Spending on Public Infrastructure? Sarbajit Sinha 31393 WPS1458 Credit Policies: Lessons from East Dimitri Vittas May 1995 P. Infante Asia Yoon Je Cho 37642 WPS1459 Pension Funds in Central Europe Dimitri Vittas May 1995 P. Infante and Russia: Their Prospects and Roland Michelitsch 37642 Potential Role in Corporate Government WPS1460 Efficiency and Equity Considerations Yacov Tsur May 1995 C. Spooner in Pricing and Allocating Irrigation Ariel Dinar 32116 Water WPS1461 Stock Market Development and Firm Asli Demirgu,-Kunt May 1995 P. Sintim-Aboagye Financing Choices Vojislav Maksimovic 38526 WPS1462 Stock Market Development and Asli Demirguc,-Kunt May 1995 P. Sintim-Aboagye Financial Intermediaries Ross Levine 38526 WPS1463 Rural Nonfarm Employment: A Survey Jean 0. Lanjouw May 1995 J. Shafer Peter Lanjouw 85581 Policy Research Working Paper Series Contact Title Author Date for paper WPS1464 How Does the North American Free Edward E. Leamer May 1995 S. Vallimont Trade Agreement Affect Central Alfonso Guerra 37791 America? Martin Kaufman Boris Segura WPS1465 Post Trade Liberalization Policy Sarath Rajapatirana May 1995 J. Troncoso and Institutional Challenges in 37826 Latin America and the Caribbean WPS1466 Ownership and Financing of Charles D. Jacobson June 1995 WDR Infrastructure: Historical Joel A. Tarr 31393 Perspectives WPS1467 Beyond the Uruguay Round: The Jeffrey D. Lewis June 1995 B. Kim Implications of an Asian Free Trade Sherman Robinson 82477 Area Zhi Wang WPS1468 Government's Role in Pakistan Rashid Faruqee June 1995 C. Anbiah Agriculture: Major Reforms are Needed 81275 WPS1469 The Role of Labor Unions in Fostering John Pencavel June 1995 WDR Economic Developmc, it 31393 WPS1470 Pension Systems and Reforms: Patricio Arrau June 1995 E. Khine Country Experiences and Research Klaus Schmidt-Hebbel 37471 Issues WPS1471Pension Reform and Growth Giancarlo Corsetti June 1995 E. Khine Klaus Schmidt-Hebbel 37471 WPS1472 Fiscal and Monetary Contraction in Klaus Schmidt-Hebbel June 1995 E. Khine Chile: A Rational-Expectations Luis Serven 37471 Approach WPS1473 The Surge in Capital Inflows to Eduardo Fernandez-Arias June 1995 Developing Countries: Prospects and Peter J. Montiel Policy Response WPS 1474 Are Stable Agreements for Sharing D. Marc Kilgour June 1995 C. Spooner International River Waters Now Ariel Dinar 32116 Possible? WPS1475 Decentralization: The Way Forward Andrew N. Parker June 1995 D. Housden for Rural Development? 36637 WPS 1476 Public Spending and the Poor: What Dominique van de Walle June 1995 C. Bernardo We Know, What We Need to Know 37699 WPS1477 Cities Without Land Markets: Alain Bertaud June 1995 L. Lewis Location and Land Use in the Bertrand Renaud 30539 Socialist City